Select Committee on Culture, Media and Sport Minutes of Evidence


MEMORANDUM SUBMITTED BY THE ANTIQUITIES DEALERS ASSOCIATION

  1.  Our association, formed in 1982, represents the leading UK dealers in classical and pre-classical antiquities from Europe and the Mediterranean. We do not represent the coin trade, or dealers in antiquities from other areas of the world.

A.  THE IMPACT AND SIZE OF THE ILLICIT TRADE

  2.  For historical reasons London has long been a centre for the legitimate trade. Travellers on the Grand Tour brought back large quantities of antiquities (for example Sir William Hamilton amassed a collection of over 7,000 Greek vases in just over five years), and this tradition was continued over the next 150 years by thousands of people from many countries who travelled and served abroad. Although many of these pieces made their way into public collections, tens of thousands are still circulating on the market.

  3.  Some suggest that London also represents the major centre for illicit antiquities, but in fact the legitimate trade, both dealers and auctioneers, has made great efforts in the last decade to distance themselves from such traffic. This is proven by the declining importance of London within the international trade. Both Switzerland and America are now much larger markets than the UK. We estimate that the turnover of London is less than £20 million per annum, excluding "one-off" sales such as the Canford relief, which realised £7 million alone. This is out of a world turnover of classical antiquities of perhaps £200-£300 million.

  4.  Whilst there is a world-wide problem with smuggling therefore, we feel that the UK contributes little directly to it. It is an international trade however, and we are anxious to help in taking positive steps to improve the global situation.

  5.  It has been particularly galling to see the way in which misinformation quickly becomes accepted as fact; for example an off-the-cuff pronouncement was made some years ago stating that the trade in illicitly excavated material amounted to some £3 billion per annum, and was second only to the trade in drugs. This is clearly nonsense, as even the source of the remark now admits, but journalists have seized on this figure and so the myth is perpetuated. A recent article in The Guardian applied this figure of £3 billion to annual thefts from Saqqara, a single site in Egypt!

  6.  The implications of such attacks are extremely serious; for what is at stake here is the whole foundation on which the art trade is based, namely that the private ownership of art and the connoisseurship which collecting inspires, are desirable in a cultured society. This tenet has been held by almost everyone for the last 500 years. It has had an enormously important effect on the way in which the great museums of the world have developed: most were founded by collector-patrons and drew, and continue to draw, on private sources when expanding their collections. Obviously museums in turn have been seminal in contributing to a much wider appreciation of world cultural heritage.

B.  CURRENT ATTEMPTS TO CONTROL THE ILLICIT TRADE

  7.  Most source countries have some form of control over the export of archaeological material; these range from the pragmatic (the UK, Germany, the Netherlands) to the draconian (Greece, Turkey, Egypt). The fiercest laws were passed at very different times, (in the case of Egypt as late as the 1970s) but are essentially chauvinistic, and it is interesting to note that in almost all cases they have been enacted at a time of nationalistic revival (in Italy under Mussolini, in Greece following the War of Independence from Turkey, in Egypt following Nasser's rule).

  8.  These laws have been designed to foster a belief in outside cultural imperialism, and are both a symptom and a source of a deep emotional feeling. Unfortunately emotion is a bad basis for legislation, and though these laws have proved remarkably ineffective, their emotional basis makes it very difficult for the relevant authorities to adjust them in a way which might make them work.

  9.  These laws are also by no means uniform; for whereas some countries (Egypt, Turkey) have taken the drastic step of "nationalising" all antiquities (even when privately owned for generations), others have allowed private ownership, and dealing, to continue. The latter case usually involves a strict embargo on export, and this has served to produce a false, two-tiered market, but even where export licences were issued in the past it was usually in the form of a single document for each shipment, sometimes containing hundreds of objects. Such documentation was inevitably parted from the material to which it related.

  10.  Given that such privately owned objects were removed from their context years ago, and anti-trade academics regard such objects as worthless, there is no archaeological argument in favour of them being rigidly chained to their country of origin, any more than all Georgian candlesticks should remain within the United Kingdom. By encouraging smuggling, such laws are having a diametrically opposed effect to that which was intended. Adjustment to encourage the legitimate trade would go a long way towards restricting the smuggling routes on which illicit trade depends.

  11.  It is legal to sell and collect antiquities in countries such as Italy. The mechanisms are theoretically in place for getting export licences, but in practice it is impossible to do so. We have first-hand experience of this which we could relate to the Committee if it was felt appropriate.

C.  FACTORS CONTRIBUTING TO THE PROBLEM

  12.  Some archaeologists (it is important to stress the strong divergence of opinion within the academic community—please see the appendix to this submission[1]) regard a trade in antiquities as being wholly undesirable, since they believe that the vast majority of objects on the market have been illicitly excavated in recent times with a concomitant destruction of archaeological evidence. Furthermore, many of them believe that an object outside its context is valueless for the purposes or scholarship. However antiquities have been collected for thousands of years—for example the Romans were avid collectors of Greek sculpture—and in this time, the number of pieces coming onto the market ran to millions. Unfortunately their perceived importance has fluctuated down the ages (for example the Arab inhabitants of Egypt routinely used ancient wood sculptures to light fires) and for this reason provenances for the vast majority of these works have been lost.

  13.  Another area which deserves consideration is the problem of chance finds. It is inevitable that a large proportion of excavated material will be found during the course of normal agricultural and economic activity. War, migration, economic development and sheer indifference have all taken their toll as well. The provenance of large numbers of objects has been discovered by chance, long after they have been sold. Very often the source of pieces is deliberately obscured for perfectly legitimate reasons, where, for example, the inheritor of an object does not wish his family to know that he is selling. The argument put forward by some academics that lack of provenance means that a particular object has recently been stolen is therefore wrong.

  14.  All these issues serve to muddy the water and to create an environment in which it is possible for those opposed to the trade to maintain the pretence that the majority of objects are on the market illicitly. It is true that until very recently, the importance of provenance was not fully understood, except in the case of major collections. This is no longer the case, and both dealers and auctioneers now take great care over this issue. It must be stressed, however, that there will always be large numbers of objects legitimately on the market which have no provable provenance; this fact applies to the whole art market, and indeed any market for second-hand goods. Due diligence on the part of the trade is therefore of the utmost importance.

  15.  Draconian laws result in the destruction of the archaeological record unless a proper system of reward exists, since the finder will usually channel such objects into an illicit market. Anecdotal evidence suggests that the penalties for doing so are now so severe that finders are deliberately destroying pieces rather than run the risk of being caught with them. This is an absurd situation. In this respect the laws of the UK offer a solution. Here a finder has an inducement to declare his discovery. Either the state takes ownership and pays a reward equivalent to the market value, or, if the piece is not of particular importance, ownership is granted to the finder. Either way, the archaeological information is preserved.

D.  POSSIBILITIES FOR IMPROVEMENT

  16.  As mentioned above, we regard UK law as a model in this area. Unfortunately it is unlikely to be adopted by other source countries. EU legislation already requires export licences for goods leaving Europe, and allows adequate redress for claimants of stolen works of art. We have considered the possibility of a passport system for all objects to offer a guarantee of good title, but such a system would involve an enormous international administrative infrastructure. Including coins, the number of objects in circulation runs to millions.

  17.  We feel therefore that a self-policing trade is the only practical solution, and in recent years have made great progress. We are signatories to a variant of the Council for the Prevention of Art Theft code of due diligence. Amongst the most important provisions of the code are the following points. It requires dealers and auctioneers to be confident of the identity of those from whom they buy, and to question the provenance of pieces offered to them. Furthermore it requires payment to be in a form which provides an audit trail.

  18.  There are now mechanisms in place to help dealers check whether objects are stolen. The most important are databases of stolen art. We are working with the Art Loss Register on an agreement which would require members to check all goods above a certain value threshold. This requirement has been pioneered by the International Association of Dealers in Ancient Art and has proved successful.

  19.  We do need more international co-operation however: for example some years ago we learned that the Italian authorities had obtained photographs of thousands of objects which had been illicitly excavated. Incredibly they have refused all requests by us for this information, even though we have approached them at government level, and via Scotland Yard (this fact can be supported by correspondence). We have also identified a number of stolen items ourselves, which were successfully returned, but have never received acknowledgement of our help. Unless we can rely on co-operation from the authorities in source countries our efforts to tackle the problem are severely hampered.

March 2000


1   Not printed. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 17 May 2000