DEPARTMENT OF THE ENVIRONMENT, TRANSPORT
AND THE REGIONS: THE HOME ENERGY EFFICIENCY SCHEME
THE
DEPARTMENT'S
AGREEMENT
WITH
EAGA
16. Eaga were set up by NEA, a national energy charity,
specifically to administer the Scheme. The Department awarded
the initial contract to administer the Scheme to Eaga in 1990
following competitive tendering. A second contract, which ran
from April 1993 to March 1996, was awarded on a single tender
basis, as was the current contract awarded in April 1996 which
runs until March 2001.[23]
By March 1997 Eaga had received fees totalling £23.8 million,
excluding Value Added Tax. Over the same period they made surpluses
and other net income totalling £4.9 million, of which
£1.3 million was paid in tax and £0.55 million
was paid to the Eaga Charitable Trust. The remaining £3 million
was held in Eaga's reserves.[24]
17. We asked the Department about the level of Eaga's
surpluses and reserves and whether these were reasonable. The
Department took the view that in principle Eaga should be allowed
to make a surplus, provided that it was at a reasonable level,
because they needed an incentive to do the work well. Whilst Eaga
could not distribute their surpluses as dividends they could donate
them to charity or use them to develop their business against
the possibility that they lost the contract in 2001. The surplus
had built up at a rate of £0.5 million a year, a rate
which the Department regarded as fair. The Department's consultants
had also concluded that the surplus was reasonable when Eaga's
contract was last renewed.[25]
18. The Department told us that whilst they were
satisfied with the position to date, they recognised that there
ought to be an understanding of what would happen if this accumulation
of surplus accelerated.[26]
They acknowledged that it was possible that Eaga would make a
lot more money if, for example, the number of grants fell because
of a sharp increase in the number of people applying for cavity
wall insulation, or if the Department's current review resulted
in significant change to the size or scope of the Scheme.[27]
If the surplus exceeded current levels the Department would be
concerned. In those circumstances they would seek a re-negotiation
of the agreement.[28]
Such a re-negotiation would be voluntary, but since the Department
provided 80 per cent of Eaga's business they had significant
power. The Department assured us that the nature of the relationship
with Eaga was such that if Ministers were dissatisfied and thought
that Eaga's operating margin was excessive, there should not be
any difficulty in reaching agreement.[29]
19. We noted that Eaga's surpluses had been very
much higher in 1995-96. The Department explained that this was
the year in which there was a surge of applications from the over-60s
before they were taken out of the Scheme, and Eaga's surplus had
been about £1 million. On the basis of 1994-95 and 1996-97
figures it seemed likely that a £0.5 million surplus would
prove to be the norm. The Department told us that they expected
the surplus in 1997-98 to be about the same as it was in 1996-97.
Moreover, the surplus as a proportion of Eaga's turnover was lower
in 1996-97 than in 1995-96, and they expected it to be lower again
in 1997-98.[30]
20. The Department told us that they had changed
the Scheme and Eaga's fees structure, but that it was not yet
possible to see the results from that change. Their latest contract
included an "inflation minus X" formula that was not
in the previous contract, which would mean that over the life
of the contract Eaga would have to accommodate a fee reduction
in real terms, amounting to some four percentage points less than
inflation.[31] As a result,
whereas the fee per grant in 1996-97 had been £12.53, the
Department expected it to be something like £11.90 or £12.00
in 1997-98.[32] The Department
believed the fee per grant could well come down further thereafter,
and they would continue to keep this under review.[33]
21. Eaga's fee was calculated on the basis of the
value rather than the number of grants paid. The Department's
consultants had concluded in 1995 that this arrangement did not
provide an incentive to Eaga to control the cost of grant payments.
However, the Department had chosen not to take the advice of their
consultants.[34] They
told us that the decision to relate the fee to the total value
rather than the volume of grants had, with hindsight, proved to
be a good thing because the reduction in VAT on energy efficiency
services from 17.5 per cent to five per cent
from April 1998 meant that for the same money Eaga would
have to administer about ten per cent more grants than they
had done in the current year. We pointed out that the Department
could have related the fee level on a diminishing scale to the
volume of grants, to take accounts of the benefits of scale.[35]
22. By March 1997 Eaga held £1.3 million in
a designated reserve to meet the cost of redundancies should there
be any significant reduction in the level of its operations and
to fund a diversification strategy, and £1.7 million in a
general reserve not allocated to any specific purpose.[36]
If Eaga's surpluses continued at current levels, by 2001 their
reserves would grow to some £5 million. Since designated
reserves, intended to pay for possible redundancies and to develop
the business, could be expected to stay fairly constant at their
current level of £1.3 million, reserves for unspecified
purposes could rise to £3.7 million. We asked whether
the Department might not require Eaga to use these surpluses and
reserves to provide energy efficiency measures for eligible households,
and how many households might stand to benefit. The Department
told us that the £3 million currently in Eaga's reserves
would pay for energy efficiency measures in some 20,000 additional
homes in a single year. However, it had been money earned by the
contractor, and it was not the Department's money.[37]
23. The Department had not included any claw-back
provision in Eaga's contract, despite awarding it on a single
tender basis. The Department told us that at that stage they had
not seen the need to have such a claw-back, and in view of the
Eaga's current rate of operating surplus it was still doubtful
whether there was need for a claw-back.[38]
The Treasury said that it would be concerned if there were a continued
increase in the size of Eaga's surplus and the Department were
not able to take action by claw-back or other means, but this
was not their impression of the current position.[39]
24. Eaga have transferred around £0.5 million
to the Eaga Charitable Trust.[40]
We asked about the Trust's status and the extent to which Eaga
and the Trust promoted each other's work. Eaga said that the Trust
were entirely independent, with a separate Chairman and Board
of Trustees. Eaga promoted the Scheme directly through those organisations
that came into day to day contact with households in the qualifying
groups. In contrast, the Trust's aim was to promote better understanding
of fuel poverty, its causes and effects and how it could best
be alleviated, and they hoped that their work would assist policy
development.[41] The
Department assured us that they were satisfied that the Trust
had put their resources into causes that the Department supported.[42]
25. The Committee asked why the Department had decided
in 1996 to give the contract to Eaga on a single tender basis
rather than on a competitive basis. The Department told us that
they believed that Eaga had been doing a good job. There was also
excess demand for the Scheme at that time, with a waiting list
of 30 weeks, and the Department were worried that a change from
one contractor to another would make that situation worse. Finally,
they had not found any alternative contractor likely to bid and
were conscious of the risk that in the absence of a credible competitor
Eaga might bid a higher price than the Department had negotiated.[43]
26. The Department assured us that in 1996 they had
made it clear that when the contract came up for renewal in 2001
it would be awarded after competition. In the lapse of time between
1996 and 2001 there would have been five more years of contracting
out and of the Private Finance Initiative, and more operators
who could run this kind of contract might well have come into
existence. The Department would certainly advertise the competition.[44]
The Treasury confirmed that they had reluctantly agreed to single
tender action in 1996, and were looking to the Department to introduce
competition at the end of the current contract period.[45]
27. Eaga's articles of association prevent the company's
reserves from being distributed as dividends or in any other way
to the members of the company. Upon winding up or dissolution,
any remaining assets could not be paid to the members of the company
but must be given or transferred to some institution having similar
objects. Eaga told the Committee that this included, for example,
organisations such as NEA and the Eaga Charitable Trust, although
Eaga judged that there were many organisations consistent with
these objectives.[46]
We asked whether the Department had any legal right to those reserves.
The Department told us that they did not, since the relationship
was not between a government department and a non departmental
public body, but between a government department and a contractor.[47]
Conclusions
28. We are concerned at the reserves which Eaga have
already accumulated, which appear well in excess of those needed
for Eaga to meet their contractual liabilities and to fund their
diversification strategy. By March 1997 Eaga had total reserves
of £3 million, including £1.7 million not allocated
to any specific purpose. At current rates of surplus, these reserves
will continue to grow by £0.5 million a year.
29. It is surprising that the Department do not consider
Eaga's surpluses, which could be used to fund more grants to householders,
to be a cause for concern. We are concerned that, in spite of
the single tender arrangements, no claw-back provisions were made
should Eaga's surplus prove excessive. We are not persuaded that
the Department's reliance on voluntary re-negotiation of fees,
should Eaga's profits be judged to be excessive, is sufficient
to safeguard public funds.
30. The Committee note the Department's justification
for their decision to award the administration contract to Eaga
on a single tender basis in 1996, but look to the Department to
take steps which will ensure that there is genuine competition
for Eaga when the contract comes up for renewal in 2001. We believe
that the Department should include a provision for claw-back in
their contract with Eaga and any successor, to be deployed should
their surpluses prove higher than is considered reasonable.
31. Eaga's constitution includes specific provisions
which circumscribe what can be done with their surpluses or assets
on wind up. Nonetheless, we are concerned that the Department
would have no share or influence in the distribution of Eaga's
assets should they be wound up.
23 C&AG's Report paras 1.8 and 3.2 Back
24
C&AG's Report paras 3.6 and 3.13-3.14 Back
25
Qs 33, 67, 150, 201, 210 and 212 Back
26
Q 67 Back
27
Q 222 Back
28
Qs 33, 67 and 140 Back
29
Qs 141-142 and 207-210 Back
30
Qs 68, 139, 182-184 and 197 Back
31
Qs 185 and 216 Back
32
Q 192 Back
33
Qs 217 and 221 Back
34
C&AG's Report paras 3.8-3.9 Back
35
Qs 193-195 Back
36
C&AG's Report para 3.14 Back
37
Qs 144-148, 174-178 and 195-202 Back
38
Q 143 Back
39
Q 154 Back
40
C&AG's Report para 3.13 Back
41
Qs 30-32 Back
42
Q 72 Back
43
Qs 223-224 Back
44
Qs 4, 166 and 168 Back
45
Qs 164-165 Back
46
Qs 227-230 Back
47
Q 202 Back
|