Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Examination of witnesses (Questions 60 - 79)

TUESDAY 17 FEBRUARY 1998

MR ROBIN FELLGETT, MR RICHARD MANNING, MR ANDREW STEELE, AND MR NICK WESTCOTT

  60.  That answer is very helpful. Up to now I had not understood the position. Does Germany also take the IMF line?
  (Mr Westcott)  Gold sales in Germany is a very sensitive political issue, in part because of Germany's history of hyper-inflation in the 1920s and 1930s. There are good domestic political reasons why Germany is nervous about gold sales.

  61.  Rather like the question of Japanese indebtedness?
  (Mr Manning)  Both the Japanese and Germans tend to the view that if they lend people money they are more careful of the money than they would be if they had been given it. There is a feeling that money is valued more if it is lent rather than given, and they have a preference for loans over grants. I do not think that that really applies to us. If one is providing money economically people will value it whether one gives it or lends it. The Germans and Japanese also finance their aid programmes in a way that depends on money being revolved. In part, the Japanese programme is financed by the post office savings bank, so Japan may use sources of money other than taxpayers' money.

Chairman

  62.  All that you have said comes down to the very basic question: Who pays? Who is to suffer the loss? If the IMF says that it cannot suffer the loss it must be replaced by gold sales; the World Bank says that it cannot suffer the loss because it does not do it that way and therefore there must be further subscriptions to the World Bank, usually by the subterfuge of using IDA money, to which I object very strongly. Even that must be repaid. The whole question comes down to who pays. Presumably, ECGD has a reserve against default which it earns by charging extra interest rates on all loans.
  (Mr Steele)  Most of the debts that we are talking about today are so-called account 1 debts. In 1991— a bit before my time in ECGD, and so I speak under advisement to some extent—in the light not least of the debt crisis of the `eighties it was decided to split the accounts into three. The so-called account 1 was basically business written before 1991. Essentially, that is the debt of which we are speaking today. That account essentially is bust in the sense that the claims paid out totalling several billion pounds—some of which we are talking about today - were much more than the amounts that ECGD had put aside to pay claims. Generally speaking, for many years we have been making provisions against the likelihood of loss. When we consider forgiveness we consider it in terms of proper financial management, as ECGD's accounting officer must do. He is forming a judgment about whether post-forgiveness the value of the remaining debt in our books has increased by forgiving a certain amount of that debt; in other words, whether the likelihood of the repayment of the remaining debt is greater. Essentially, that is the judgment that we must make in considering forgiveness in the Paris Club and elsewhere. A major part of that judgment is based on the sustainability of the debt position of the debtor country concerned post-forgiveness.

  63.  So, you are also concerned with who pays or gets the blow?
  (Mr Steele)  Yes.

Mrs Kingham

  64.  What is your view of what went wrong in relation to Mozambique? You have explained why structurally the process could not proceed. Does it mean that there is no future for the initiative, or was that problem specific to Mozambique as a country?
  (Mr Fellgett)  Perhaps I may bring you up to date with where we are with Mozambique. The issue of whose accounts bear the loss is important. It was agreed that each individual country within the Paris Club, including the United Kingdom, would bear the loss up to their previously highest rate of forgiveness (67 per cent). Beyond that, the loss would be borne equally by all creditors, not just bilateral government creditors within the Paris Club but also the IMF, World Bank, the African Development Bank and the other regional development banks equally in proportion to their claims. Someone who had twice the claims would bear twice the loss. In percentage terms it was all equal. That was never specified in the precise terms that I have just described but that was the flavour of what was agreed. Assuming that the figures are reliable—as I said at the beginning, that is always an unwise assumption—that will work for all except a tiny number of countries, one of which (perhaps the only one) is Mozambique where that kind of approach to sharing the cost runs straight into the buffer that the Paris Club has agreed to forgive only up to 80 per cent. The view of the Government is that that buffer must be overridden. We have agreed a process here under which unpayable or unsustainable debts are written off so that the country is in a position to pay what is left. Eighty per cent is not a magic figure. In the case of Mozambique the required figure that I have seen—it may not be accurate—is 88 per cent. We believe that that is what we should do. Unfortunately, not all members of the Paris Club are persuaded of that position. The Paris Club operates by consensus; everyone must agree, so each member has a veto. People are discouraged from using it if it means a vote of 19 to one. What was agreed with considerable difficulty was that the Paris Club would do a number of additional things to bring the gap down to about US$100 million. The Paris Club will move to 80 per cent and then do a variety of other things which mean that the level is equivalent to 85 per cent. It needs to go to 88 per cent. The remaining gap is equivalent to about US$100 million worth of debt relief for Mozambique. The Government now seek to ensure that that gap is filled as quickly as possible by whatever are the best means. One is talking about US$100 million split between up to 20 creditors. This is a philosophical debate, not a debate about money.

Chairman

  65.  What you are saying is that negotiations continue and that you have some hope that the situation may be resolved. In the context of the subject-matter with which we are dealing it does not sound like a lot of money, although personally it is a large figure. You believe that it is soluble, so you do not believe that this is the end of the Paris Club procedures?
  (Mr Fellgett)  I believe that progress on Mozambique has been disappointing, if I may use parliamentary terms. I have used stronger language inside and outside the Paris Club. The international community has not delivered what it agreed at the IMF and World Bank meetings.

Dr Tonge

  66.  That was the target of 88 per cent?
  (Mr Fellgett)  It had the implication of 88 per cent. Clearly, that has damaged the credibility of the Paris Club process. My colleagues are working as hard as they can to ensure that that gap is filled. I believe that in practice some of the money will have to be found by the World Bank and/or IMF. That is the only way to complete the process, which is already overdue for Mozambique, as quickly as possible. The UK Government are willing to put in some additional money. My colleagues in DfID have already agreed that about US$17 million worth of assistance to Mozambique will be in the form of a payment into their trust fund for debt repayment. The Secretary of State for International Development announced before Christmas that the UK was willing to help finance the African Development Bank's contribution to this process. That is a bank which has no resources of its own. She and the Chancellor are to announce this morning that as part of the resolution of the problem the UK will contribute unilaterally, as it were—to set an example and encourage others—up to another US$10 million to fill the US$100 million gap, with the aim of ensuring that the process is completed for this country, which is perhaps the most deserving case of all, with the minimum further delay. Has this damaged the process? I hope not. The running up against the buffers of the 80 per cent in the Paris Club ought not to be a problem for at least the great majority of other countries that must be considered. The numbers are different and 80 per cent should be enough as Mozambique is resolved and the process moves on to other countries. Although it has received almost no publicity, the case of Guyana was ticked off very quickly and simply over the Christmas period. I hope that the process will get back on track. That is the Government's strong wish, to put it mildly. I am cautiously optimistic about it. There is some spotlight on the Paris Club to show that it will play ball in the next few cases and that it will not run into the same kind of problem.

Chairman

  67.  Mr Manning, this is the second time I have heard of the aid budget being used to pay off debts to the African Development Bank. I happen to know that the African Development Bank was lending very injudiciously in the quite recent past to countries that could not possibly repay at interest rates that they could not possibly meet. Why are we rewarding the African Development Bank with our precious aid money in this way?
  (Mr Manning)  I would not characterise it as a reward for the African Development Bank. We would not be doing this unless we had confidence in the new management of the African Development Bank that it is now set on a sustainable policy course. Indeed, there are meetings to take place in Washington later this week at which the non-regional members of the African Development Bank will consider what more that bank needs to do to provide a degree of confidence required to supplement its capital. This takes one back to the difficult question of governance and decision-taking in the African Development Bank. We believe that Mr Kabbaj, the new president of the African Development Bank, is doing an excellent job in very difficult circumstances. We believe that it is right to enable the bank to play its part where necessary. It is important to keep the bank engaged in the process along with the World Bank and IMF. That is why the decision was taken to make a contribution in the case of Uganda and in principle to make a contribution of a size yet to be determined in relation to Mozambique.

  68.  Did you not have a director on the board of the African Development Bank when it was lending injudiciously?
  (Mr Manning)  We have a director on the board of that bank. The problem with that bank rather than other regional banks is that, as you rightly say, it has lent to countries which are not creditworthy for the kind of funds that it has made available. Certainly, the board should have seen it coming, as it were. The difficulty arises from the way that the board of the African Development Bank operates and the relatively weak position of the non-regional directors in relation to decision-taking. Those are the kinds of issues that need to be properly addressed in relation to the proposed capital increase.

  69.  One must pursue at another time the question of how one controls these development banks. It raises very serious questions. Your department keeps putting before Parliament renewals for these banks with no explanation as to what the policy has been and whether or not they are worthy of support. I think that that is a very serious question facing both Parliament and you.
  (Mr Manning)  We would be very happy to respond to that. We shall make sure that we look carefully at the memoranda that we put forward in future.

Ms King

  70.  I should like to underline some of the concerns raised earlier about structural adjustment programmes and their ability to stimulate growth. As to who is giving money to whom, it is helpful if we remember the context of the debate, which is the situation since the onset of the debt crisis. In the decade between 1981 and 1991 there was a net transfer in terms of flows from the poor countries of the south to the rich countries of the north equivalent to five times the Marshall Plan. I think that it is instructive to bear that in mind when making judgments in this area. One of the key criticisms that has been levelled is about the requirement of a six-year period of structural adjustment. NGOs argue that that is an unnecessarily long period of time. First, will the Government advocate a reduction in that period? Secondly, why cannot relief be given after three years at the decision point as opposed to six years at the point of completion?
  (Mr Fellgett)  Can the Government advocate a shorter period? The answer is that they have done so, and they continue to do so. To be one of a very large number of countries in these decisions is always frustrating. Everything is a compromise. What was agreed by the boards of the IMF and World Bank and Ministers and governors at the interim and development committees was that the process of getting full HIPC relief would depend on two three-year stages with a so-called decision point in the middle but that exceptionally the period could be shorter taking account of countries' existing track records. In practice, so far it has been possible to agree that the full six years should not be applied in any case. While we continue to feel that six years is in general too long, rather than argue the general point, especially as we can continue to agree rather shorter periods in practice as each case arises, we hope that you can be modestly reassured on the practice. However, undoubtedly if you read the documents they say that the HIPC process lasts for six years.

  71.  So, it is the practice at this point effectively to give money after the three-year period?
  (Mr Fellgett)  The practice varies from country to country. In the case of Mozambique, the second three-year period will in practice be one and a half years.

  72.  Does that mean that it will receive debt relief after a period of four and a half years?
  (Mr Fellgett)  Perhaps I may first outline the process. The idea is that for the first three years the country receives a reduction of up to 67 per cent from the Paris Club year by year. The amount to be paid can be as little as one third of the notional amount due each year. That happens year by year. At the end of the three years the so-called decision point arrives. Then decisions are made as to what is to happen in another three years' time. During the next three years—we have not had a three-years second phase so far—what is available from the Paris Club is a reduction of up to 80 per cent year by year, together with relief from the World Bank. At the end of the second period there is a facility to write down the most outstanding debt.

  73.  Are you satisfied that in practice the concerns raised here are dealt with?
  (Mr Fellgett)  So far it has proved possible to agree reasonable periods for these decisions and final implementation following year-by-year write-offs.
  (Mr Manning)  Clearly, it raises a question as to whether the country between the decision point and the completion point, it having demonstrated virtue if you like, is helped through the period. In the case of Uganda, all its multilateral debt service up to the completion point is being met by a variety of bilateral donor-funded initiatives.

  74.  My next question is about the eligibility criteria for HIPCs. Are they unrealistically high? You will be aware that they have been the subject of criticism. I understand that no account is taken of the private commercial debts of debtor countries. First, do you believe that the current eligibility criteria are a reliable measure of debt sustainability? Secondly, is the threshold set at a realistic level?
  (Mr Fellgett)  As far as eligibility is concerned, the agreed initiative followed the outcome of analytic work by staff primarily in the World Bank and IMF. There was then discussion by all countries represented there by executive directors. One has a layer of political compromise among a large number of countries on top of the analysis made by staff. For example, Oxfam has produced some cogently argued material suggesting that some of this is not good enough both in terms of eligibility and sustainability. Can a country like Mozambique really afford to pay as much as 20 per cent of its export earnings in debt service? First, there is a risk that if we go back to the foundations and disturb the compromise we will have no action. Even if the case for some change is clear to go back to the drawing board and renegotiate will result in the process stopping for a period. That is something about which people from debtor countries whom I meet feel quite strongly. They believe that even if the process does not give them absolutely everything that they want on the whole it gives them a lot and they prefer the process to run rather than stop.

Chairman

  75.  You also indicated that with all these targets and the periods involved when an examination is made case by case these criteria are modified. Is that the case with the two figures that you have given?
  (Mr Fellgett)  The two sustainability targets are that the total amount of a country's official debt should not be more than twice its annual export earnings and that the amount of its actual official debt payments in any single year should not exceed 20 per cent. In practice, what my colleagues in finance ministries in developing countries care most about are their annual payments. What do they have to find out of their budgets this year for debt servicing? In practice that figure is significantly lower than 20 per cent in nearly all cases. What tends to happen is that the 200 per cent target for the overall amount of debt reduces debt to the point where the annual payments come in at under 20 per cent because it is under 20 per cent over a very long period, certainly in the case of Mozambique. That is not so for every country. To go back to the Oxfam paper which argues for a lower amount of debt for Mozambique, what has been agreed on a preliminary basis—it must be confirmed—in the boards of the World Bank and IMF is that the so-called completion point at which Mozambique's debt is finally dealt with in a comprehensive way rather than on the basis of a year-by-year write down will arise prior to the earliest date at which the Cahora Bassa dam can start to produce electricity again for export. It has the practical effect that if the Cahora Bassa dam begins to produce electricity again Mozambique's export earnings will go up but no account would be taken of that in deciding the amounts. It is all a question of what is tackled head on and what one plays ad hoc. That is not to say that my friends in Oxfam, to whom I spoke as often as I could in my previous job, think that the result is perfect.

Ms King

  76.  Do you think that the threshold is at a realistic level?
  (Mr Fellgett)  I think that in practice we can deliver a realistic result.

Chairman

  77.  Mr Manning, are we doing anything to bring the Cahora Bassa dam on stream?
  (Mr Manning)  Subject to checking, I do not think that we are assisting under the bilateral aid programme. Perhaps other funds are going in.

  78.  CDC was an investor?
  (Mr Manning)  I shall check.[5]

Ms King

  79.  There is also a question about some of the measurements of debt sustainability, in particular the vulnerability factors such as crop dependency. Can you give examples of other vulnerability factors and in practice how they are taken into account?
  (Mr Fellgett)  To the best of my recollection, so far the dependence of a country on a single export crop is the main factor. Uganda and coffee is an example. The way that the process is structured is that the debt sustainability target is meant to be set in a range from 200 to 250 per cent. The remaining amount of debt should be somewhere between two and two and a half times annual export earnings. The vulnerability of the country is an argument for pushing it to the 200 per cent end rather than the other. That argument was used for Uganda. In addition, because of the volatility of coffee prices the export earnings from coffee were calculated over a period to avoid distortion of the figures by taking one year rather than another. There was a pretty intense discussion between my colleagues in the finance ministry in Kampala and ourselves and other creditors, including the IMF and World Bank, over that exceedingly obscure statistic. How does one smooth coffee prices? Since then, on the whole the decisions have been to give the maximum relief available under the initiative towards the 200 per cent rather than the 250 per cent end. In a sense, the "vulnerability" arguments have not been as important as might have been thought. But I believe that it was very important for Uganda as the first country; otherwise, I doubt whether it would have done as well as it did under the process.
  (Mr Westcott)  There is one elaboration of the eligibility criteria. Where one has a poor country that is HIPC eligible but has very high exports, as some do, the additional criterion of fiscal sustainability is introduced such that debt payments do not exceed a certain level of a country's tax revenue. This applies mainly to one country—the Ivory Coast - because it has a very export-oriented economy. It was regarded as unfair to penalise that country because of that since such a large proportion of its GDP was in exports. It has been adapted in that way to take account of some countries that are vulnerable in that respect.
  (Mr Fellgett)  To date, Guyana is the main beneficiary of that change.


5   See Evidence, pp. 21-22. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries

© Parliamentary copyright 1998
Prepared 14 May 1998