Select Committee on Agriculture Minutes of Evidence



Examination of witnesses (Questions 182 - 199)

TUESDAY 21 MARCH 2000

MR PETER STEVENSON, MR DAVID BOWLES and MR CHRIS FISHER

Chairman

  182. Good morning. Welcome. You know what we have been investigating. We have obviously been talking to people in Geneva. We are going to the United States shortly. We were very interested in the memoranda which you have sent to us. We have obviously discovered, in the course of our investigations, that there is a lot of resistance, for diverse reasons, to trying to incorporate formal animal welfare criteria into world trade negotiations. This is for reasons which will be elaborated and explored by the Committee this morning. I would like to start by asking you a very direct question. Do you have evidence—and by evidence I mean not anecdotal evidence but proper evidence—that consumers are willing to pay for welfare, as opposed to saying that they would prefer high animal standards and saying they would pay for it. The anecdote on which I invite you to comment, which has been repeated to us, is when somebody is going into a supermarket and you ask them, "If you know you can buy bacon, which has been produced to high standards, would you pay a bit extra?" they say yes; but when you investigate their trolley on the way out you find that they have done no such thing. Could you help us by indicating whether you really think the market place rewards welfare? That is really the question.
  (Mr Bowles) You are aware of the RSPCA's Freedom Food scheme, which is basically to establish a niche for good animal welfare. It is interesting, if we are looking at hard figures, to see how that has grown in the six years starting from 1994. If we take, for instance, free-range eggs, that was the first product that Freedom Food was launched under in 1994. At that stage we had sales of 100,000 a month. Sales are now, in 2000, 70 million a month; so you can see the enormous growth that has occurred in that particular market. This is because people want free-range eggs. They are prepared to pay for free-range eggs and they want a free-range egg product. Freedom Food has expanded in other areas into processed food. We are just launching a range of meat pies, for instance, where it is much more difficult to encapsulate the animal welfare product into something which has been processed. You will see from the way that Freedom Food has grown that there is a niche there. I accept that there may be a difference in what the public say in questionnaires and what they are putting in their trolley but the public in questionnaires are coming out extremely strongly in favour of wanting good animal welfare standards. However, you can see from the Freedom Food products that this is reflected, to a large extent, by what the public actually do put in their trolleys.

  183. You have cited eggs. I wonder to what extent that is because people feel that free-range eggs are healthier for them, and they buy them because they prefer them rather than being interested in the welfare side. Is there another commodity that you could cite, like eggs, with a similar experience?
  (Mr Bowles) We have products in the pork range at the moment. Now those products have not been going as long. It is much more difficult to see a trend there but we have noticed that there is a huge uptake in free-range good animal welfare pork products. That is primarily because of the fact that we believe the public is demanding good animal welfare. I do not necessarily buy into the argument that they buy free-range because they think it is healthy. The public is sanitised a lot about the arguments between battery hen eggs and free-range eggs. They understand the welfare problems with the battery hen system. I think our surveys and Compassion surveys show that the public do want to buy a welfare friendly egg. They are buying, not just because of the health indications, but because of the welfare indications.

  184. Is there a price threshold which applies? In other words, are people willing to make this choice with Freedom Food products—let us say, at a 10 per cent premium—but not at a 15 per cent premium over the price? Where is the tolerance in that regard? Have you any evidence of there being a tolerance in that regard?
  (Mr Bowles) The price is actually set by the retailers. Peter can go into some of the problems; the fact that the retailer is actually setting the differential price. We have had evidence showing that when, for instance, Freedom Food do vouchers, giving price off for products, there is a huge uptake in those products. I do not know exactly where the threshold is but, yes, there is undoubtedly a threshold that occurs.
  (Mr Stevenson) We have done surveys, going back to eggs, actually at the supermarkets. When we did a survey about 18 months ago the majority of supermarkets were reporting that over 30 per cent of their total egg sales were non-caged eggs; in other words, either free-range or barn. Three of the major supermarkets were reporting over 50 per cent were non-caged eggs. You always have the complication that this was looking at the actual eggs and not the processed foods containing eggs. People at the supermarkets are willing to pay that extra in order to buy high welfare products. Most of the research so far, from our point of view, has been done on eggs because, of course, that was our big concern leading up to the decision of the EU Council last summer.

Mr Paterson

  185. What is your problem in the fastest growing section of the egg market, which is powdered egg or liquid egg which goes into processed pizzas or flans, things like that?
  (Mr Stevenson) It is the task of animal welfare groups now to sensitise the public—also when it comes to cakes, biscuits or ready made meals—making sure that they are asking for products which contain non-caged eggs. I think we could achieve that just in the way we have done that with the more obvious sector of the table eggs.
  (Mr Bowles) You pick on a very good point. The whole argument about whether the EU should go battery-free was not about imports of shell eggs but the imports of processed eggs. This shows the limitations that can occur sometimes with labelling. Not only have you got confused labelling with eggs in the stores, at the moment, because you do not have a mandatory egg labelling scheme; but also the public, when they are buying processed eggs, are one stage removed from that actual product. That is why it is quite exciting that Freedom Food is now going into processed meat products because we are trying to develop that particular market.

  186. Would you have labelling on processed products as well?
  (Mr Bowles) Yes, exactly.

  187. That is your position?
  (Mr Bowles) Yes.

Mr Jack

  188. The heart of this matter is the ability to differentiate between animals raised in one regime as opposed to, shall we say, a lesser regime, whatever we define as animal welfare. The determinants in trading terms as to what reaches the shores of this country and the sourcing thereof is the leading food retailers, the manufacturers, and the caterers. What discussions have you had with them about these issues in the context of the WTO? Do they show any sort of cognisance of the problem? Do you believe that they are really interested in imposing or ensuring that there is an equivalence of standards between their overseas sources of raw material and the United Kingdom?
  (Mr Stevenson) We have regular discussions with all the major supermarkets and the caterers, but particularly the supermarkets. We lobby, push, persuade them to try and ensure that they have certain standards for all their current products. Particularly obviously when it comes to pig meat, we have put a lot of pressure on them through surveys and publicising the results, to make sure that all their pig meat—not just their own labels but the branded products too—are coming either from pigs from the United Kingdom or abroad but reared to the same standards; that is, stall and tether free. Clearly the supermarkets do need pushing and persuading but, yes, they are susceptible to that pressure of setting high welfare standards.

  189. Do you believe there is a real equivalence, a real parity? For example, chicken from Thailand is one that currently exercises a lot of people's minds. I have no idea how Thai chickens are reared, but the supermarkets might argue that there is an equivalence between that product and the domestic product. Question mark: is there?
  (Mr Stevenson) We are currently doing investigation into some of the developing countries, including Thailand. Hopefully, we will know a lot more when that study is completed in a month's time. However, I would imagine that broiler production will tend to be very, very similar world-wide. It is, of all the animal rearing industries, the one that has the most uniform standards.

  Chairman: I think that brings us on quite neatly to Alan's line of questioning.

Mr Hurst

  190. It can be very much a niche interest, to use a common phrase these days, animal welfare. The Consumers' Association did not mention the subject when they gave evidence to us. The Poultry Meat Federation really emphasised more food safety and animal health rather than the welfare question. The argument could be put that animal welfare is very much an activity of a small number of non-governmental organisations rather than a matter of general interest. Would you care to comment upon that?
  (Mr Bowles) There are two things which I would like to say. One is the link between animal welfare and animal health. Peter might like to go into that in greater detail, but there is a large link between good animal welfare and good animal health. In fact, the problem with the Thai chickens, why we prohibited the import of those, was, I understand, on animal health grounds. That is linked in with their method of production. The second thing I would say is that I have found, during the past year of working on this subject, that there is an increase in interest in animal welfare, particularly from producers but also from the retail outlets. If we look at what is happening in the pig market, at the moment, the retailers are only sourcing from good animal welfare pork products on their own brand labels. That is because they perceive and they actually know that there is a consumer interest in this area. So I think that it is not just a niche market. There are large interests in this. Those interests will grow.
  (Mr Stevenson) Certainly when we did surveys leading up to the Council's decision on the Hens Directive—not just in Britain but in Ireland, France, and the Netherlands—in all of them roughly the same proportion of people were saying that the battery cage system ought to be prohibited by the EU. There are large numbers of people who are concerned about this issue. When we were lobbying European Union institutions last year in the run-up to Seattle—and I am talking about the Commission, the Council and the Parliament—all of them accepted, without any difficulty, that this was important. Indeed, if you look at the various resolutions those three bodies made in the two or three months leading up to Seattle, they stressed several things. They said there needs to be discovered an appropriate balance between trade and non-trade concerns. They expressly defined non-trade concerns as including animal welfare. This was still in the days when they hoped progress would be made at Seattle. All of them said that they believed that the adverse impact of the WTO rules on animal welfare should be one of the negotiating points of the EU. The Council of Agriculture Ministers specifically said that they believed that the "green box" should be expanded, so that it was absolutely clear that payments to promote high standards of animal welfare were legitimate "green box" payments. This was taken on board by institutions representing all 15 Member States that this was an important issue of broad public concern.

  191. There can be a perception, can there not, that animal welfare activism is very much for rich city folk, who may have retired to the country, rather than those who are actively involved in country affairs or, indeed, those who are buying food on a balanced budget. That is a perception which might be there.
  (Mr Stevenson) We have never found, in terms of our support and any questionnaires we have done, any difference between urban and rural interests in farm animal welfare issues. You talked about people on a tight budget. One point we have been trying to research, and the point we have been making over the last two or three years, is that sometimes the farming industry is, quite frankly, a little bit naughty in saying that if we change certain systems—shall we say, going from the battery cage to the free-range for eggs, or going from stalls and tethers to group housing or free-range for sows—that this will be extremely expensive for both producers and for the consumer. I do not believe that is so. I do not believe that these intensive systems are necessarily always inherently very much cheaper. If you look at the industry's National Farmers' Union own figures, a free-range egg cost just 1.5 pence more to produce than a battery egg. It really is tiny. I am not talking about the price charged in the shop. I believe that many shops are over-charging the premium on high welfare. I am in the middle of doing some research into pig production costs. This is because probably our biggest campaign, which is coming up, is to try and get an EU-wide ban on the stall and tether system. When the European Scientific Veterinary Committee looked at pig production costs, they found out that one of the main group house alternatives, the electronic sow feeder, in terms of capital costs, was cheaper than stalls and tethers. In terms of running costs, the group-housing alternatives, on the whole—I am afraid we are back to 1.5 pence—are 1.5 pence more per kilo of pig meat. Again, an absolutely tiny figure.

  192. Leaving aside pig meat for the moment but going back to battery hens and their eggs, one penny per egg is a colossal sum of money across an annual production rate of eggs for one producer.
  (Mr Stevenson) The Ministry of Agriculture figures show that we eat something like 1.8 eggs per person per week; so again, provided that retailers do not over-charge on their mark-up, we could change from battery eggs to free-range eggs at about £2 each per annum.

  193. May I ask a question which has always mystified me and I have never known the answer to. You have discussed welfare methods. If one method is much more positive in welfare terms for the animal than another and the consumer knows about that, I think your argument is that consumers will start to switch to the welfare-positive product. But if you take the product as a whole, including those which are not welfare friendly, does it remain stable as a whole or does it go down? In other words, if you take pig meat, if you distinguish between welfare-positive pigs and welfare-negative pigs, does the whole pig meat market go up or down the more the welfare issue is discussed? Are there any findings on that?
  (Mr Bowles) The pig industry is quite an interesting question but it is very difficult to tease out certain things because other issues are happening. For instance, in the whole pig industry there is no doubt that animal welfare improvements to stall and tether ban had a cost, but that cost is probably a third or fourth in the scale of costs that is affecting the United Kingdom pig industry at the moment: only after BSE controls, the strong pound, and the collapse of the Eastern European markets. What you see in the pig industry is that in the bacon products there has been a large push on high welfare bacon products and the United Kingdom share of that market has stabilised and has remained. The amount of Danish imports of bacon has not gone up, even though the British pig industry in other areas—for instance, pork meat—is collapsing because the amount of imports has gone up. That shows that there is a differentiation in the public's mind. They will go to welfare friendly products where they know them. You can see that the market in that area did actually stabilise.

  194. Is that a shift within the product market to the welfare friendly market, (within, say, pig meat), or is there an increase in the amount of pig meat consumed if you prove to the public that, in fact, it is produced in a more welfare positive way?
  (Mr Bowles) What happened with pig meat is that there was a shift, certainly in Denmark, where the farms in this country were demanding welfare friendly pigs, and the Danish producers had to shift to stall and tether ban production methods. Otherwise, they would not sell their pork in this country and the United Kingdom was a very important market to them. It had that positive effect there. What you are seeing in the bacon market is that it is increasing in terms of actual sales. The problems of teasing this out is because pork had an increase in sales anyway as a result of the BSE. Then beef made a come-back so it is difficult to say: what are the actual reasons for this? Is it because beef was making a come-back or were people going for welfare friendly products?
  (Mr Stevenson) A slightly broader thought. Obviously some of the data is complex and some of it is simply not there on many of the points that have been raised over the last five minutes. I would say that most people would accept that it is important that we, in the European Union, have reasonably high standards of farm animal welfare. There are sufficient people who care about that and that should be addressed. Although I have argued that often the costs of changing from poor welfare to good welfare are not enormous—I am not pretending there are no costs and those can be quite crucial—nevertheless, from our point of view, the conclusion which is reached is that reforms to the WTO rules are vitally needed, both to protect EU producers but also to protect the EU's attempts to move to high animal welfare standards.

  195. Both of your organisations highlight conflicts between EU welfare legislation and WTO rules. How would you see this situation being ultimately resolved?
  (Mr Fisher) Firstly, to wrap up the previous point. I would say that if you take a completely pro-liberalisation view of the market and animal welfare, then the very least you need is much better if not perfect information between consumers. They need to know about the things that interest them: at the very minimum, clear labelling and probably some public information. The discussion we have just had here talks about situations where there has been virtually no mandatory or even official voluntary scheme run at a governmental or European level. Such schemes as there have been have either been run by retailers or animal welfare organisations. We are at a very immature stage in the labelling process, so it is not entirely surprising that consumers are not necessarily fulfilling all their desires through the market because they do not have perfect information, leaving aside that they also have other interests. For example, chicken is perceived as healthier because it has less fat, so they may have another reason to buy chicken, although it is not a very pro-welfare point. On the question of WTO, the key problem is process and production methods. All animal welfare method issues can be described as a process and production method; non-product related. I see nods, so I can see that you are familiar with the jargon. Essentially, it is very difficult (if not impossible) in most cases, to determine in the physical product whether it is a free-range egg or a battery egg. Whether it has been humanely produced or is intensively produced pork. Therefore, from a WTO point of view, all these products are the same. They are "like products" and should be treated the same. So if we are talking about fundamentals, this is the fundamental problem from the WTO. The WTO has a completely different mindset, even from the consumers' or most legislators' mindsets, where at legislative and personal levels we all make distinctions on the way the products are produced to a greater or lesser extent. Can this be dealt with at a WTO level? Politically, at the present time, the answer is a resounding "no" because there is deep suspicion amongst many countries. If you allow these distinctions to be made, then all kinds of trade barriers will be erected. This is partly a matter of convenience because, of course, we have the WTO Agreement on Intellectual Property, which does make very similar distinctions between products which are otherwise indistinguishable. So I would say that where there is a will there is a way but at the present time there does not seem to be a will to make distinctions on the basis of PPMs. This, therefore, leaves us in a situation of: can WTO rules be adapted, in other ways at least, to make the liberalised market less damaging to animal welfare goals? This is where we come to the question of competitivity of domestic producers. It is quite clear that we have different standards in Europe. Let us forget the developing countries, let us talk about the United States, one of our major competitors. The animal welfare standards are startlingly different, for the most part, particularly in farm animal welfare. How do we deal with these differences? "Green box" payments have already been cited. This seems to be politically the most acceptable way in WTO terms, although it may not be acceptable to the Chancellor or to the European Union because it may involve extra costs. Labelling is another but we have dealt with labelling in so far as, at best, labelling will be complementary. It will not be a complete solution. I do not think labelling would be proposed as a total solution in other areas such as the environment, for example. It adds value to the policy objective but it does not usually produce the whole process. Therefore, we are faced with fundamentals of the WTO which is: can we make distinctions on PPMs? Are there general exceptions to the WTO rules applied in such a way that they will be helpful to animal welfare? Answer: probably not, based on the panels there have been so far. If the mindset cannot be changed easily or quickly, which it probably cannot, we have to move to more pragmatic ways of dealing with the problem—"green box" payments, labelling, or some other kinds of border adjustments—which are at least non-trade distorting to WTO partners.
  (Mr Stevenson) At the risk of repeating myself, from the animal welfare point of view, which is so much at the core of our concerns, if I was allowed to say only one thing I would, as Chris Fisher did, talk about the real importance of trying to make some sort of progress on WTO attitudes to process and production methods. It is where all our problems stem from because, as Chris Fisher said, virtually every animal welfare concern is about the way in which the animal is treated and not the end product. I think the WTO attitude to PPMs has become unrealistic and absurd. It started off from a principle that imported products should be treated no less favourably than the domestic ones. We have now arrived at the point where the EU can ban, say, the battery cage, but it cannot ban the import or marketing of battery eggs. Therefore, it can ban the battery egg in the EU but we have to treat the imported battery egg as favourably as our own free-range egg. We cannot distinguish between them. So we have now got to the point where the imported product has to be treated more favourably than the domestic one because of the PPM rules.

  196. Is not the root of the problem that there are no common universal standards and views about animal welfare? Therefore, however perfect it may be, the only way you could move forward to a more universal concept is through the WTO?
  (Mr Stevenson) What I believe is that there is a way of making progress, if the political will is there, on PPMs. I believe it would not be unreasonable to say to the WTO: let WTO members be able to make PPM distinctions in their marketing or import regulations subject, of course, to certain provisos. That they are non-discriminatory. That they are not disguised restrictions on trade. That they can be supported by sound science. It is not some arbitrary or whimsical distinction. That the PPM distinction being made is one of substance. In other words, we are not talking about some little technical difference. We are not saying, "We allow 450 square centimetres and you only allow 400 so we will ban your import." It has to be something of substance. "We have banned the battery cage, you have not, we do not want battery eggs." When making your PPM distinction, you would have to show that this is supported by the public in your jurisdiction, through opinion polls or whatever. There is a strong ethical mood. I believe a way forward could be made on PPMs. The other thing I want to emphasise again is the importance of getting clarity into the "green box". We were enormously heartened when last week the Minister of Agriculture, for the first time, started to talk about public money being used to help producers move from intensive to more humane systems. That is permissible under the Rural Development Regulation. The query is whether it will be challenged under the "green box". The "green box" does not clearly allow payments to promote high welfare.
  (Mr Bowles) There are two points to pick up on your multilateral question. The first is that there are common standards, obviously both within the 15 countries of the EU, but also within the 30 or so countries that are signed up to the Council of Europe standards on the Convention on Farming and the Convention on Transport. The second point is that even if there was a common standard on certain animal welfare standards, which was recognised as a global convention, for instance, it would be a bottom line. It would not solve the fundamental question which is: if the EU wanted to raise its standard above that bottom line, would it run into the same problem as we are talking about now?

Mr Jack

  197. If I was responsible for food exports from a less developed country, and I heard what you said; and I said that I produce an indistinguishable product from the one that you do in Europe, but I cannot implement your so-called high welfare standards because it will make life more difficult for me and my people will suffer, who comes first? The people or the animals?
  (Mr Stevenson) The developing country who said, "We cannot afford your standards," I do not believe that is a problem. Of course, we are sensitive to these concerns. Most people who support animal welfare organisations are the very same people who are concerned with developing countries. But first, as I said earlier, often the cost differences are really tiny. Secondly, remember we are not saying to the developing country that we will not import your eggs unless all your egg production meets our standards. What they do with their egg production for their domestic market or other export markets is their business. We are saying that the bit of their production which comes to us, we want it to be to the standard which we would insist on in our own territory. That should not be a problem. I am not aware of a single country in the world that has all of its egg laying hens or pigs in the same production system. Even in the most intensive countries, say France, you will get some very good free-range pigs and chickens. This applies world-wide. So one is merely saying to the developing country who want to export to the EU, "Please bring your exports from your free-range systems or non-intensive systems." I do not believe it is a problem in practice.

Mr Mitchell

  198. We have come on to the WTO and Millennium Round negotiations. Effectively you are saying that to achieve better animal welfare you are prepared to strike a major blow at Britain's competitive situation of, say, egg producers by the caged bird restriction, which will effectively, from 2010, ban caged birds. Now that does pose a unique problem for this country, which does not affect many other countries. Firstly, our scale of production is higher, so that ban is going to be a more serious blow against the industry. Secondly, we are a crowded island and do not have space for the kind of free-range or barn production that will be substituted. Think of the planning nightmare that poultry producers are going to face if this comes in.
  (Mr Fisher) You have to accept, in the first instance, that this is really the philosophy of the WTO, which they would happily accept. They advocate the idea of competitive advantage. If space was an advantage for a particular country in egg production, therefore, they should be allowed to exploit that egg production. We do not take that view. We think there is a case for being able to produce eggs closer to home and to the standards you prefer. The question is then: how can we deal with that in the context of a liberalised system? I do not think any of us advocate the idea that we just force up standards domestically and to hell with the consequences.

  199. You are prepared to impose a major blow on British production, are you not?
  (Mr Fisher) No, I do not think so at all.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 11 April 2000