Select Committee on Agriculture Appendices to the Minutes of Evidence


Annex C

AGRICULTURAL LIBERALISATION AND ITS ENVIRONMENTAL EFFECTS

  Note: being a study of farmers' intentions, the results of this study must be interpreted with caution. They are also based on a more radical liberalisation scenario than is likely to be agreed in the next round. Nevertheless, the results provide a useful contribution to the debate and correspond with earlier research for the Agencies (Doyle et al, 1997).

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY FROM THE REPORT FOR THE UK WILDLIFE AND COUNTRYSIDE AGENCIES BY POTTER ET AL, WYE COLLEGE, 1999

  1.  There has long been speculation about the likely social and environmental consequences of a complete withdrawal of agricultural support under the CAP. The contention that the CAP has been one of the major causes of the environmental damage and decline of the last 40 years has underpinned campaigns to rebalance agricultural support in favour of the environment and provided a convincing intellectual justification for long term reform. Nevertheless, from an early stage, there has been ambivalence towards the idea that simply dismantling the CAP would redress the balance and a growing sense that agri-environmental change may be subject to "hysteresis"—the failure of effects to reverse themselves even as their apparent underlying cause is removed. It is a paradox of the present debate that while the present CAP is clearly unsustainable in its present form, dismantling it quickly and without replacement is coming to be seen as equally problematic from an environmental point of view.

  2.  With the liberalisation of the CAP now a more realistic long term possibility in the wake of the Uruguay Round Agriculture Agreement, predictions about how Europe's countryside would adjust to more open market conditions are of greatly more than academic interest. Indeed, there is already evidence that the hypothesised social and environmental implications have been factored into the policy making process, forecasts of the "desertification" of rural Europe being used to justify the need to maintain a "European model" of agriculture beyond the next WTO Round. In reality, little is known empirically about the likely sequence of events following agricultural liberalisation; while modelling work has improved knowledge of the way economically rational decision makers might respond to policy change, it cannot identify any systematic variations in the way farm households would respond to the withdrawal of agricultural support. The GB Statutory Countryside Agencies are aware of this, and over the last two years have been commissioning empirical research to assess the environmental consequences of short and long-range CAP reform. This report sets out the results from the most recent of these studies, undertaken to gain a better understanding of the farmer response to agricultural liberalisation in different environmental settings across the EU.

  3.  The specific objective of this research was to carry out an intentions survey of farmers in five countries (England, Wales, Scotland, Germany and Spain) in order to better understand how farmers would respond when confronted with such sudden and radical policy change. A questionnaire survey of 244 farmers identified current plans and farm family trajectories and then used a form of sensitivity analysis to measure the degree to which these would be adjusted, reinforced or abandoned under conditions of Full Liberalisation. Further analysis explored some of the environmental consequences of the observed tenor and pattern of response in different agri-environmental settings. In addition, the presentation of a "Green CAP" scenario has enabled analysis of the willingness of farmers to take up environmental payments under some future rearrangement of the agricultural support system.

  4.  Five study areas were selected, ranging from an intensive, largely arable landscape in East Anglia to an example of one of the EU's most extensive farming systems in the dehesa heartland of Extremadura in Cáceres, southern Spain. In between there were study areas in Wales (a mixed farming area in Ceredigion), Scotland (a hill farming area in mid-Argyll) and Germany (an area of mixed, part-time farming in the Swabian Alb).

  5.  According to the survey results, Full Liberalisation would elicit the following types of farmer response:

    (a)  cost cutting and enterprise restructuring;

    (b)  reductions in farm household consumption;

    (c)  diversification and a move towards becoming more pluriactive;

    (d)  sale of land and other farm assets;

    (e)  early retirement, with or without succession; and

    (f)  exit from farming.

  6.  Of these options, significant numbers of respondents said they would be more likely to consider (d) to (f) than (a) to (c). In fact, 25 per cent of farmers in the sample predicted they would leave farming within the next 10 years if agricultural liberalisation came about. The resulting shake out of farmers and land would be most decisive in the Welsh and Scottish study areas (60 per cent predicting they would leave farming), locations where farmers are most dependent on existing agricultural support, and have fewest opportunities for off farm work or diversification. It would be least pronounced in East Anglia and Spain, where policy change would be met with a more graduated agricultural response. In the German study area, while it was clear that large numbers of farmers would plan to give up farming, it was less obvious that they would give up land. This exception aside, analysis suggests that, overall, as much as 42 per cent of land on survey farms overall would change hands within 10 years of the liberalisation of support. For many of the remaining family farmers determined to remain on the land, the initial response to a cost-price squeeze would be to adjust consumption rather than production, with a small minority contemplating any serious disengagement from agriculture as an income source. It remains unclear how far their attempts to absorb the economic consequences of the withdrawal of support would ensure long term survival. Indeed, there was evidence from the survey that a further shake out of land is likely to take place in marginal countryside as the rate of succession to existing farms declines.

  7.  The environmental consequences of all this would be complex, long term and heavily sensitive to context. The following main types of environmental effect were identified:

  Short term, direct effects: It is clear that there would be some in-field extensification of production driven by the need to cut "discretionary expenditure" during the initial phase of the transition. But there would also be a cut-back in conservation investment and management of the conservation resource, identified by respondents in the East Anglian study area particularly as an early casualty of the expected squeeze.

  Medium term, indirect effects: Further into the transition, there would be indirect (and less determinate) environmental consequences resulting from the adjustments farmers make in order to maintain farm household income. Among these would be a trend towards more pluriactivity and there are hints in the data that this would be associated with an extensification of production on farms.

  Long term, delayed effects: It is likely that there eventually be profound changes in land use and management brought about by longer term farm structural change. If the analysis presented here is correct, these structural changes will eclipse any adjustments made within fields or farms on surviving farms, reallocating land to surviving farms but in locations such as mid-Argyll, Ceredigion, and Cáceres, also bringing about transfers of land out of farming altogether. Again, the geographical unevenness of this adjustment is an integral part of the story: while in East Anglia 80 per cent of any land given up is predicted to remain in farming, in Ceredigion 48 per cent is thought likely to move into a non-agricultural use.

  8.  It is difficult to draw up a balance sheet of the environmental costs and benefits of these different effects. This uncertainty is greatest in relation to the environmental consequences of large scale structural change, where the relocation of land between farms and land users may create opportunities as well as threats for conservationists. In the East Anglian study area, the disappearance of the few remaining "residual" farms currently operating in the spaces between larger holdings, could trigger the further rationalisation of field boundaries and the loss of habitats associated with small scale farms. In the Scottish, Welsh and Spanish study areas, it is a reasonable assumption that there will be a new pattern of land holding centred on larger, more extensively managed farms. The likely consequences of this for conservation capital and, in the Scottish case, upland vegetation, require further investigation. Some land may well be bought up by forestry interests or, in the Scottish and Spanish study areas, revert to estate owners with game or forestry interests. The environmental implications of such transfers depend on the form and pattern of any new tree planting and the management regimes installed by landlords and new owners.

  9.  The policy implications of these findings need to be interpreted with care. For instance, it is probably now politically unrealistic (and may be environmentally undesirable) to argue for the retention of base-line agricultural support in order to underwrite the survival of large numbers of marginal farms. By emphasising the sensitivity of many family farms to the withdrawal of agricultural support, the research also underscores their heavy policy dependence, their economic marginality and their vulnerability to the larger technological and cultural forces for restructuring which operate beyond policy control. A more reasonable policy stance is one which accepts the inevitability of further structural change in marginal countryside but also identifies limits to this process, beyond which savings from agricultural support are outweighed by the growing social and environmental costs of farming decline and rural depopulation. A corollary to this analysis is the adoption of a precautionary approach to designing alternative systems of rural support, setting up payment structures which enable many (though probably not all) existing farmers or their replacements to occupy rural land, while also providing an incentive to maintain and enhance biodiversity and countryside character. The system must be dynamic and capable of adjustment up or down as the limits of acceptable change are better understood and have been aired in public debate.

  10.  The Green CAP was presented to farmers in the sample in order to assess their reaction to a system of payments which combined an element of support subject to environmental compliance with higher tier incentive payments for environmental management. It was found to be effective in retaining farmers and land in agriculture, though its purchase was greater in study areas like Argyll with a history of agri-environmental involvement than in Cáceres, where decoupled environmental payments were viewed as a foreign concept. Overall, however, farmers' responses suggest that 23 per cent more land is likely to be retained in farming under a Green CAP than under Full Liberalisation. Of the land given up by the existing generation of farmers, 30 per cent more would pass to a successor and less onto the open market. At the same time, however, farmers' expectations regarding compliance requirements were low, with the most willing participants being the farmers who expected to have to make the fewest adjustments to their current farming practices. This suggests that, while acceptable as a safety net for vulnerable farms, a tiered system of environmental payments may continue to be resisted if it requires substantial changes to farming systems and the way land is managed.

  11.  The research has shed new light on the nature of the farmer reaction to what, by any standards, would be very radical policy change. In this, it elaborates the "benchmark scenario" within the current debate about long range CAP reform. Nevertheless, it is clear that more work remains to be done if policy makers are to have a sound knowledge base for future policy development. This should include:

    —  research which develops the policy applicability of the concept of limits to acceptable change in both farm structural and land use terms;

    —  further empirical research in order to map the relationship between current farming practices, systems and structures and biodiversity and countryside character; and

    —  longitudinal research to track the sort of agri-environmental transformations mentioned above as they occur.

  In all these cases, it will be necessary to link the collection of land cover and ecological change data to socioeconomic surveys of the decisions, motives and aspirations of individual land managers. There is a particularly strong case for such work taking place within the context of the Government's Countryside Surveys.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 4 July 2000