Select Committee on Social Security Second Report


APPENDIX 4 (continued)

VISIT TO WASHINGTON AND WISCONSIN 1-5 DECEMBER 1997

10. AMERICAN FEDERATION OF LABOUR-CONGRESS OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATIONS (AFL-CIO)
Mr Marc Baldwin Assistant Director, Public Policy Department
Mr Chris Owens Senior Policy Analyst

  The AFL-CIO was broadly supportive of the President's welfare initiatives. They had concerns about worker substitution and ex-welfare recipients being used to depress wages or to weaken unions.

  The US economy as a whole was performing well and jobs were being created. The overall picture masked some pockets of high unemployment in certain geographical areas (mostly those formerly dependent on heavy industry) and among certain groups of workers. For example, for women without high school graduation, some pockets of unemployment over 10 per cent existed. It was important to ascertain what was the true picture on the ground before the welfare initiatives began, if accurate evaluation was to be made.

  There were various tax credit incentives for employers to take on employees but these had variable take-up rates and employers usually applied for credits after employing someone to do the job, rather than them being an incentive in deciding to employ the worker in the first place. Subsidies and incentives appeared most useful if linked with in-work training.

  The AFL-CIO had identified two basic forms of economic development:

Low road - low wages
- few rights for employees
High road - anti-poverty strategy
- training schemes and
- in-work support

  Within training schemes, there was currently an emphasis on life skills and employability skills yet the work ethic was only a small part of the problem for the unemployed/welfare recipients. AFL-CIO saw its main role to focus on better wages and conditions.

  AFL-CIO President Sweeney had initially wanted the President to use his veto on the 1996 Act but the AFL-CIO had accepted that there was a consensus among its members, and the population as a whole, that people should work whenever that was possible. There was however not a full consensus on exactly who should be compelled to work and how this should be facilitated.

  The true test of the reforms would be if an economic downturn occurred. In fact, some areas already did not have sufficient jobs for all welfare recipients and the Republican mayor of Philadelphia had already questioned whether the present scheme was feasible.

  There were already tensions between the different levels of jurisdictions: State (Governors) -v- County -v- City (Mayors).

  There was not much evidence on whether the existence of the EITC depressed wages. The EITC was well accepted because it was seen as part of the tax system, unconnected to welfare handouts. The EITC made no demands on employers and its impact on wages was spread further up the income scale, above the poverty level. The minimum wage had declined in real terms and it was this that had led to in-work poverty. There was no real evidence for the view that lower real value of the minimum wage had led to a greater number of jobs being created. A higher minimum wage might actually have created jobs by boosting demand in areas where many people lived on minimum wage incomes.

  The 1996 Act was only part of the picture; President Clinton had launched initiatives that the AFL-CIO greatly welcomed. These included greater employee protection, $3 billion job creation schemes and resisting privatisation of human services administration.

  The jobs gap analysis concerned the numbers of people expected to join the workforce and the number of jobs likely to be available. The difference in the jobs gap, other factors that needed to be accounted for were education, training and special needs support. Coalitions of businesses and government had come together to undertake the America Works project which intended to provide jobs for people in a particular locality but such initiatives tended to be limited in scale.

  The definition of work activity was very narrowly drawn. The result was that in some instances, education and training was not counted as an acceptable work activity and some people had had to give up their courses which appeared counter-productive to welfare to work aims. States could vary the numbers in education who were deemed to be in acceptable work activity.

  The AFL-CIO worked directly with employers worked positively with employers to promote work credits, the EITC and child support initiatives.

  As for the wider political environment affecting trades unions, a recent strike concerning UPS had had widespread public support, partly perhaps because people could relate to the issues of part-time, contract and temporary working. The AFL-CIO had been initially hostile to the growth of part-time jobs but had had to accept reality and now negotiated for a better deal for part-timers.

  There were concerns from existing workers and a belief that increasing numbers of welfare workers would dilute rights for all: this had to be monitored. In the last 25 years union membership had been falling, possibly hastened by anti-union policies pursued under Presidents Reagan and Bush between 1980 and 1992. The union movement regarded President Clinton as much more union-friendly and the decline in membership had now halted. People were perhaps aware that wages at the bottom end of the workforce had dropped and workers in the middle were therefore more fearful of dropping down themselves.

  The Conference of Mayors had recently discussed welfare reforms and had focussed on the need for decent pay and conditions for those who worked hard.

  The issue of medicare costs was very important in getting people off welfare. The loss of medicare acted as a deterrent (an unemployment trap) for people moving into low paid jobs without attached medical insurance. The problem of the working poor could come to be seen as more important than those of welfare recipients.

11. HERITAGE FOUNDATION
Mr Robert Rector Senior Policy Analyst

  Mr Rector introduced himself as the individual who crafted the Welfare Reconciliation Act legislation, based on ideas borrowed from Wisconsin. The background to the changes was job creation at the macro-economic level, but a growing problem of dependence. There was concern about values because welfare recipients were subject to cultural poverty and an eroded work ethic. The institution of marriage was eroded and with successive generations of a family on welfare there was a need to disrupt that culture. It was necessary to affect those values directly. Marriage or teen abstinence could not by themselves take a million people off the welfare rolls. Education and training programmes were a political teddy bear, exemplified by the dictum from President Johnson's War on Poverty that it was better to teach a man how to fish than to give him a fish to eat. Despite the wide initial support for this approach, it did not work and had no effect on the welfare caseload. The JTP Act allowed for a controlled evaluation of individuals randomly assigned to training or jobs. Male trainees improved their outcomes by zero per cent, and females by only three per cent. These programmes did not produce the results that were needed.

  Evaluation had been carried out over several years. On the job training in the form of workfare was effective. Classroom training, directed at a population which during years of elementary and high school had mastered the art of sitting in a classroom and learning nothing, was not. School education produced people who could not read and write very well. Training was being used as a mechanism to avoid work. Since the early 1970s $68 billion of taxpayers' money had been spent on education and training, but it had not led to reduced dependence on welfare. Workfare had been advocated since 1970 but was not practised until the past 3 or 4 years. Since then the AFDC had declined dramatically. From 1987 the national caseload had continued to increase but in Governor Thompson's Wisconsin the caseload had declined, then remained steady during the recession, followed by falls of 3 or 4 or even 10 per cent a month. Supposed experts on welfare had agreed that the maximum effect on welfare rolls would be 5 per cent or so, but Wisconsin showed drops of 5 per cent in a single month. The rationale of why dependence was supposed to be inevitable was disproved by the data.

  Oregon, South Carolina and other States had delivered similar successes. What happened to people leaving welfare was not necessarily known. Anecdotally, it appeared that 70 per cent were now in work and 30 per cent were being supported by other family members. The welfare bureaucracy was faced with a 98 per cent drop in the caseload in some counties in Wisconsin. Welfare reform posed a maximum threat to the welfare industry.

  It was a myth that lack of daycare was an obstacle to work. The essential dynamic of reform was that the States could keep the surplus generated by reducing the level of entitlement spending for greater spending on the poor. Dramatic savings were expected. Spending per claimant rose as there was a more intensive effect on claimants.

  The two criteria for success should be a reduction in caseload and a reduction in the number of out-of-wedlock births. Everything else would flow from that. People would not be kicked out on the streets. The objective was to reduce long-term welfare dependence and the absence of fathers.

  There had been some worry over whether it was right to force mothers of very young children into the workplace. Initially it had been intended to target only the mothers of older children. There was a daycare problem for children under school age, so starting at a later age had been considered. The overall ranking of the best environments in which to bring up children was:

  The last environment had no positive consequences whatever for the child. In addition to two parents, a child needed the example of a working parent and an ethos of independence. The data were very clear. Being home alone with a welfare mother was not good for the children.

  The more income was injected into a welfare dependent family, the worse the problem became. The source of the income mattered a great deal. There were negative effects on the child if the money coming in came from welfare, whether in terms of labour force participation, chances of high school graduation and so on.

  IQ levels were not correlated with benefits. The higher the benefit, the longer was the time spent on welfare. The length of time on welfare had a negative effect. Giving salves to the poor had not worked in either the UK or the USA.

  Apart from the narrow range of the incomes near the level of malnutrition, there was no US study which showed higher welfare payments benefited the child. It made a difference where the income came from.

  Many benefit recipients got money under the table. Occasional prostitution, called "going out" in the US, was not a big time activity. Where the habit of dependency was disrupted, such women could find much better ways of making money. The overall objective should be to bring down the number of births out-of-wedlock.

  A pattern of serial co-habiting partners did not support the child. It was a devastatingly bad thing, and the core behaviour that produced dependency. Conservatives believed that the power of cash was a contributing factor to the numbers of out-of-wedlock births. It was necessary to move into a pro-marriage direction. Under income-tested systems, the easiest way to be able to report a lack of income was to not have a male earner present. The welfare system actually promoted marriage break-up. Welfare should be made to be no longer a one-way handout. Workfare in Wisconsin had cut rolls by 70 per cent. Milwaukee had previously had one of the highest dependency rates in the country, with 90 per cent of the black single mothers being on welfare. There had been an 85 per cent drop in the caseload, and welfare dependence had been eliminated throughout most of the rest of the State of Wisconsin. It was the job of charities to support those who truly needed aid. Everyone had known at the beginning of the century that it was necessary to have a work test, but this wisdom had been lost until recently. If money was paid to individuals for not having a job, they could end up being on welfare for years. If someone approached the State to say they needed help to find a job, they would be given 4 weeks under supervision to find a job. At the end of that time they would be given a broom and told to start cleaning the halls. It was remarkable that 60 to 80 per cent of welfare recipients who reached that stage suddenly remembered that they had another option - to get a job instead of carrying a broom.

  The reductions in caseload were not purely related to the state of the economy. There was a negligible 0.5 correlation between the level of unemployment and welfare caseload. The top 8 States by the size of the fall in caseload all had workfare programmes. Wyoming's caseload had been cut dramatically while that of Hawaii had increased. It was clear that the key variable was the reform process not the economy.

  The variation between States provided natural experimental models as they diverged in policy. New York City had introduced workfare, while a liberal democratic legislature in California had no introduced systematic reforms. In Oregon 6 out of 7 recipients offered a community service job found they had other things to do; a lot of them would already have been working, off the books.

  In theory, workfare could put other people out of work and depress the wage rates of entry level jobs, but the US economy created so many jobs. If one was frightened by the possibility of affecting the wages and security of people already in work, one would end up having people in long-term dependence.

  Education never had any effect on welfare caseloads. Only workfare could deliver the "wake-up call" to make people find work. People would be cut off without any income at all only if they refused to co-operate with the system and were unwilling to begin work.

  The negative consequences such as crime, prostitution, begging and destitution had proved to be a lot smaller than people would have thought. Mothers would not refuse work and thereby put their children at risk. In Wisconsin it had been found that non co-operating mothers might have a drug problem. The work requirement was sorting out that kind of problem. It was much better to challenge a person than to leave them at home with a welfare cheque and a cocaine habit funded by a little prostitution on the side.

  Even without operating a time limit two counties in Wisconsin had reduced their welfare caseload by 98 per cent. A recent New York Times article by Jason DeParle had reported on what was called a "homeless shelter" but was actually a supervised living facility, with one inmate saying that workforce was the best thing that had happened to him - just the wake up call he needed. It had been argued that the rhetoric was draconian, and that the public could not accept it, but it was debatable whether there would be any real increase in homelessness.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries

© Parliamentary copyright 1998
Prepared 18 February 1998