TAX AND BENEFITS: AN INTERIM
REPORT
The Social Security Committee
has agreed to the following Report:
Introduction
1. The Labour manifesto
stated:
"We will examine
the interaction of the tax and benefits system so that they can
be streamlined and modernised, so as to fulfil our objectives
of promoting work incentives, reducing poverty and welfare dependence
and strengthening community and family life."[1]
2. To fulfil this manifesto
pledge, the Government announced in May 1997 the formation of
a task force to consider the streamlining and modernisation of
the interaction between the taxation and benefit systems. The
task force is headed by Mr Martin Taylor, Chief Executive of Barclays
plc. The "Taylor Task Force" has brought together officials
from the Treasury, the Inland Revenue, the Department of Social
Security and the Department for Education and Employment. The
original announcement was that the project would last for about
one year.[2]
In the Budget speech in July 1997, the Chancellor announced that
the task force would look at proposals for an Earned Income Tax
Credit and that its findings would inform the Spring Budget.[3]
Mr Chris Kelly, Head of Policy at the Department of Social Security,
put the work of the Task Force into its context:
"There is
a very comprehensive review going on which covers all benefits.
One of those reviews is the review which is being conducted by
the Taylor Task Force. What the Task Force is concentrating on
in the first instance - because this is what the Chancellor asked
us to concentrate on, as he announced in his Budget - is the earned
income tax credit notion."[4]
3. Our initial terms of
reference were:
- to analyse the difficulties
with the current tax/benefit arrangements;
- to examine how greater
integration of the tax and benefit systems might affect work incentives
for claimants and family structures and to assess the net impact
on public spending and resources;
- to examine whether a more
streamlined and integrated system would bring administrative and
efficiency advantages to claimants, taxpayers and staff;
- to examine the underlying
principles of taxation and benefit; whether the assessment unit
should be the individual, a couple or wider household; the question
of control and transfer of money within households; the nature
of support by the tax and benefit system for families and children;
- to ascertain what useful
lessons can be learned about tax and benefits from the experiences
of other countries;
- to contribute to discussion
of the issues currently being considered by the Task Force under
Mr Martin Taylor.
4. We believe the issues
involved in improving work incentives and ameliorating the effects
of the poverty trap to be amongst the most pressing in current
social policy. Furthermore, efficient and equitable tax and benefits
systems underpin other important initiatives such as welfare to
work. We are also concerned that tax and benefits structures
may not at present fully support stable family life and child
rearing.
5. This Report is an interim
Report, intended to provide an overview of the issues that need
to be addressed, without attempting at this stage to provide solutions
or proposals. We intend to look more closely at Government proposals
once these have been unveiled.
6. We wish to thank all
those who have submitted evidence based on our original terms
of reference. A list of Appendices to the Minutes of Evidence
is at page xxxix. Many of the submissions we received contained
detailed analyses and proposals relating to tax and benefits.
We intend to make further use of this detailed evidence in our
later reports on this subject. We are also grateful to those
who accepted our invitation to give oral evidence who are listed
at page xxxviii. We also wish to thank Mr Christopher Giles,
of the Institute for Fiscal Studies, who has acted as our specialist
adviser for this inquiry. We accepted the advice of the Chancellor
of the Exchequer that it would be premature for us to take evidence
from Treasury officials and Mr Martin Taylor at this stage of
our inquiry. We look forward to having an early opportunity to
question witnesses from the Treasury and elsewhere as part of
the consultative process leading up to the next Budget.
The difficulties
with the current tax/benefit arrangements
7. The scope of this Report
is wide, outlining the many and varied problems that can occur
because of the interaction of taxation and benefits. It is impossible
to tackle individual problems in isolation as change in one area
of the system has an impact in another. The main problems identified
and discussed in this section are:
- the poverty trap
- the unemployment trap
- the administrative and
bureaucratic obstacles that deter people moving into work.
Since the formation of the welfare
state, the tax and benefits systems have operated wholly separately
from each other (being currently administered by the Inland Revenue
and Department of Social Security respectively). Different departments
of government make decisions on their respective areas yet, taken
together, these separate decisions can combine to produce unforeseen
consequences. This is clearly seen in the workings of the post-war
tax and benefits systems. In the 1930s most manual workers on
average wages were not subject to income tax on their earnings
and additionally there was no comprehensive welfare benefits system
in place.[5]
As the post-war welfare state developed, the tax and benefits
systems came to overlap. The level at which income tax was paid
crept down the income scale[6]
and the provision of means-tested benefits was extended to the
point that the tax and benefit system converged at the lower end
of the income scale. The convergence gave rise to two main problems
known frequently as the poverty trap and unemployment trap.
8. The poverty trap
affects the incomes of those who may be categorised as the `working
poor'. Most benefits that help supplement the income of this
group (including Family Credit, Housing Benefit, Council Tax Benefit)
are means-tested. Therefore, they are withdrawn as earnings rise.
Additionally, as earnings rise people pay more income tax or
National Insurance Contributions[7]
(or perhaps start paying them for the first time). The result
is that the marginal tax rate on any extra earnings can reach
97 per cent. Table 1 shows the mechanics of the poverty trap.
Table 1: Cumulative deductions
from each £1 of gross earnings
Tax or Benefit
| Family
| Single person or couple
|
Extra Income
| £1.00
| £1.00
|
Income Tax @ 20 per cent
| 20p
| 20p
|
National Insurance @ 10 per cent
| 10p
| 10p
|
Net earnings
| 70p
| 70p
|
Family Credit @ 70 per cent
| 49p
| n/a
|
Income net of Family Credit
| 21p
| 70p
|
Housing Benefit @ 65 per cent
| 14p
| 45.5p
|
Council Tax Benefit @ 20 per cent
| 4p
| 14p
|
Net disposable income
| 3p
| 10.5p
|
Source: Report for Chartered
Institute of Housing on Replacing Housing Benefit with Housing
Credit.
The effective marginal rate from
tax/benefit withdrawal is far higher than tax rates on income
that exist elsewhere in the tax system (the top rate of income
tax being 40 per cent). Yet it is levied on those whose earnings
are at the lowest end of the income scale. As well as being widely
perceived as unfair, it is also potentially economically and socially
damaging in that it might discourage effort and lower morale of
those seeking to improve their position. Table 2 shows the numbers
of people affected by high marginal tax rates.
Table 2: Numbers affected
by high marginal deduction rates (thousands)
Marginal Deduction Rate
| 1994/95
| 1995/96
| 1996/97
|
100 per cent +
| 0 |
10 |
5 |
90 per cent +
| 90 |
100 |
105 |
80 per cent +
| 355
| 420
| 360
|
70 per cent +
| 600
| 615
| 645
|
60 per cent +
| 620
| 630
| 655
|
50 per cent +
| 625
| 630
| 660
|
Source: Based on 1994-95
Family Resources Survey, uprated to 1996-97 levels, adjusted to
benefit caseloads using Housing Benefit Management Statistics
and the Family Credit Statistical Sample
(taken from the memorandum submitted by the Department of Social
Security Ev p.2.)
9. The unemployment trap
concerns the relationship between incomes of those who are in
and out of work. Simply, if the difference between income that
can be obtained in work compared to benefits available while unemployed
is not sufficiently great, some unemployed people might be deterred
from taking a job. Table 3 shows the numbers of the working population
with high replacement ratios (defined as out-of work income as
a percentage of in-work income).
Table 3: Replacement ratios
for the working population, thousands
Replacement ratio
| 1993/94
| 1994/95
| 1995/96
| 1996/97
|
100 per cent +
| 10
| 10
| 15
| 15
|
90 per cent +
| 40
| 35
| 35
| 45
|
80 per cent +
| 175
| 190
| 165
| 195
|
70 per cent +
| 465
| 505
| 510
| 510
|
Source: Social Security Departmental
Report 1997-98 to 1999-2000, Cm 3613, March 1997
(taken from the memorandum submitted by the Department of Social
Security Ev p.3).
The memorandum from the Department
of Social Security pointed out that the replacement ratios shown
in Table 3 apply to those currently within the working population;
for those outside the labour market the situation may be more
acute because those currently unemployed may command lower wages
on starting work than those currently employed and in consequence
face higher replacement ratios.[8]
10. The Department of Social
Security memorandum described those groups most severely affected
by the unemployment trap:
- those with mortgages
who are entitled to help with interest payments on out-of-work
benefits but not if they receive Family Credit;
- those with high in-work
costs not taken account of in the tax/benefits system (eg on childcare
or travel to works costs);
- those without entitlement
to Family Credit - all couples without children and single people
(except where entitlement to Disability Working Allowance exists.)[9]
The loss of passported benefits,
such as free school meals (the costs of which vary according to
local authority and number of school-age children), also affects
the financial equation. The National Association of Citizens
Advice Bureaux provided some case studies which illustrated the
difficulties of people caught in the poverty and unemployment
traps.[10]
The memorandum from Andersen Consulting contained the following
diagram to show the relationship between in-work and out-of-work
benefits.
Figure 1: Sources
of income and deductions for a married couple with one child under
5 years old

Source: Andersen Consulting
Appendix 18
11. Non-financial factors
also affect work incentives. Benefit claimants considering taking
a job might not be able to calculate what their future in-work
income would be. Calculations have to be made of the various
different means-tests inherent in the benefits available plus
tax and national insurance deductions (which are levied at different
rates). A claimant also has to fill in forms to claim benefits
and produce evidence of income, hours worked, savings, family
members and household composition and deal with various branches
of officialdom. Therefore, the uncertainty of in-work income,
allied with the `hassle' factor of claiming benefits, can provide
a powerful disincentive to take low paid work. This is especially
true if the work on offer is temporary or uncertain to last, since
at attempt to return to unemployed status can result in benefit
sanctions. Added together, the claimant might not be prepared
to leave the passive `security' that state benefits can represent.
12. The Unemployment Unit
told us that claimants had to deal with a plethora of different
agencies and departments, none of which appeared to communicate
with each other:
"The Employment
Service and the Benefits Agency share the administration of JSA
claims while the Benefits Agency alone handles Family Credit.
Housing Benefit and Council Tax Benefit are each dealt with by
a different department in the local authority. Housing Benefit
departments are in general particularly poor at providing a fast
and hassle-free service."[11]
13. The Children's Society
drew attention to the upheavals in family income, both in moving
into work and returning to benefits.[12]
Ms Pamela Meadows of the Policy Studies Institute stressed the
importance of avoiding dislocation of income when people move
from benefit into work because families who are making the transition
from not working to work have no spare resources.[13]
Ms Janet Allbeson of the National Association of Citizens Advice
Bureaux referred to the difficulties of people who have to switch
between in-work and out-of-work benefits according to whether
they worked more or less than 16 hours in a week:
"You have
also got people doing temporary work, increasing numbers of people,
often as a way into work, temping, trying to get work experience,
trying to get contacts, and that is incredibly problematic because
you are having to claim and reclaim benefits and particularly
Income Support and Jobseeker's Allowance are quite slow to kick
in and also Housing Benefit."[14]
14. The Department of Social
Security recognised the importance of these non-financial `hassle'
factors as deterrents to work.[15]
Their memorandum outlined administrative measures taken to improve
the transition to work, such as faster Family Credit administration
for new claimants and the extension of entitlement to Housing
Benefit for the first four weeks of starting work.[16]
Welcome as such initiatives are, the `hassle' factor remains
a significant factor in discouraging some claimants to take work.
The memorandum from Electronic Data Systems (EDS) discussed how
the "astonishing" growth in computer capacity could
be harnessed to provide better services for customers.[17]
In particular EDS discussed how call centres could be utilised
to make more contact with the DSS by telephone and how the Internet
could be used to improve access to information.[18]
15. Clearly, there are several
steps which could be taken, short of a wholesale re-structuring
of the system, which could help to improve work incentives. The
Institute for Public Policy Research outlined a number of other
improvements to the social security system which would help bridge
the gap between benefits and work.[19]
These include flexible earnings disregards, better transitional
and passported benefits and greater help with the cost of starting
work.
1 Labour Party Manifesto, General Election 1997, page 13. Back
2 HM Treasury Press Release 47/97, 19 May 1997. Back
3 HC Deb 2 July 1997 vol 297 col 311 and Q 10. Back
4 Q 15. Back
5 Third Special Report from the Treasury and Civil Service Committee, Session 1982-83, The Structure of Personal Income Taxation and Income Support, HC 386, para 1.4. Back
6 ibid., para 1.5. Back
7 National Insurance Contributions (NICs) are levied on all employed and self-employed people who earn above the Lower Earnings Limit (currently £62) up to the Upper Earnings Limit (currently £465). NICs are essentially a form of taxation. They are administered by the Contributions Agency, an executive Agency of the Department of Social Security. Back
8 Ev p.3. Back
9 Ev p.3. Back
10 National Association of Citizens Advice Bureaux, Benefits and Work: A CAB perspective on the welfare to work debate, by Janet Allbeson (1997). Back
11 Appendix 8. Back
12 Appendix 14. Back
13 Q 169. Back
14 Q 213. Back
15 Ev p.4. Back
16 ibid. Back
17 Appendix 5. Back
18 ibid. Back
19 Appendix 26. Back
|