Select Committee on Trade and Industry First Report



Profit-sharing

  47. A common suggestion for regulatory improvement is that RPI-X should be replaced by some form of profit-sharing formula. The DGES states that "RPI-X already does share the benefits of cost reductions": this is done "by setting price limits based on projected cost reductions, and by setting subsequent limits reflecting experience of actual cost reductions".[87] The prospective benefits of this will therefore be built in to the prices charged under the control.[88] However, shareholders get the rewards first, and customers in the subsequent price review period through lower prices for the future. Research undertaken by National Economic Research Associates has shown that "over time, customers get over 70% of any efficiency improvement, and shareholders under 30%".[89] Whilst efficiency is an important aspect of the price control formula, the economic profits that the monopolies make, even though they derive from out-performance of the regulators' surrogate competition through price controls, may be perceived as "excess" profit gained by the abuse of monopoly power. Whatever the reasons, there have been dramatic profit increases, and it is understandable that consumers are concerned that they might not be receiving their fair share of the benefits of efficiency savings; and it is widely believed that shareholders have benefited far more than consumers (see paras 182-188).[90] Such concerns have led to proposals for reforming the RPI-X regulation formula.

  48. Several variants of profit-sharing, such as "annual formula" profit-sharing and "sliding scale" schemes, have been referred to by witnesses. Such schemes would give customers a greater or earlier share of any unanticipated efficiency gains than the RPI-X formula does. Annual formula profit-sharing requires fixed rebates based on the actual profit earned in the year. A profit threshold is determined for the company and, if actual profit is greater than the threshold, then a proportion of the excess profit is returned to customers, usually by way of price reductions or a rebate in the following year. With sliding scale regulation the company can choose to set lower prices in return for a lower rate of profit-sharing. If the profit-sharing scheme is symmetrical as regards risk, then the company might also be allowed to raise prices if profits fell below the given threshold level of profit.

  49. The main advantages of a profit-sharing mechanism are that it ensures that prices do not get significantly out of line with costs, it creates an automatic correction over any lax price formula and, most importantly, it results in an earlier, more equitable distribution of efficiency benefits between shareholders and consumers.[91] Several disadvantages were also put forward:

    --   any sanctions on profits would have detrimental effects on incentives to reduce costs compared with the existing RPI-X control;[92]

    --   although customers might receive a larger share of the profits in the short term, this is likely to be more than offset by the higher cost base which they would ultimately have to bear;[93]

    --   there is a risk that it would give companies incentives to manipulate profit levels so as to minimise or eliminate any requirement to reduce prices to customers;

    --   above all, profit-sharing would make regulation more detailed, complex and uncertain as it would involve defining `normal' and `excess' profits, and annual discussions between the regulator and the company.[94]

  50. After consulting on the issue of profit-sharing, the regulators have, on the whole, rejected the idea in favour of the existing system chiefly on the grounds that extensive annual profit-sharing arrangements are likely to reduce incentives to increase efficiency. For example, the rail regulator opted to start with the RPI-X form of control.[95] According to OFGAS, "evidence from the US, where such a [profit-sharing] form of control has been implemented, does not indicate compensating advantages".[96] The DGES's response has been not to reject it completely. He believes that there is a case for considering alternatives akin to sliding scale regulation in certain circumstances, and has proposed a form of a sliding scale control on NGC's revenue from transmission services.[97]

  51. The GCC argues that sliding scale regulation "should not be lightly discarded by regulators".[98] However, the weight of the evidence suggested that profit-sharing has not yet been sufficiently developed. The MEB believes "that such an approach requires further careful consideration and investigation, with possibly a limited trial to assist wider debate, prior to any serious consideration being given to its introduction in the future".[99]

  52. None of the witnesses put forward definitions of `normal' or `excess' profits, thus reinforcing the view that such terms would be difficult to define. The MEB believes that the regulators "have tended not to commit themselves other than in broad terms" to addressing these issues.[100] With regard to the determination of the proportion of the profits to be returned to customers, a 50:50 split was suggested, but reasons to support this ratio, as opposed to any other, were not given; nor was there any discussion of the implication this would have for the incentive regulatory framework.

  53. The MEB argued that the nature of profit-sharing within the current RPI-X regulation is not explicit and is, therefore, not well understood.[101] The extent to which this contributes to the dissatisfaction with the current regime, rather than a belief that there are fundamental flaws with the RPI-X formula, is unclear. A more explicit form of profit-sharing might be more acceptable politically, but whether profit-sharing is on balance a desirable alternative to RPI-X regulation depends on judgements of the extent of the disincentive to efficiency, the increased regulatory burden and the relative weights placed on efficiency and equity objectives. We were interested by the Director General of Water Supply's recent proposals for a voluntary acceleration scheme for the earlier sharing of profits with consumers: because it is a voluntary scheme it should not destroy incentives to efficiency.[102] By its very nature, such a scheme cannot be imposed by Government or the regulators; nevertheless, we urge companies to consider voluntary acceleration.

  54. British Gas argued strongly for a profit-sharing mechanism to be introduced alongside the current RPI-X control for a different reason. It pointed out that RPI-X regulation provides strong incentives to achieve efficiency gains at the beginning of the price control period compared to the end of the period. British Gas told us that "savings made earlier in the formula period were worth far more than savings made toward the end because lower costs, under gas regulation thus far, are incorporated in the revised and lower cost base for the next period".[103] It believes that the formula encourages a short-term focus on efficiency gains and that a better balance needs to be achieved between the short-term interests of gas consumers and the need to finance the business. Essentially British Gas's concern is that the company's shareholders will not benefit from the lower cost level created as a result of its restructuring programme; instead the benefits will be passed to consumers through lower prices. British Gas considers that a profit-sharing system would allow the efficiency incentives to be the same throughout the period, and it would prefer a profit-sharing system which would allow some element of `roll-over' of cost-savings whereby benefits accrued to shareholders as well as customers. OFGAS rejected British Gas's proposal on the basis that it was potentially subjective, interventionist, and the calculations involved would be complex. Instead, OFGAS proposed a risk sharing mechanism relating to the costs associated with the introduction of competition in domestic gas supply.[104] We think that British Gas's point about RPI-X regulation providing stronger incentives to efficiency in the earlier years is an important one. However, it appears to us that the proposal which British Gas have put forward would benefit shareholders the most. We support the DGGS's decision not to introduce British Gas's proposals.

  55. None of the options we have examined is perfect. Although many witnesses criticised the RPI-X form of incentive regulation by periodic review, the weight of our evidence did not support a move towards a rate of return approach.[105] In fact, witnesses regarded the rate of return method as having significant and numerous deficiencies compared with the RPI-X formula.[106] The arguments for incentive regulation are powerful and the advantages of the RPI-X incentive regulation outweigh those of rate of return, and other forms of profit-sharing, such as annual formula profit-sharing and sliding scale regulation, because they are likely to erode incentives. Therefore, the RPI-X form of incentive regulation has much to commend it over other methods, above all, because it provides powerful incentives to companies to reduce costs through efficiency improvements, a feature we regard as central in any formula chosen. The weight of our evidence suggests that there are strong arguments in favour of the continuity and fine-tuning of the current formula. Given the complexity of price control regulation and the clear advances being made by regulators, we would regard the abandonment of RPI-X as being a reaction to past deficiencies. We therefore support the continuation of RPI-X incentive regulation in its broadest sense on the grounds that it is essential for the maintenance of effective incentives to efficiency but believe that further work needs to be done to improve the estimation of X. We recognise that profit-sharing has not been sufficiently developed or tested and we do not rule it out as an option for the future. We recommend that the use of RPI-X incentive regulation be continued.


87  "Utilities Regulation Consultation for Change", Professor Littlechild, Industry Forum Conference, 1995, p.8. Back

88  Ev. p.276. Back

89  "Utilities Regulation Consultation for Change", Professor Littlechild, Industry Forum Conference, 1995, p.8. Back

90  eg. Q.428; Mem. p.93. Back

91  eg. Ev. p.176; Ev. p.96. Back

92  Mem. p.31. Back

93  Mem. p.34. Back

94  eg. Mem. p.85; Ev. p.191. Back

95  Mem. p.18. Back

96  Ev. p.248. Back

97  Ev. p.276. Back

98  Ev. p.96. Back

99  Mem. p.31. Back

100  Ibid. Back

101  Ibid. Back

102  Ev. p.237. Back

103  Ev. p.313. Back

104  Ev. p.248. Back

105  eg. Mem. p.31; Ev. p.114. Back

106  eg Ev. p.324. Back


 
previous page contents next page
House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries

© Parliamentary copyright 1997
Prepared 18 March 1997