III. AGENDA 2000 (continued)
Direct payments
35. Although the extent of the support price cuts
envisaged in Agenda 2000, and of the compensatory direct
payments to producers, varies between cereals, beef and dairy,
the switch from market support to direct payments, continuing
in the direction established in the 1992 CAP reforms, forms the
kernel of Agenda 2000. We will consider the specific proposals
for each of the three regimes in our next section, but it makes
sense at this stage to subject the general principle of direct
payments to examination.
36. The Commission acknowledges that, in the cereals
sector, there has been an "over-compensation of producers
in the last few years"[27]
under the 1992 reforms, and states that, under the Agenda 2000
proposals, direct payments "will be set at an appropriate
level while avoiding any overcompensation"[28].
In particular, the non-crop specific area payment to be introduced
in the crop sector "will be lowered if the market prices
are sustained at a higher level than currently foreseen"[29].
In addition, the Commission proposes to extend to arable crops
the availability of an option for member states to make direct
payments conditional upon the observance of environmental provisions.
At various points in Agenda 2000, the Commission employs
the terminology of "direct payments", "direct income
payments" and "direct compensatory aids", though
it appears to envisage direct payments continuing to function
as compensation for lower market prices received by farmers,
despite the fact that full compensation is not proposed for cereals.
There are also signals that such payments could be further tied
to environmental conditions and "modulated" or limited
to achieve other socio-economic or budgetary objectives. Miss
Kate Timms described the language used in Agenda 2000 as
"not particularly helpful". She said that the payments
were there "to serve the purpose of compensation, buying
out change..... If that is what they are let us be honest and
candid and call them compensation..."[30].
37. The Commission does not postulate, in Agenda
2000, either an end-date for direct payments, or any decrease
in payments over time. For the Government, this is one of the
most serious weaknesses in the Commission's proposals. Mr Andy
Lebrecht, Head of MAFF's European Union Division, said that "securing
degressive payments and the eventual phasing out [of payments]"
was one of the Government's priorities in the forthcoming negotiations
over Agenda 2000[31].
A note submitted by MAFF to the European Commission sets out
the reasons behind the Government's position: "We... strongly
doubt that payments to farmers simply because they are farmers
will be tolerated by the public as a permanent feature of the
Union. For this reason, as well as to ensure that the necessary
adjustments to farm structures take place over time, they should
be degressive. Existing direct payments to farmers should be
placed on the same basis as new ones"[32].
38. Farmers' representatives were cagey on this subject.
The NFU conceded that if direct aids were to be justified as
"economic payments" they would ultimately have to be
regarded as transitional, though they were not willing to be specific
about the length of any transition period[33].
The NFU argued that the EU should not "unilaterally"
decide to make its payments degressive, and they considered that
it would be a "tactical mistake for the British Government
to make this a major issue in discussions with its EU partners"[34].
We recognize that the NFU's approach to this matter is much less
conservative than the majority of its sister farming unions throughout
the EU, but its views on the nature of direct payments do appear
to contradict their other statements in evidence to us, when they
criticize the Commission for failing to address the new constraints
on European agriculture which are likely to result from the next
round of WTO negotiations and for allowing the USA to "take
the high ground" in these negotiations[35].
39. Direct payments are being made to compensate
farmers for reduced levels of price support. An explicit recognition
that these payments to farmers are compensatory in nature must,
in our view, be accompanied by a recognition that they cannot
be permanent. We agree with the Government that the rationale
of direct payments must be to assist farmers to adjust to the
new market circumstances resulting from reductions in market support
prices. Such compensatory or adjustment aid should not be available
indefinitely to farmers. It must be time-limited, and decrease
over time. Moreover, it would be absurd to contemplate the provision
of compensatory direct payments to central and eastern European
farmers when they accede to the EU, just as it would be absurd
to provide payments to farmers in the existing 15 member states
and not their eastern colleagues once they are fully integrated
into the EU. In negotiations on the Agenda 2000 package,
the Government must be vigilant against any attempts to muddle
these clear principles.
40. The USA has effectively decoupled support for
agriculture from production and imposed a schedule for support
payments to decline and terminate, under the Federal Agricultural
Improvement and Reform Act 1996. It therefore has no interest
in prolonging the protection afforded to certain production-linked
subsidies under the so-called "blue box" provisions
of the Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture into the next round
of WTO negotiations, as we have already remarked (see paragraph
28). Because of this, and other developments, the Government
has pointed out that the EU is likely to come under strong pressure
in those negotiations to decouple support[36].
The Government's assumption was confirmed by evidence which we
received from the New Zealand and Australian Governments. The
New Zealand Government said that the direct payments proposed
in Agenda 2000 would "lock in subsidies based on inflated
production capacities.... and will therefore continue to distort
production"[37].
The Australian Government declared its intention to look for
"a move away from production-linked support with removal
of the separate so-called "blue box" domestic support"[38].
41. The UK Government's case for decoupling subsidies
from production does not rest solely on likely international pressures:
the strategy is also seen as desirable in itself "in helping
agricultural structures to adjust and become more competitive"[39].
In oral evidence Miss Timms expanded on the type of arrangements
which the Government wanted to see introduced:
"What we are anxious to see is a payment
that genuinely stands independent of all the factors of production,
ie the crop, the land. Ultimately if you are going to decouple
completely it seems to me you have got to go somewhat in the direction
that the US has gone and have a payment that is not one linked
to the farmer remaining a farmer but a payment that pays him by
virtue, if you like, of the fact that he has been a farmer but
he has no further commitment necessarily to remaining in that
business. You have got to have something that stands free and
allows him, if he chooses to continue in the business, to adjust
his business downwards as it were to world market price levels
or go out of business altogether if needs be."[40]
Strong support for the concept of decoupling direct
payments come from the Consumers in Europe Group[41],
and from the Council for the Protection of Rural England[42].
42. We sensed a degree of nervousness from representatives
of farmers and landowners about a policy which promoted the full
decoupling of support from the means of agricultural production.
Sir David Naish, then President of the NFU, said that the issue
had to be looked at "commodity by commodity"; he argued
that a move towards decoupling would have to take account of support
for agricultural and food industries throughout the world, including
in the USA[43]. The
Country Landowners' Association advocated greater decoupling of
support, including the transformation of livestock headage payments
into area payments, but baulked at the possible detachment of
support from land. Mr Tony Bailey, Director of Policy at the
CLA, thought that wholly decoupled support through, for example,
transferable income-bearing bonds, could, in circumstances where
producers ceased production and land had no alternative use, have
a direct economic impact on the value of land. He was also concerned
that the introduction of transferable bonds could result in resources
being transferred away from rural to urban areas. Nevertheless,
he conceded that detachment of compensation payments from land
could be contemplated if other resources were made available for
rural areas[44]. More
robust opposition to the strategy of decoupling compensation payments
was expressed to us by an arable and dairy farmer, Mr Malcolm
Read, who claimed that there was no logic or common sense behind
the view that decoupled payments were acceptable and production-linked
payments were not. Mr Read's strictures were not confined to
the decoupling of payments: he foresaw dire consequences, for
European farmers and consumers alike, flowing from the entire
direction of CAP reform advocated by the Government and the NFU[45].
43. Naturally the different characteristics which
direct payments might have, such as their absolute level, their
duration, any element of decrease in them, and the extent to which
they are decoupled, are all part of the same equation defining
their overall acceptability. If it were clearly understood that
payments were to be phased out over a specified period, so the
pressures for them to be decoupled would diminish. Likewise,
if payments were to be truly decoupled, they would be likely to
be protected from reductions, in WTO terms at least, by achieving
"green box" status.
44. Full decoupling of payments might produce considerable
political challenges. Even if resources were to be made available
to rural areas through agri-environmental and rural development
programmes, to supply environmental services demanded by the public
and to stimulate alternative sources of employment and income
for those currently dependent on farming, there can be no guarantee
that the overall level of resources would or should remain the
same. The recipients of agri-environmental and rural development
funding could be very different, both in terms of regions and
individuals, from the current and future recipients of compensation
payments under the 1992 CAP reforms and the reforms proposed in
Agenda 2000. Mr Read further argued that decoupled payments
would be unpopular with the public and taxpayers, and that politicians
would be able to harness this unpopularity to "reduce or
abolish the payments, leaving farmers with no support"[46].
45. We consider that, in principle, the full decoupling
of direct payments to farmers is both necessary and desirable
if European agriculture is to re-structure itself to become competitive
on world markets. However we also consider that a coherent framework
for agri-environmental and rural development policies must be
developed along with decoupling to sustain the viability of agricultural
and rural communities. Funding for such policies could flow from
reductions in decoupled direct compensation payments.
46. Agenda 2000 proposes the introduction
of "an individual ceiling covering all direct income payments
granted under the Common Market Organisations" and also indicates
that member states "would be allowed to introduce differentiation
criteria according to commonly agreed rules".[47]
The first of these proposals, for individual ceilings, appears
to represent the return, clothed in different terminology, of
the concept of "modulation" as it has generally been
understood in the UK since it formed a part of the Commission's
proposals for the 1992 MacSharry reforms - though, in the end,
only a minor element of the modulation proposal was adopted in
1992. Ceilings on direct payments have consistently been opposed
by UK Governments because farm sizes in the UK are on average
larger than in other member states (70 hectares compared with
17.5 hectares for the EU as a whole): so ceilings would mean a
disproportionately severe loss for the UK. MAFF also argued against
ceilings on the grounds that they would discourage competitiveness
and penalise relatively efficient producers.[48]
The NFU echoed these objections, and pointed out that there would
be "no direct benefits for small farmers from an aid ceiling".[49]
The arguments against capping payments, at least for so long
as they are linked to production, were succinctly summarized by
Cargill plc.[50]
47. Despite the NFU's contention that small farmers
would not benefit from a ceiling on aid to individual producers,
the Family Farmers' Association (FFA) favoured the idea of such
a ceiling. Recognising the strong objections to such a proposal,
however, they suggested possible alternatives of relating the
ceiling to the number of people supported by a business, or of
tapering payments above a certain limit. The FFA envisaged that
budgetary savings achieved by such methods could allow funds to
be re-deployed towards agri-environmental ends.[51]
Support for utilizing ceilings as part of an explicit policy
of redistributing funding, on income support grounds, from larger
to smaller farms, also came from Professor Martin Whitby of The
University of Newcastle upon Tyne.[52]
Yet to use direct payments for such redistributional purposes
would confound the logic that such payments are compensatory,
and there is no clear correlation between farm size, however measured,
and incomes of people engaged in farming.
48. The arguments that savings from the imposition
of aid ceilings could be used to pursue environmental or socio-economic
objectives appear to us to conflate the two separate proposals
from the Commission, of "ceilings" and "differentiation".
This is not surprising, as the Commission has given no details
of the reasons for each of the proposals, the level of the ceilings
which might be set or the types of "differentiation"
which might be countenanced. The Central Association of Agricultural
Valuers (CAAV) speculated about the level of the ceiling which
the Commission might have in mind, and the Commission's motives
for the inclusion of the ceilings proposal: "It is possible
that it has been included precisely to attract the attention of
the UK as a point for it to gain by conceding on other matters".[53]
Pointing out that no figures on the financial effects of the
introduction of ceilings had been given in the Agenda 2000
documents, the CAAV hypothesized that the proposal was "a
token, not ... a genuine policy tool".[54]
49. Given that the sole rationale for individual
aid ceilings would appear to be the financial savings which they
would achieve, we see no virtues in the imposition of such ceilings
which could not be better attained by reducing direct payments
gradually over time. We also consider that ceilings would militate
against the efficiency and competitiveness of UK and EU agriculture.
Though a form of "differentiation" applied at a member
state level would be more acceptable, it would still be open to
the objections that, in attempting to meet wider socio-economic
concerns through fine-tuning production-linked payments, it
would distort agricultural competitiveness both within and between
EU member states, and that it would add to the bureaucracy of
the CAP. We recognize widespread concerns about the effects
of CAP reform on smaller and family farms in this country, but
given that we see no long-term role for direct payments, we do
not consider that modulation of such payments is the appropriate
way to address these concerns. Separate agri-environmental and
rural policy instruments are the best way to deal with these problems.
50. The Agenda 2000 document holds out the
prospect of introducing "optional conditionality", or
"environmental cross-compliance", to use the jargon,
on the direct payments to be made in the crop sector:
"As is already the case in the beef and
sheep sectors, the Commission will table a proposal enabling Member
States to make the granting of direct payments for arable crops
and set-aside conditional on the respect of environmental provisions,
allowing them to be increasingly used to pursue environmental
objectives"[55].
51. The European Commission's proposals on environmental
conditionality were attacked from two different directions in
evidence to us. The Government argued that the attachment of
environmental conditions to direct payments would confer a spurious
respectability upon those payments which would decrease the likelihood
of reducing or ending them. According to the Government, environmental
objectives could be better achieved by re-directing funds from
direct payments to "precisely targeted" environmental
measures[56]. Environmental
organisations, on the other hand, in their written evidence, criticized
the Commission for failing to make environmental conditionality
mandatory, rather than optional, for member states. The Countryside
Commission described the Agenda 2000 proposal as "very
disappointing"[57];
the CPRE extolled the benefits of "applying environmental
conditions to all support payments from the public purse"[58];
and the RSPB called for the European Commission to "be pressed
to table a proposal enabling (and requiring) Member States to
introduce environmental conditions for area payments"[59].
In oral evidence, however, the environmental organisations conceded
the point that the attachment of environmental conditions to direct
payments was not the ideal solution. Dr Roger Clarke, Director
of Programmes at the Countryside Commission, for example, stated
that: "We only advocate conditionality because for the foreseeable
future most of the CAP money will go into commodity support and
it makes sense to get at least some environmental benefit out
of that"[60].
52. In their March 1997 Report on agri-environmental
schemes, the previous Agriculture Committee considered the desirability
of attaching environmental conditions to arable area payments,
in the light of concern expressed about the detrimental effects
of arable farming on the environment and wildlife in the UK.
That Committee concluded "We consider that it is essential
to strengthen or introduce cross-compliance requirements for those
subsidies which are clearly most antagonistic to environmental
benefits"[61].
However, now, Agenda 2000 points the way towards effectively
addressing agri-environmental concerns through other discrete
policy mechanisms. Should the UK Government succeed in its
objective of securing an end date for direct payments, we see
little benefit in the attachment of environmental conditions to
such payments. On the other hand, should no end date be agreed,
specific environmental conditions should be attached to direct
payments, provided that these can be defined and enforced in a
workable way. These conditions should be mandatory for all EU
member states, and infringement of the conditions by farmers should
lead to the loss of a substantial proportion of direct payments.
With financial incentives available to farmers who wish
to farm in environmentally beneficial ways, we do not consider
that it is unduly harsh to penalise farmers who cause environmental
degradation while in receipt of public funds.
Expenditure
53. The Commission's calculations of the likely effects
of the Agenda 2000 proposals on CAP expenditure show that,
even taking into account the prospect of enlargement, expenditure
will remain comfortably within the agriculture guideline, assuming
it remains defined as now, over the period 2000 to 2006. The
Commission envisages that the reforms proposed to the cereals,
beef and dairy regimes will result in savings in market support
of 3.7 billion ecu a year by 2006, with an increase in 7.7 billion
ecu a year on direct compensatory aid by the same date. Even
with additional expenditure within the agricultural guideline
on agri-environmental and rural development accompanying measures,
and on pre-accession aid and expenditure relating to the accession
of new member states, the growth in the guideline over the period
in question will lead to a safety margin, or underspend in relation
to the guideline, rising from 0.5 billion ecu in 2003 to 4.7 billion
ecu in 2006[62].
54. Most witnesses, including the Government, broadly
accepted the Commission's financial analysis, although MAFF felt
that the net increase in expenditure of 4 billion ecu predicted
by the Commission in respect of the reforms in the cereals, beef
and dairy sectors might be an over-estimate, and suggested that
it was more likely to be in the region of 2 to 3 billion ecu[63].
MAFF argued that the Commission's estimates of future expenditure
on direct payments were rather high[64].
Nevertheless, far from reducing CAP budgetary expenditure,
it is clear that the Commission, in Agenda 2000, is resigned
to increasing it. This is totally unacceptable. It could have
been avoided by reducing direct payments over time.
55. Agenda 2000 does not deal directly with
fraud and irregularity associated with CAP expenditure, but the
Government's view was that, in general, the direction of reform
proposed by the Commission would have beneficial effects in reducing
the level of fraud. MAFF stated:
"A further shift in emphasis of support
under the CAP away from market support involving intervention
buying and export refunds towards direct payments to farmers,
providing the latter are subject to controls, should help to minimise
the scope for fraudulent practices and irregularities"[65].
The outcry from farmers which greeted the introduction
of the Integrated Administration and Control System (IACS) has
now virtually subsided, and there is widespread acceptance of
the need for such controls to prevent fraud. We welcome the
fact that opportunities for fraud will decrease as reform of the
CAP progresses.
Consumers
56. Apart from a reference to the expectation that
consumers will benefit from lower prices as a result of the proposed
reforms[66], the Commission
is silent on the cost to consumers of the CAP in its current form
and the magnitude of the savings to consumers which would arise
from the implementation of the Agenda 2000 market reforms.
The latest OECD figures show that in 1996 the agricultural producer
subsidy equivalent of the EU as a whole (i.e. the value of
transfers to agriculture from EU consumers and taxpayers) amounted
to $85 billion (£54 billion), or 43 per cent of the value
of agricultural production, and of this the consumer subsidy equivalent
(i.e. the value of transfers to agriculture from EU consumers)
stood at $35.4 billion (£23 billion)[67].
MAFF estimated that, if lower market prices were to feed fully
through to the retail level, the Agenda 2000 reforms would
reduce consumer expenditure in the EU as a whole by about 10 billion
ecu (£6.77 billion). In the UK, the saving would be around
1.5 billion ecu (£1 billion)[68].
The Consumers in Europe Group translated the figures for the
consumer subsidy to producers, resulting from the artificially
high prices within Europe compared with world prices, into a sum
of £18 per week for a family of four in 1995, reducing slightly
to £16 a week in 1996[69].
57. There are uncertainties about the calculations
of the cost to consumers of the CAP. In particular, it is generally
assumed that the proposed reforms of the CAP would reduce EU exports,
which, other things being equal, could lead to an increase in
world market prices. If this were to happen, the savings to European
consumers from reduced protection would be somewhat lower, though
it is difficult to calculate this precisely. We nevertheless
find it unacceptable that the Commission has failed to provide,
as a component part of its Agenda 2000 analysis, any assessment
of the probable benefits to consumers from its reform proposals.
We also find the Commission's silence on this subject mystifying,
as the likely benefits to consumers constitute one of the strongest
arguments in favour of the direction of CAP reform advocated by
the Commission. We urge the Government to ensure that the consumer
interest is kept high on the agenda during the forthcoming negotiations
over CAP reform.
27
Agenda 2000, Vol 1, p 23 Back
28
ibid p 28 Back
29
ibid p 29 Back
30
Q 54 Back
31
Q 97 Back
32
Ev pp 11-12 Back
33
Ev p 31; Q 142 Back
34
Ev p 31 Back
35
Ev pp 30-31 Back
36
Ev p 8 Back
37
Ev p 295 Back
38
Ev p 293 para 18 Back
39
Ev p 11 Back
40
Q 61 Back
41
Ev p 68 Back
42
Ev p 100 Back
43
Qq 128-9 Back
44
Q 210 Back
45
Appendix 42 Back
46
Ev p 271 Back
47
Agenda 2000, Vol I, p 32 Back
48
Ev p 7 Back
49
Ev p 31 Back
50
Ev p 139 Back
51
Ev pp 268-269 Back
52
Ev p 167 Back
53
Ev p 186, para 7.1 Back
54
Ev ibid para 7.4 Back
55
Agenda 2000, Vol 1, p 29 Back
56
Ev p 6; Qq 94-95 Back
57
Ev p 84 (para 26) Back
58
Ev p 101 (para 10) Back
59
Ev p 111 Back
60
Q 346; see also Qq 374-382 Back
61
Second Report from the Agriculture Committee, Session 1996-97
Environmentally Sensitive Areas and other schemes under the
Agri-environment Regulation, HC45-I, 1996-97, para 110 Back
62
Agenda 2000, Vol 1 p 75 and p 87, Table 2 Back
63
Ev p 8 Back
64
ibid Back
65
Ev p 9 Back
66
Agenda 2000 Vol 1 p 27 Back
67
Agricultural Policies, Markets and Trade: Monitoring and Evaluation
1997, OECD, Paris, 1997. The sterling figures are derived
from the average exchange rate for 1996 of 1.5617 US$ = £1:
Financial Statistics, Office of National Statistics, January
1998, p 119, Table 7.1A Back
68
Ev p 9 Back
69
Qq 247-8 Back
|