PRE-BUDGET REPORT
Specific measures and principles
39. This inquiry was aimed at examining the Government's
statements on environmental taxation and the potential of the
tax system to deliver environmental objectives and encourage sustainable
development rather than an in-depth appraisal of individual measures.
However the evidence we have received on some of the measures
in the last Budget and those discussed in the Pre-Budget Report
do merit consideration and where we can draw conclusions we do
so.
40. For all environmental tax measures we conclude
that it is important that the Government produce a clear statement
of its objectives. There is potential for confusion between taxes
levied according to estimates of specific externalities but which
also have broader aims such as providing incentives for better
environmental behaviour.
VAT on domestic fuel and energy
efficiency measures
41. The imposition of VAT on domestic fuel has been
presented to us as an example of poor implementation of an environmental
tax in contrast to, for example, the introduction of the landfill
tax. VAT on domestic fuel came after little consultation. This
Government reduced the rate to 5 per cent in the July Budget at
an environmental 'cost' of 0.24 million tonnes of CO2
but a social benefit in reducing a disproportionate tax burden
on low income households. The Financial Secretary told us that
the environmental cost was compensated for by the increase in
the road fuel duty escalator.[37]
It has been argued that a better answer would be to levy even
the full rate of VAT and address the regressive effect separately.
Compensation could be delivered through the benefits system or
by introducing a tax-free energy allowance. The Treasury told
us that the justification for a reduction in the rate across the
whole population, to deal with an impact on low income households,
was the application of the overall principle of avoiding unnecessary
complexity and the potential for unintended effects within the
tax system.[38] We do
not accept that perceived demands of simplicity should override
the Government's pursuit of the integrated objectives of sustainable
development.
42. An associated issue is that of energy efficiency.
Increasing energy efficiency is a clear example of win/win policy.
Lower costs, lower emissions and social equity could all be enhanced
by encouraging business to invest in energy efficiency measures
and by addressing the UK's relatively poor quality of housing
stock in this context.[39]
The Government is committed to the reduction of VAT from 17.5
to 5 per cent on installations of energy saving materials under
certain Government schemes. On Customs and Excise's own estimates
this will have an insignificant effect on emissions of CO2
but will allow at least 40,000 homes to benefit from such improvements
each year.[40] The application
of the reduction in VAT is limited by EC VAT law. We received
a large amount of evidence from the Association for the Conservation
of Energy strongly contesting the interpretation of the EC directive
and suggesting that the real block was a lack of political will.[41]
The Financial Secretary told us that the matter had been discussed
with the European Commission and that the conclusions were the
result of the UK Government's interpretation of its legal obligations.[42]
We remain concerned at the existing anomaly whereby relative
tax levels on the consumption and conservation of energy favours
the former. This can only work against the achievement of higher
efficiency.
43. We note the Treasury's evidence on the application
of European law to the reductions of the UK's rates of VAT on
domestic fuel and power and on the installation of energy efficiency
materials under certain Government funded schemes.[43]
We also note the fact that, at the time this Report was being
prepared, the Government had not yet raised the issue of a wider
relief of VAT on energy saving materials with any other EU Member
State as was its stated intention in the Pre-Budget Report.[44]
44. We recommend that the Government pursue its
negotiations within the European Union as a matter of urgency
to widen the scope of the reduction of VAT on energy saving measures.
Over the longer term we recommend that the level of VAT on domestic
fuel and power be fully appraised as part of the response to the
UK's obligations under the Kyoto Protocol and that this appraisal
include examination of the feasibility of using a tax-free allowance
for domestic fuel and other measures to address issues of distributional
impact.
VAT on building and reclamation
45. Further candidates for action should include
the harmonisation of the rate of VAT levied on renovation and
new build. We believe the existing tax
treatment to be anomalous as it militates against the achievement
of the Government's environmental objectives for housing policy
in so far as there is a target for brownfield development. A
broader approach to these objectives would need to include incentives
to develop derelict and contaminated land.
Water pollution charges
46. We are conscious of the extensive consultation
process conducted by the DETR on this issue and the fact that
we have received no evidence on this subject from the agricultural
sector. We note the evidence we have received concerning the
large body of legislation on water quality standards (much of
it from the European Communities).[45]
However, we note the existence of water pollution charging schemes
in Germany, the Netherlands and France which appear to operate
in concert with European legislative requirements.[46]
The arguments advanced over the continuing incentive effects
of an environmental tax on water pollution, which produce improvements
over and above statutory requirements, appear to us to be compelling.
We recommend that the Government consider levying a tax on water
pollution from point sources to provide a continuing incentive
for abatement.
47. Diffuse sources of pollution, such as the use
of pesticides, by their nature are not so amenable to regulatory
control and the balance of our evidence was towards the introduction
of a uniform tax on pesticide usage. However, there was a strong
emphasis on a broad approach to addressing pesticide pollution
because of the entrenched incentives for their use in current
agricultural practice in the UK.[47]
We recommend that the Government consider a package of measures
to reduce pollution of water supplies arising from pesticides.
These should tackle both the existing incentives for the
use of large volumes of such chemicals and introduce a disincentive
in the form of a new tax.
The landfill tax
48. The landfill tax is currently under review by
Customs and Excise and its conclusions are due to be published
with, or shortly after, the Budget. We note that the Environment
Sub-Committee of the Environment, Transport and Regional Affairs
Departmental Select Committee is currently inquiring into Sustainable
Waste Management and will be reporting later in the year. Additionally
the House of Lords European Communities Committee (Sub-Committee
C) will shortly be reporting on the draft EC Landfill Directive.
49. The CBI Green Taxes Group described the landfill
tax as falling at the first hurdle in that it failed to address
the accepted externalities of methane emissions and leaching which
varied markedly between different sites.[48]
However, other witnesses, including the Environment Agency, suggested
that the value of the tax was that it began to address the relative
environmental values of the various paths for waste.[49]
The objective was not necessarily to distinguish between landfill
sites but to shift the treatment of waste up the hierarchy which
ran from landfill and incineration to recycling and ultimately,
minimisation. We note calls by a number of witnesses for an increase
in the rate of the landfill tax as well as for an extension of
its scope to include other forms of waste disposal including incineration.[50]
50. We believe that in general the introduction of
the landfill tax has been very successful, and is a good example
of the advantages of having an extended period of analysis and
consultation before introducing any environmental tax, so as to
ensure that a reasonable measure of agreement about externalities
and likely behavioural effects can be established and likely problems
identified in advance. It is not surprising however that some
teething problems have still occurred, and as with any new tax
these need to be carefully reviewed. We have received evidence
of some negative environmental effects of the tax such as increased
fly-tipping and a reduction of inert materials going to landfill
which were necessary for the safe treatment of other wastes.
We recommend that there should continue to be close monitoring
of the impacts and effectiveness of the landfill tax. This would
allow any fine-tuning needed to deal with incipient problems,
or consideration of an increase in rates, to be promptly addressed,
thereby enabling progress towards the objectives of improving
waste management practices to be optimised.
Aggregates extraction
51. Our evidence on aggregates extraction was divided.
However, we noted with interest the agreement between Friends
of the Earth and the CBI Green Taxes Working Group that the environmental
impacts of quarrying may be better addressed by regulations and
the planning system.[51]
Friends of the Earth went on to argue however, that a tax was
appropriate as well because "it provides a longer term incentive
for efficiency in the use of aggregates and can make a contribution
to shifting the burden of taxation".[52]
The Quarry Products Association said that the scope for efficiency
improvements in the use of aggregates was limited by substantial
current levels of recycling and the limited availability of satisfactory
secondary materials to suit specifications.[53]
The CBI Green Taxes Working Group told us that another consideration
was the geographical distribution of aggregates sources and warned
against addressing one environmental problem by increasing another
in the form of further pressure on the transport network.[54]
52. We note that the DETR has commissioned research
into the environmental costs attached to quarrying, and in particular
the supply of aggregates. We recommend that the research be
published and there should be full consultation undertaken to
determine to what extent a tax might be able to capture any externalities
identified therein. Consultation should also explicitly include
the question of in what ways, and to what extent, the incentive
effects of a tax might alter the practice of the aggregates and
construction industry.
Vehicle use
53. The transport sector contributes about 14 per
cent of the UK's CO2 emissions as well as a significant
amounts of other pollutants degrading local air quality. And
the problem is growing.[55]
We expect that the Government's forthcoming statements on the
Kyoto protocol, integrated transport and the advanced review of
the air quality strategy, will all contain reference to vehicle,
particularly private car, use. The use of taxation on road fuel
and the differentials applying to different fuel types, has the
potential to encourage people to use more fuel efficient vehicles
and less carbon-intensive and polluting fuels, to switch from
private to public transport, and to travel less in order to achieve
a reduction in road traffic. This has been well-argued by the
Royal Commission on Environmental Pollution and the Round Table
on Sustainable Development amongst others.[56]
Professor Davies of the CBI Green Taxes Working Group however,
told us that the he did not view duty on road fuel as an environmental
instrument and that if vehicle use caused problems of pollution
and congestion, these should be tackled directly and not by a
general tax on motoring.[57]
The Automobile Association drew attention to the high cost of
CO2 reduction through duty on road fuel compared to
estimates of tackling emissions from the industrial and domestic
sectors.[58]
54. The actual measures in the Pre-Budget Report
are modest. We welcome the scheme on vehicle excise duty (VED)
as it extends to lorries and buses. However we would like to
see consideration given to the issue in relation to private cars.
Alternative suggestions were made to us. On the one hand VED
could be abolished (except for an administrative fee) and taxation
concentrated on car usage rather than car ownership.[59]
This would have the advantages of being very progressive as well
as increasing the marginal cost of each journey relative to the
initial investment.[60]
On the other hand the profile of VED is high, as it was paid
in one lump, suggesting that incentive effects of a differential
based on pollutants and CO2 emissions might be significant.
VED could be targeted on engine size and efficiency and emissions
rating. The distributional impact would need examination as older
cheaper cars tend to be more polluting although they also tend
to have smaller engines.[61]
The Royal Society for the Protection of Birds submitted a detailed
report on this matter commissioned from the Institute for European
Environmental policy.[62]
55. Other witnesses mentioned the perverse incentives
in company car taxation. The system rewards drivers for driving
further and the full value of complimentary fuel is not taxed
(we would add the provision of free parking to this list). As
Friends of the Earth put it "it is difficult to find a better
example of where the tax system does exactly the opposite to the
Government's aims of sending clear signals about which economic
activities it wishes to encourage."[63]
The Committee was delighted to hear Mr Michael Roberts of the
CBI Green Taxes Group say that in business "there is an appetite
for change where there is felt to be fiscal distortion, particularly
in the transport market".[64]
56. We believe that the duty on road fuel, and the
escalation of its rate, acts to check the overall growth of an
activity at a rate that has serious consequences for public health,
environmental standards and economic efficiency. The specific
externalities of the emissions of pollutants and CO2
and of congestion should also be addressed directly and we look
to the Government's eagerly awaited documents on climate change,
transport and air quality to tackle these issues head on. It
is vital however, that these matters are addressed in the round
and account is taken of those sectors of society, particularly
those people on lower incomes living in rural areas, who depend
on cars for access to vital services. Account should also be
taken of these issues in considering other Government policies
which may place important services out of reach except by the
use of private motor transport. In particular we recommend
that:
- the Government should fully appraise the environmental
effects of introducing differentials to the rate of vehicle excise
duty based around emission standards for regulated pollutants
and for CO2 as well as engine size and efficiency;
- the Government should appraise the incentive
effects of higher rates of escalation on road fuel duty and take
account of the most up to date scientific evidence in setting
the differentials; and
- in the light of the growing consensus we have
identified the Government should address the perverse incentives
in the taxation of company cars as part of its integrated transport
policy if not sooner.
To realise fully the benefits of these measures
the integrated transport strategy must match steady increases
in the overall cost of motoring with steady improvements in the
availability of real alternatives in the form of better public
transport, more energy efficient vehicles and alternative fuels.
Conclusion
57. We accept that the introduction of environmental
taxes must allow for the application of all the analytical rigour
and full consultation that the Treasury and other witnesses have
emphasised. We agree with the need for a holistic approach which
takes account of effects on both social equity and competitiveness
as well as existing regulatory and voluntary arrangements. We
welcome signs that the tax system is on notice to deliver environmental
objectives and we urge the Government to approach the complementary
subjects of environmentally damaging subsidies and incentives
to invest in environmental technologies as part of its strategic
approach. We believe that our conclusions and recommendations,
set out above, will assist in this process and in the Government's
reporting to Parliament thereon.
37
Q14 Back
38
Q15 Back
39
Ev p17 Back
40
'Energy Saving Materials: The Scope for a Reduced Rate of VAT',
Customs and Excise (26 November 1997), p12. Back
41
Appendix 8, pp70-82 Back
42
Q13 Back
43
Ev p106, paragraphs 14 & 15 Back
44
HC Deb, 25 February 1998, col 234, wa Back
45
Ev p94 Back
46
'Economic Instruments for Water Pollution' Department of Environment,
Transport and the Regions, November 1997, annex 3. Back
47
Ev pp60-1 & 64 Back
48
Q66 Back
49
Ev p51 Back
50
Ibid, & p62 Back
51
Ev p61 and Q67 Back
52
Ev p61 Back
53
Ev p83 Back
54
Q67 Back
55
Ev p96 Back
56
See for example 20th and 18th reports form
the Royal Commission on Environmental Pollution, (Cms. 3752 and
2674). Back
57
Q79 Back
58
Ev p96-7 Back
59
QQ61-2 Back
60
Q60 Back
61
Ev p62 Back
62
'Greening Vehicle Excise Duty', Institute for European Environmental
Policy. Back
63
Ev p62 Back
64
Q91 Back
|