APPENDIX 26
Memorandum submitted by Andrew and Nicola
Morris (Q38)
INTRODUCTION
We are a husband and wife partnership farming a 65
acre County Council dairy farm in Worcestershire.
On leaving school we both worked on several different
farms before attending agricultural college: Andrew gained an
NCA at Walford and Nicola a BSc Agricultural Technology at Harper
Adams. Andrew successfully applied for the tenancy at Eatons farm
and began farming in his own right in 1991.
On leaving agricultural college Nicola worked as
a dairy and business management consultant for Genus (now Axient)
for six years, and began farming with Andrew in 1995.
It is our intention to remain in the dairy industry
until we retire (2025), though we will struggle to continue if
the milk price falls any further.
Our submission will hopefully provide some useful
information on the marketing of milk from a dairy farmer's point
of view.
THE MILK
MARKET IN
ENGLAND AND
WALES
In 1991, we were legally obliged to sell all our
milk to the Milk Marketing Board (MMB).
The MMB was formed in the 1930s to provide individual
farmers with an effective way of marketing their milk. Prior to
that farmers were at the mercy of the dairy companies and received
an artificially low milk price.
With the advent of milk quotas in 1984 and changes
in the market place (low fat milks) it was generally agreed within
the industry that the milk market should be deregulated.
In 1994 the Scheme of Reorganisation was approved
by Ministers. In November 1994 we were at liberty to sell our
milk, in theory, to any processor. In reality at the time we had
two choices:
sell our milk to a farmers' co-op,
either Milk Marque* or the Milk Group**
sell direct to the local processorAvonmore
dairies.
We opted to sell our milk to Milk Marque because
we believe that farmers will never receive a fair price for their
milk unless they market collectively.
The five year period from deregulation to present
day overwhelmingly supports this belief.
*Milk Marque is a farmer-owned co-operative marketing
milk in England and Wales
**The Milk Group is a farmer-owned co-operative marketing milk
in the Midlands
OUR MILK
PRICE
Table 1 shows the changes in our milk price from
1990 to 1999 and the membership of Milk Marque (our co-op) 1994
to 1999.
Table 1: Our milk price pre-deregulation
to present day
|
Year | Milk price ppl
| Membership of Milk Marque nos*
|
|
1990-91 | 19.0
| |
1991-92 | 21.5
| |
1992-93 | 21.7
| |
1993-94 | 21.4
| |
1994-95# | 21.8
| 20.3 |
1995-96 | 24.0
| 19.3 |
1996-97 | 24.3
| 17.4 |
1997-98 | 21.3
| 15.5 |
1998-99 | 18.3
| 13.1 |
1999-00 | 16.9**
| 12.1** |
|
Notes
*Milk Marque Membership as at the end of each milk year (March)
**Budgeted figures
# Deregulation
The dramatic decline in our milk price may be due in part to the
strength of the pound but it is mainly due to the demise of Milk
Marque. In 1994-95 Milk Marque marketed about 60 per cent of the
milk in the UK, today (October 1999) it is about 39 per cent.
The decline in milk price has had a dramatic effect on our farm
profit. Table 2 shows the effect of the declining milk price from
1997 to 1999 on farm profitability.
Some of the decline in profit has been offset by cost reductions
mainly:
labour costs (mainly contract labour)
animal feed costs
rent (we have reduced the amount of land on short-term
let)
We are now considerably more "efficient" than we were
but it has been extracted at a high price: we now work a 60-70
hour week compared to a 50-60 hour week; we have not had a family
holiday for two years; the farm is now farmed more intensively
than it was, ie we have a similar number of animals on a smaller
acreage.
Table 2: The effect of the milk price on the profitability
of our farm 1997-1999
|
Year | Actual | Actual
| 6 months actual |
| 1997-98 | 1998-99
| 6 mths Budget |
| | | 1999-00
|
|
Total Income (%) | 100 | 88
| 80 |
Total Costs (%) | 100 | 92
| 82 |
Profit (%) | 100 | 79
| 57 |
Milk price ppl | 21.3 | 18.3
| 16.8 |
|
Despite the decline in milk price we remain committed members
of Milk Marque as we still believe that farmers will never receive
a fair price for their milk unless they market collectively.
OUR MEMBERSHIP
OF MILK
MARQUE
When we joined Milk Marque we knew that we would get a lower price
for other milk than our neighbours who opted to sell direct or
join smaller groups.
We believe the reasons for this are:
milk supply varies throughout the year, with a
"spring flush" and a trough in late summer
transport charges
liquid milk market
Milk supply versus processing requirements
In the UK we have a distinct seasonal pattern of milk production.
On the whole most processors would prefer a level supply to enable
their factories to run at optimum efficiency. Therefore, it is
in the interest of the processors to source a percentage of their
milk direct From the farm and to buy a varying percentage (depending
on the time of year) of their milk from Milk Marque. That way
they have a guaranteed minimum supply and Milk Marque has the
sole responsibility of coping with the UK's seasonal pattern of
production.
The buying behaviour of the processors means that at farm level
the direct supplying farmer is offered a price incentive to supply
direct whilst Milk Marque members have an artificially lower price
because they carry the costs of finding a market for milk at times
of the year when there is an over supply.
TRANSPORT CHARGES
The advent of deregulation inevitably lead to an increase in transport
costs: within a five mile radius of our farm, milk is collected
by three different tankers taking milk to three different destinations,
pre deregulation there would have been one.
Milk Marque has a higher share of these transport charges: most
processors will generally offer direct supplying contracts to
the closest farms, leaving Milk Marque to collect milk from more
outlying farms.
Milk Marque also has to bear the costs of transhipment: milk is
normally delivered direct to nearby customers using the vehicles
that collected it, however, a significant amount of Milk Marque's
milk is transported over longer distances i.e. transhipped. This
milk is taken to the depot and reloaded into larger multi-purpose
tankers and delivered to its final destination.
As Milk Marque's membership has declined the proportion of milk
transhipped has increased: in 1998 over 45 per cent of Milk Marque's
milk was transhipped.
LIQUID MILK
MARKET
The liquid milk market generates the highest returns to processors.
The three main liquid processors, Express Dairies, Unigate and
MD Foods, all source a significant percentage of their requirements
direct ie approximately 40 per cent, 25 per cent and 50 per cent
respectively (source UK milk report 1999).
Pre-deregulation, all dairy farmers had a share of the liquid
milk premium, through the MMB's "pooled price policy".
Post deregulation, as Milk Marque's membership has declined with
an ever increasing number of farmers supplying direct, the remaining
members have an ever declining share of the liquid milk premium
and therefore, an ever declining overall milk price.
The UK seasonal pattern of production, transport charges and the
liquid milk premium all have a negative effect on Milk Marque's
milk price. Even with any economies of scale, Milk Marque is destined
to be at or near the bottom of any milk price league table.
The milk price Milk Marque achieves determines the size of its
membership. This is not a precise relationship, some farmers will
leave if they are offered a better price, others will only leave
once the Milk Marque milk price is close to their cost of production.
Thus, Milk Marque must be efficient, aggressive and innovative
in the market place if it is to survive and prosper, and it could
be argued that unless Milk Marque operates in this manner it is
not acting in the best interests of its members.
One of the features which distinguishes a co-op from other organisations
is that :
"It aims to optimise the returns to members for their produce,
rather than to make a return on investment to shareholders."
It is Milk Marque's behaviour in the market place which ultimately
lead to its referral to the Monopolies and Mergers Commission
on 27 January 1998 under the monopoly provisions of the Fair Trading
Act 1973.
The Monopolies and Mergers Commission (MMC) Report on
the supply of raw milk in Great Britain
As members of Milk Marque, having read chapter 2 (conclusions)
of the MMC report, we accept the findings that:
Milk Marque is a scale monopoly, even at its present size of 39
per cent (1999) and it has raised the average price of milk by
virtue of its selling system
However, if it can been shown that the GB milk price is artificially
lower than it should be, could this conclusion be reversed ie
Milk Marque acted as an effective co-op and achieved an optimum
price for its members?
MILK MARQUE'S
INFLUENCE ON
PRICE
The MMC put it to Milk Marque that, in principle, if prices had
been set above the competitive level (level sufficient to cover
costs with a normal level of profit) this might be attributable
either to the exercise of market power on its part as by far the
largest supplier of milk in GB or to the CAP price support system.
The MMC measured the effects of CAP by calculating the coverage
ratio (coverage ratio refers to the ratio of the producer's farm
gate price to the target price) and found that the average coverage
ratio for the period after deregulation, at 89 per cent, has been
about five percentage points higher than the average coverage
ratio prior to deregulation.
The MMC put it to Milk Marque that this increase in the coverage
ratio broadly reflected the degree to which it was exercising
its market power.
The Council of Ministers sets the target price, a key element
of the coverage ratio, at levels that EC producers might realistically
be expected to achieve. Therefore, if it can be shown that Great
Britain (GB) has certain characteristics unique to its milk market,
and that these characteristics have had a greater effect since
deregulation, it could be concluded that changes in the coverage
ratio do not necessarily indicate the degree to which Milk Marque
was exercising its market power.
THE GREAT
BRITAIN MILK
MARKET
Features of the GB Milk Market which are unique:
1. The effect of the strength of sterling has a variable
effect on the balance of trade.
2. GB has the largest liquid milk market in EC
3. There is very little vertical integration in GB compared
to other EC countries
4. There is a huge range in the size of the milk producer
groups marketing their own milk in GB. In the EU as a whole there
is a greater uniformity in size.
1. THE BALANCE
OF TRADE
AND THE
STRENGTH OF
STERLING
Table 3 shows the UK balance of trade 1990 to 1997 and changes
in the exchange rate over the same period
Table 3: UK balance of trade*
|
Year | Balance of Trade
| ecu/sterling
|
| £m
| tonnes | exchange rate
|
| | | Ecu/£
|
|
1997 | 320
| -47,500 | Jan
| 0.768 |
1996 | 408.8
| -122,280 | Jan
| 0.856 |
1995 | 249.0
| -15,360 | Jan
| 0.78 |
1994 | na
| -39,910 | Jan
| 0.75 |
1993 | na
| -5,830 | Jan
| 0.80 |
1992 | na
| -162,580 | Jan
| 0.72 |
1991 | na
| -39,740 | Jan
| |
1990 | na
| -32,530 | Jan
| |
|
* exports from the UK minus imports into the UK
(source: Dairy facts and figures 1998; MMC report
on the supply in GB of raw cows' milk of; UK milk report 1999)
MAIN POINTS
a) The UK is a net importer of dairy products
b) The pound was at its weakest in January 1996
and at its strongest in January 1992
c) When the pound is strong imports are cheaper
and exports are more expensive. Therefore, when the pound is strong
the balance of trade will be more negative; in respect of dairy
products changes in the value of sterling do not appear to have
a precise effect on the balance of trade:
For example when the £ was strong in January
1992 the balance of trade was -162,580 tonnes (the highest deficit)
and when it was at its weakest in January 1996 the trade deficit
was -122,280 tonnes.
2. GB HAS THE
LARGEST LIQUID
MILK MARKET
EC
It could be argued that, because the returns from
the liquid milk market are higher than for other products (Annex
1), GB should have one of the highest milk prices in the EU.
Pre deregulation, there was some restriction on how
much milk was available for each dairy product; though the liquid
milk market was given priority.
Post deregulation, the only restriction on how much
milk is available for each product is price. Therefore, in theory
if a processor was prepared to increase his share of the liquid
milk market he could do so by securing a large proportion of his
milk on market led contracts at a price. If several processors
adopted this policy it would have a significant upward pressure
on milk price.
Indeed in the two years immediately following deregulation
demand for market led contracts was at its highest. (table 2.2
p43 MMC report 1999).
3. THERE IS
VERY LITTLE
VERTICAL INTEGRATION
IN GB COMPARED
TO OTHER
EC COUNTRIES
Vertical integration is accepted to enhance the milk
price of producers; lack of vertical integration is often cited
as one of the reasons why the GB milk price is lower than most
other EU countries (MMC report 1999 6.72).
Since deregulation the degree of vertical integration
has increased (Annex 2), it is not unreasonable to assume that
this would have an upward pressure on price.
4. MILK PRODUCER
GROUPS MARKETING
THEIR OWN
MILK IN
GB
There are currently 41 milk producer groups in GB
(UK Milk Report 1999), varying in size from 10 members to over
13,000.
The majority of these groups are non quota holding:
when they sign their contract with an individual processor, that
processor is assigned the producer's individual quota.
These producers are effectively direct suppliers,
though they can leave their chosen processor or processors, once
they terminate their contract.
On the whole non quota holding producer groups tend
to supply only one or possibly two different processors at the
same time.
By assigning their quota to the individual processor,
it is the processor's responsibility to deal with the quota administration
(ie transfer of quota, balancing milk supply with quota available,
calculation and collection of super levy).
This direct supply arrangement is most suitable for
small groups as they avoid any of the administration costs associated
with the marketing of milk and the management of quota.
Quota holding groups, of which there are eight in
GB, are more costly to run than non-quota holding groups but quota
holding groups are at liberty to sell their milk to any processor
and they are never tied to just one processor.
It is very difficult to determine whether the number
of groups, the type of group and the range in size have a positive
or negative effect on price.
It could, however, be concluded, that because the
producer group structure is markedly different than that in other
EU countries, the market will operate differently and comparisons
between EU price and GB price may be misleading.
Clearly, certain characteristics of the GB market
are unique (ie the size of the liquid milk market, degree of vertical
integration, and the milk producer group structure), and there
is also evidence to suggest that changes in the strength of the
pound do not affect the balance of trade in the conventional manner.
Is it possible that these two factors make comparisons
between the GB farmgate price and the EU target price imprecise?
Is it possible that if Milk Marque had been able
to supply some quantitative analysis (MMC report 1999 2.98 &
2.104) to show that the rise in milk price, immediately post deregulation,
was in fact due to legitimate changes in the market rather than
to an abuse of market power then milk producers would now be facing
a more promising future?
THE FUTURE
Our initial reaction on hearing Milk Marque's proposals
to split into three co-ops was disbelief that such a major change
in policy was necessary.
Having read some of the evidence presented in the
MMC report, it is clear that Milk Marque must either undergo structural
change or the selling system must be reformed.
The proposed structural changes will not necessarily
result in three strong co-ops because :
The new co-ops will still establish the
baseline price to all producers (as Milk Marque has historically
done) by virtue of their size relative to existing groups.
The new co-ops will have higher transport charges
than existing groups, as members are spread over a wider geographical
area.
The new co-ops will not have a fair share of
the liquid milk premium whilst producers currently selling direct
continue to sell direct.
The only advantage the new co-ops will have is that
they will be able to expand their processing activities. Though,
as with all new businesses the payback will not be immediate and
will require significant investment. Thus, any additional processing
capacity is unlikely to have an immediate effect on milk price
Reform of the selling system is an option, but for
this option to succeed a certain amount of intervention from a
third party would probably be required, and in addition the problem
of Milk Marque's high transport costs would have to be addressed.
As milk producers we are not convinced that either
the structural reforms or reform of the selling system will be
in the best interests of producers.
A more radical approach is required and can only
be achieved with Government intervention.
WHY SHOULD
THE GOVERNMENT
INTERVENE ON
BEHALF OF
MILK PRODUCERS?
In virtually all countries, whether high income and
mature or developing, free market or centrally planned, the Government
is in some way involved with its agricultural industry (Geoffrey
Whitehead). If an individual Government does not intervene then
foreign competitors will increase their market share at the expensive
of that Government's own producers.
The GB dairy sector
Historically, the GB has always had one of the lowest
milk prices in Europe (except for the two years immediately post
deregulation).
The UK milk price is currently bottom of the EU milk
price league table and is likely to remain there if Milk Marque
is split into three co-ops: if Milk Marque has artificially raised
the milk price by virtue of its position as a scale monopoly the
disbanding of Milk Marque will result in a fall in milk price.
For a significant number of dairy producers any further
decline in milk price will be unsustainable.
Trends in profitability, as discussed in the MMC
report, indicated that farms in an ADAS survey were achieving
a profit of 4.00 ppl in 1997-98, since then the milk price has
declined by, on average, a further 2.75 ppl to March 1999 (UK
Milk Report 1999). A further decline of 1-2 ppl is projected for
the milk year ending March 2000.
A scheme must be devised which enables both milk
producers and processors to achieve an acceptable profit, whilst
delivering a fair price to consumers.
Milk marketing
In the UK we are in a unique position in so far as
we have experienced a statutory milk marketing scheme (ie 1930s
to 1994) and also a deregulated market from 1994 to 1999.
The statutory scheme was reasonably successful until
the introduction of quotas and also the increase in demand for
low fat milk, though it did stifle innovation and did not encourage
efficiency in the processing sector.
The deregulated milk marketing scheme has also failed
and will fail again if the only alteration to it is the disbanding
of Milk Marque.
An alternative would be a scheme which:
only allowed farmers to sell milk
through a quota holding co-op
organised transport on a regional basis and allowed
tankers to carry milk from more than one co-op
Why should such a scheme be adopted?
The processing and retail sectors are now dominated
by a handful of companies, primary producers can only derive a
fair price for their product if they can compete on an equal basis.
In order to determine the optimum size and number
of co-ops the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index could be used (2.387
MMC report 1999). British farmers are notoriously bad at co-operating
and will not do so unless they are forced by statute, thus, if
the proposed scheme is in the interests of the majority, membership
of a co-op would have to be legally binding; the choice of co-op
would be the farmers' decision.
If farmers continue to supply direct they will undermine
any new co-ops, in the same way as Milk Marque has been undermined
over the last five years.
The present transport system is inefficient and is
taking money out of the industry which neither milk producers
or processors can afford to lose.
The present transport system has environmental implications:
there are more tankers on our roads and each tanker has to drive
further to gain a full load.
If tankers were able to collect milk from farms on
the basis of the destination of the milk rather than on the basis
of which milk producer group had sold it, the industry as a whole
would benefit.
Indeed in its submission to the MMC, Dairy Crest
said that it wanted a transport system that was cost effective.
Any transport costs should be quoted separately and processors
and Milk Marque should work together to reduce costs for their
mutual benefit.
The environmental benefits of a pooled transport
system can not be underestimated.
IF THERE
IS NO
GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION
WHAT WILL
HAPPEN TO
OUR DAIRY
INDUSTRY ?
It is true that a lower milk price will, in theory,
increase the efficiency of the Industry and should, therefore,
benefit consumers.
However, there must be a point at which the milk
price is high enough to allow a business to survive but insufficient
to allow a proper re-investment programme to be implemented.
The rate at which producers are leaving the dairy
industry is increasing. In 1996-97 6.2 per cent left, prior to
that the average rate of decline over a 12 year period was about
3 per cent per year (MMC report 1999).
The loss of milk producers from the industry has
implications on other sectors of agriculture: in the last 18 months
four large herds (ie 100-250 cows) have been sold within a 15
mile radius of our farm, only one of those producers retired,
the other three have become beef, sheep and/or arable farmers.
Farmers are an enigma to the general public: they
complain a lot often when there is nothing to complain about.
But when the "chips are really down" they can be eerily
silent.
Looking at out own business we know the milk price
is getting uncomfortably close to our costs of production and
we by industry standards are in the top 10 per cent of farms in
terms of efficiency.
How is everyone else coping and how long can they
survive ?
CONCLUSION
There is definitely a need for structural and cultural
changes in the UK milk market.
There is, however, only one proposal on the table;
that is the disbanding of Milk Marque and the creation of three
new co- ops. Our fear, as producers, is that unless the whole
industry grasps the concept that co- operation is the key to surviving
and prospering we all face a very bleak future.
4 October 1999
|