Select Committee on Social Security First Report


APPENDIX 6

Memorandum submitted by the Institute for Fiscal Studies (TAB 69)

SUMMARY

  1. This submission considers a number of issues arising from the announcement of the Working Families Tax Credit and the reforms to National Insurance in the Budget on 17 March 1998.

NIC Reforms

  2. The NIC reforms involve the removal of discontinuities from the structure of contributions and the harmonisation of parts of the NIC structure with the income tax system. These are welcome developments to National Insurance, which will simplify the administration burden on employers and ease the distortions produced in the labour market.

  3. In terms of their distributional impact, the NI reforms are progressive. On average, only employees living in the richest 10 of households see the combined employer and employee contributions increase. For the other nine-tenths of households, on average total contributions fall.

  4. A number of issues remain to be addressed within the NI system. First, the contributions of the self-employed need to be reformed. Such reform should lead to the level of contributions paid by the self-employed being moved closer in line with the level of contributions paid by those in employment. Second, a comprehensive review of the contributory principle for non-means-tested benefits is urgently required.

The Working Families Tax Credit

  5. The Working Families Tax Credit can be summarised as a more generous version of Family Credit with an altered method of payment. The impact of the structural change, as opposed to the increase in generosity, hinges on whether the "re-branding" of Family Credit will have any impact on behaviour. There is no hard evidence on the importance or direction of such effects.

  6. The increased generosity of the WFTC is concentrated on households in the poorer part of the income distribution. In terms of work incentives, the WFTC represents a trade-off between negative and positive labour supply effects. For workless families, it will unambiguously increase the financial returns to working. It lowers some of the highest marginal tax rates, but only to levels just below 70 per cent . Others will become entitled to the WFTC and will therefore see their marginal tax rates increase substantially. There are also significant incentives for second earners, mainly women, in couples to leave employment altogether. These effects are consistent with the government's statement that "the highest priority must be to get one member of workless households into work".[18]

  7. The cost of the childcare credit in the WFTC largely depends on the degree to which current informal childcare arrangements are brought into the formal sector.

2. NIC REFORMS

  8. The NIC reforms proposed in the Taylor Report and implemented in the Budget represent a substantial step towards the rationalisation of National Insurance system. Certain major issues still need to be addressed, in particular how the contributory principle can be adapted to conform to the new structure of National Insurance.

Change in structure of Class 1 contributions

  9. The changes to the Class 1 NICs can be broken down into a number of elements. First is the removal of discontinuities from the NIC system. This was achieved by abolishing the "entry fee" to employer NICs and moving to a single marginal rate for employer NICs. These measures should increase the flexibility of the labour market insofar as rigidities are being generated by the discontinuities in NICs. In addition, the reduction in the number of rates in operation will simplify the administration of the system.

  10. The second element is the alignment of the point at which NICs first becomes payable with the personal allowance of income tax. In the case of employer contributions, this is to be achieved by setting the LEL to £81 per week, the weekly equivalent to the personal allowance. However, the LEL for employee NICs remains at £64 per week, though the government is committed to increasing this to £81 at some point in the future. This alignment of values in the NI and income tax systems will not produce large administrative savings. Only single people with straightforward tax affairs start paying PAYE at the £81 per week. Married couples and those with children have higher total allowances due to existence of the Married Couple's Allowance and the Additional Personal Allowance. For those with more complicated tax affairs, the Inland Revenue will often adjust their tax code and hence the point at which they start paying PAYE. These problems are compounded by differences in the period of assessment between income tax and National Insurance.

  11. The third element of the NIC reforms is the degree of redistribution that is involved. The package ensures that the total of employer and employee NICs for all employees earning less than £480 per week will be lower. Employee NICs fall for all workers. But the changes to employer NICs mean that these will be higher for those on high earnings and for those with earnings just below £155 and £210 per week. In the short term this distinction between lower employee and higher employer contributions might affect which party receives the gains from the overall NIC reduction. In the long term it should have no effect. Employers care only another total cost of employing a person. Employees care about final amount earned in job. It is the gap between these two amounts which matters, which is unaffected by whether contributions are labelled as "employer" or "employee".

  12. Figure 1 shows the distributional impact of the NIC changes. This divides households into 10 deciles ranked by income. The figure shows the average change in total NICs paid. On average, households in the first nine deciles see their total NICs fall, while only those in the richest decile lose, with average NIC raising by almost £4.00 per week. Note that this average result for the richest decile hides a large variation within this group. The highest paid employees will see there total NIC increase by almost 2.2 per cent of their gross pay.


NICs and the self-employed

  13. The Taylor Report outlined how the NIC reforms could be extended to the self-employed.[19] In the Budget the Chancellor committed himself to examine carefully these options. The proposals to abolish the flat-rate Class 2 contributions and to align the Lower Profits Limit with the Lower Earnings Limit would be a welcome development in line with the reforms to employee contributions.

  14. However, self-employed NICs present two problems that do not occur with employee contributions. First, the self-employed have a lower level of entitlement to contributory benefits than the employed. There is little justification for lower benefit entitlements to the self-employed, especially given the dependence of the benefit system on means testing, which does not distinguish between those who have been employed and self-employed.

  15. Second, there is a strong case for increasing the contributions of the self-employed. Under the current system, the NIC liability generated when a person is self-employed is substantially lower than when the person is an employee. For example, consider a firm paying £200 per week to a person for a service. If the person is an employee of the firm, the government will receive £25.25 in NICs. If the person is self-employed, the government will receive only £9.92. The distinction between these contribution levels is only partly accounted for by the lower benefit entitlement of the self-employed. The present situation is not only inequitable, it is also distortionary. Granting tax privilege to one form of work contract creates an incentive to restructure economic activity to minimise tax liability, even though on other grounds this structure is not efficient.

Integration of NICs and income tax

  16. As was noted above, the increase in starting point of NICs to the level of the personal allowance is a more limited integration of NICs and income tax than it at first appears. But even this integration is hampered by the current contributory principle. Those with earnings above the LEL currently gain earn contributions toward entitlement to certain benefits, while those with earnings below the LEL do not. Simply increasing the LEL for both employer and employee contributions to £81 would also increase the amount of earnings needed to generate benefit entitlement. To avoid this, the government could allow people with earnings between £64 and £81 per week to retain their benefit entitlements without making any contributions. However, it would be problematic to justify this situation to a person earning below £64 per week, who would also be making no contributions but would not receive any benefit entitlement.

  17. These problems highlight how outdated the contributory principle has become. Under the NIC system announced in the budget, a person earning £63.99 would make no contributions and gain no benefit entitlement, while a person earning £64.01 per week will pay 0.1p per week in contributions and gain entitlement to NI benefits. The time has clearly come to modernise the contributory principle.

  18. This should be accompanied by a re-examination of the role of non-means-tested benefits in the current system. To take one example, consider contributory Jobseeker's Allowance.[20] This now provides a small weekly payment for six months to those who satisfy the necessary contribution criteria. The payment no longer takes account of the person's dependants. It is difficult to see what this benefit is designed to achieve in the context of the current benefit system. One alternative might be a non-means-tested benefit that was designed to ease labour market transitions. It would be available on a short-term basis at a reasonably generous rate and with little accompanying monitoring. It would be intended to facilitate a period of off-the-job search.

  19. In paragraph 2.13, the Taylor Report makes a strong case against full integration of income tax and National Insurance. It notes possible large redistribution if employee NICs merged with income tax. But this need not be the case. Savings already have differential tax treatment from other income sources—why not also income from employment and self-employment. The real question that should be asked is whether we believe it is correct to tax income from working more highly than income from other sources.

  20. However, in short term the conclusion of the Taylor Report is probably correct—we cannot move directly to integration of income tax and National Insurance as one "big bang" solution. But aim of integration provides a clear and coherent rationale for further modernising of the NI system.

3. THE WORKING FAMILIES TAX CREDIT

  21. In terms of its structure, the Working Families Tax Credit (WFTC) is little more than a "re-branded" version of Family Credit (FC) with an altered method of payment. In terms of its value, the WFTC represents a substantial injection of funds into in-work support for families with children.

Structural changes

  22. The structural differences between WFTC and FC are limited to the method of payment. Claimants will still have to make a claim to a government agency, which will be part of the Inland Revenue rather than the Benefits Agency. This agency will assess the claim and decide on the amount of the tax credit. By default, a new tax code will be issued to the employer who will make payments on behalf of the government. The only difference from the current system will be that the money involved will pass through employers' accounts and the "wage packet" before reaching families rather than being paid directly to the families by the government.

  23. There are a number of issues that need to be considered even under these minimal changes. First are the psychological issues that arise. These take a number of forms. Examples are

    —  As the WFTC will pass through employers' accounts before being paid to claimants, it might have a more direct relationship with working and therefore strengthen individuals' attachment to employment.

    —  As the WFTC will officially be part of the tax system rather than the benefit system, increasing its generosity might be made easier by portraying the change as a tax reduction as opposed to a benefit increase.

[21]

    —  If people did not regard the WFTC as a welfare benefit, it might reduce the stigma associated with receiving transfer payments and so increase take-up.

    —  As employers and potentially work colleagues will observe the WFTC, it might increase the stigma associated with receiving transfer payments and so decrease take-up.

    —  As employers will directly observe the level of WFTC payments being made to their employees, they might be more likely to lower gross wages in response to these transfers.

  There is no hard evidence about the importance of any of these effects; the weight placed on these arguments will depend only on one's beliefs about the likely reactions of welfare claimants, employers, voters and politicians to the introduction of the WFTC.

  24. Aside from changes in take-up, the change in the method of payment cannot affect the overall level of family income. It will, however, represent a redistribution of income within couples. Currently, FC is typically paid to the woman in a couple. The WFTC will by default be paid to the principal earner, which in over 75 per cent of couples in receipt of FC is the man. To avoid compulsory transfer of resources from women to men, claimants may opt to receive the WFTC as a direct transfer payment to women from the government.

  25. It is unclear how far this option will go to meeting the main concern of the "wallet versus purse" debate, which is that redistribution within the family may affect the level of expenditure on goods for children. The evidence on whether such redistributions do in general cause changes in expenditure patterns is inconclusive. However, it is likely that in cases where such problems occur, women will be unable to exercise a choice as to who in the couple should receive the WFTC.

  26. The WFTC will also involve employers as effective payment agents. For most employers, this is unlikely to be a major problem—the cost of the WFTC payments will be netted off the main income tax liability paid by the firm to the Inland Revenue on behalf of employees. Problems could arise for employers with large numbers of WFTC recipients and few non-recipients. In these cases, the company may be owed money by the Inland Revenue each month. While the actual number of such cases may be small, the system of payment from the Revenue to firms will have to be extremely efficient to avoid serious cash-flow problems for those affected.

Increased generosity of in work support

  27. The WFTC will be substantially more generous than FC. By the end of the century, the government expects to be spending £5 billion per year on the WFTC, which is £1.5 billion more than was expected under FC. This will have two important effects. The first is distributional, with the government transferring greater resources to low wage families with children. The second is the impact on work incentives and how the WFTC acts as a "welfare to work" measure. Previous research has shown that in most cases the distributional effect of a reform is by far the most important.[22]

  28. Figure 2 shows a simplified version of the in-work support system. Both FC and the WFTC share this structure. When an individual in a family with children works more than 16 hours, the family becomes entitled to in work support. The maximum amount that can be received is equal to the total credits for that type of family. FC continues to be paid at the maximum amount until income net of income tax and National Insurance exceeds a fixed level known as the applicable amount. After this level, the amount of FC is reduced, or tapered, as income rises. The rate at which it is tapered is currently 70 per cent, which means that for a £1 increase in net income, there will be a 70p reduction in the family credit payment.


  29. The WFTC will increase the generosity of in-work support relative to the FC system in three ways.

    —  an increase in the credit for children under 11 from £12.35 to £14.85 per child;

    —  an increase in the applicable amount from £79 to £90 per week;

    —  a reduction in the taper from 70 per cent to 55 per cent.

  The effect of these changes on our simplified version of in work support is shown in Figure 3. Those currently receiving the maximum payment see a small increase in the level of their payment if they have children under 11. Those with net incomes between £79 and £90 move from being on the taper to receiving maximum support. The others on the taper see the taper rate fall from 70 per cent to 55 per cent. The largest cash gains go to those people who are currently just at the end of the taper. The increased generosity of in-work support also creates new entitlement to in-work support.


Distributional effect of the WFTC

  30. The distributional impact of the increased generosity of the WFTC over FC is shown in Figure 4. The majority of the gains from this change are in the poorer deciles, with the second poorest decile gaining the most. Virtually none of the gains from this change go to households in the richest half of the income distribution.


The impact of a WFTC on work incentives

  31. Two concepts—the unemployment trap and the poverty trap—are useful for analysing changes in the structure of in-work support.[23] The unemployment trap refers to the situation where people are little or no better off in work than they would be remaining on benefits. A measure of the unemployment trap is the replacement ratio, which measures income out of work as a percentage of in-work income. Other things being equal, we would expect a person to be more likely to take up employment if income in work is high relative to income out of work, i.e. if they have a low replacement ratio.

  32. The second concept we use is the poverty trap.[24] For people in work, a poverty trap can arise where increases in gross income result in much smaller changes in their disposable income. The usual measure of the poverty trap is the effective marginal tax rate. This is the rate at which disposable income increases in response to a £1 increase in gross income. The difference between the two will be accounted for by increases in tax or National Insurance payments and by reductions in benefits.

  33. There is a trade-off involved in designing a system of in-work support. Increasing the level of payments reduces replacement ratios, thereby alleviating the unemployment trap. At some stage, these additional benefits have to be withdrawn, which increases marginal tax rates and thereby worsens the poverty trap over that range of income.

Impact on replacement rates

  34. The impact of the WFTC on the replacement rates of those in work is shown in Table 1. In most cases, the WFTC increases the financial returns to working by increasing in-work income. The main groups affected are lone parents and men in single earner couples. In total, 275,000 lone parents see their replacement rates fall 4 per cent on average, while the replacement rates 350,000 men in single earner couples fall by an average of 5 per cent.
TABLE 1
Number of individuals with altered replacement ratios

Number of
individuals
Average
initial level
per cent
Average change
(percentage
points)
per cent

Increased returns to employment
Lone parents
All275,00067 -4
Single earner couples
Men350,00077 -5
Women75,00084 -4
Two earner couples
Men125,00074 -5
Women100,00082 -3
Decreased returns to employment
Two earner couples
Men975,00047 3
Women750,00067 5


  35. It is important to note that Table 1 is confined to those currently in work.[25] It therefore excludes the impact of the WFTC on families where no one is currently working. For individuals in these families, the increased generosity of the WFTC relative to FC will make taking a job more attractive at certain hours and wage combinations.

  36. While normally we think of increases in in-work support as lowering replacement rates, for two-earner couples we can get an opposite effect. A second earner might see their replacement rate rise, making work financially less attractive. If the primary earner's income alone entitled the couple to WFTC, then the WFTC would form part of out-of-work income for the second earner. An increase in the generosity of WFTC can therefore act as an increase in out-of-work income for second earners. This causes in increase in the replacement ratio.

  37. This effect can be seen in the results at the bottom of Table 1. Almost 1 million men and 750,000 women in two earner couples see their financial returns to employment fall as a result of the WFTC. In general, this effect will be more important for women. On average, replacement rates of women are initially 67 per cent and these are increased by 5 per cent. This indicates that for this group, the increased generosity of in-work support may be used to allow the second earner to give up working altogether.

Impact on marginal tax rates

  38. With the introduction of the WFTC, the rate at which in work support will be tapered will be reduced from 70 per cent to 55 per cent. However, the drop in overall marginal tax rates will not be 15 per cent. This is because the taper operates on income net of income tax and National Insurance and the WFTC interacts with other means-tested benefits. Table 2 shows the impact of the reduction in the taper rate on overall marginal tax rates for those on various combinations of National Insurance, income tax and means-tested benefits. The combined marginal tax rate from National Insurance and FC/WFTC will fall by 13.5 per cent to 59.5 per cent. The highest marginal tax rates, which are produced by the interaction of a number of means-tested benefits, will be less affected. For instance, the marginal tax rate produced by NI, income tax, Housing Benefit and Council Tax Benefit falls by only 1.3 per cent to 95.3 per cent.
TABLE 2
Impact of reduction in taper on marginal tax rates

Marginal ratesBefore (FC)
per cent
After (WFTC)
per cent

NI+FC/WFTC73.059.5
NI+IT+FC/WFTC79.068.5
NI+IT+FC/WFTC+HB92.7 89.0
NI+IT+FC/WFTC+HB+CTB96.9 95.3


  39. Table 3 shows the number of individuals with altered marginal tax rates. The first set of columns shows the number of individuals whose marginal tax rates are in each range before and after the introduction of the WFTC. The second set of columns shows the number with marginal tax rates in that range or above. There is reduction of 450,000 in the number of people with marginal tax rates above 70 per cent. Most of the people in these groups see their marginal tax rates fall to the 60-70 per cent range. In addition, a large number of people are drawn onto higher marginal tax rates through the increase in the number of recipients of in-work support. These two factors contribute to the sharp rise in the numbers with marginal tax rates between 60-70 per cent. Overall, while the numbers with marginal rax rates above 70 per cent falls by 450,000, the number with marginal tax rates above 50 per cent increases by 460,000.
TABLE 3
Number of individuals with altered marginal tax rates

Range
Numbers in range
Numbers in range or above
Per centBeforeAfter ChangeBeforeAfter Change

50 to 600207 2078101,274 464
60 to 7079790 7118101,067 257
70 to 8026617 -249731277 -454
80 to 90235145 -90465260 -205
90 to 100222115 -107230115 -115
10080 -880-8


Childcare measures

  40. The impact of the childcare credit to be introduced with the WFTC is the most difficult element of the last budget to quantify. Under FC, childcare expenses can be disregarded against income. This in effect means that only those who have income above the applicable amount can gain. The majority of lone parents, who are entitled to full FC before childcare costs are taken into account, receive no additional payments in respect of these costs. The childcare disregard in FC has a low cost and a very low take-up.

  41. Under the WFTC, support for childcare will operate through an additional credit. This will be over and above normal adult, child and 30-hour credits, so all WFTC claimants with childcare expenses will be able to receive help with them. The credit will cover 70 per cent of eligible childcare costs, up to a maximum of £100 a week for one child and £150 for two or more children. As such, the maximum amount of WFTC help available will be £70 for families with one child and £105 a week for families with two or more children.

  42. Currently those receiving FC spend very little on formal childcare. In all the results presented above, we have assumed that the use of childcare will follow these present patterns. But with the introduction of the credit many people currently using informal childcare arrangements, such as that provided by family and friends, may formalise these arrangements in order to gain from the childcare credit. It is uncertainty about the degree to which current activities may be formalised that makes the overall cost of the childcare credit so difficult to estimate. The government's current spending projections estimate the addititional cost of the childcare credit to be in the region of £250 million per year. The maximum additional expenditure is substantially higher than this, reaching £4 billion per year if all eligible families spend the full £100 or £150 a week on childcare. This represents a very wide range of potential costs for the credit. This is one of the few budget measures where only experience of its operation will allow us to determine its actual cost.

June 1998


18   The Working Families Tax Credit and work incentives, The Modernisation of Britain's Tax and Benefit System, Number Three, paragraph 4.10. Back

19   See the Taylor Report, paragraphs 2.25-2.28. Back

20   This replaced Unemployment Benefit in October 1996. Back

21   In the public accounts, the part of a WFTC that offset current tax liabilities could be included as a tax reduction. However, standard conventions for international comparisons would mean that any "negative income tax" paid by the government would appear as an expenditure item. This treatment is currently applied to mortgage interest tax relief paid to non-taxpayers. Aside from psychological considerations, the labelling of cash flows is, of course, irrelevant. The overall level of redistribution performed by the government is what matters and this is unaltered by the naming of cash flows. Back

22   See Duncan and Giles (1996), Labour Supply Incentives and Recent Family Credit Reforms, Economic Journal. Back

23   The complete analysis of the WFTC on work incentives requires a full labour supply model to be estimated. The results of such a model are not available at present. However, the more limited analysis presented here does give a strong indication of the likely direction and magnitude of the full labour supply effects. Back

24   The term "poverty trap" is used in the literature to denote the situation where individuals face high effective marginal tax rates in the lower parts of the income or earnings distribution. It is not a normative claim about whether or not the people facing such rates are in poverty. Back

25   To include the unemployed in this analysis, it would be necessary to estimate the wage level they would receive if they were working. This is not attempted here. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries

© Parliamentary copyright 1998
Prepared 2 December 1998