Select Committee on Education and Employment Appendices to the Minutes of Evidence


APPENDIX 9

Memorandum from Andrew Glyn and Esra Erdem, Corpus Christi College, Oxford and Oxford University Department of Economics (JG 15)

THE UK JOBS GAP—LACK OF QUALIFICATIONS AND THE REGIONAL DIMENSION

  1.  It is well known that the unemployment rate, even when measured from labour force surveys, seriously understates lack of work—many of those facing joblessness drop out of the labour force (particularly men) or delay entering it (particularly women). Such "economic inactivity" is very unevenly spread over the UK regions—much more unevenly than unemployment. Moreover inactivity tends to be higher where there is more unemployment. The result is that the "non-employment rate"—the proportion of the relevant population which is not working (the unemployment rate plus the inactivity rate)—shows a very wide degree of variation across regions. Figure 1 demonstrates this for men aged 25-64. In 1997 both the national level of unemployment and regional differences in unemployment were low by the standards of the past two decades. However, inactivity was both high and with wide regional variations so that a number of the older industrial areas were still experiencing a very serious problem of joblessness. Hardly more than 70 per cent of men aged 25-64 were in work in Merseyside, South Yorkshire or Tyne and Wear (the table attached provides the data for some of the most important series used in the charts).

  2.  Lack of work is also particularly concentrated amongst the least qualified; again differences in inactivity amplify the differences in unemployment rates experienced by groups with different educational qualifications. Those with no educational qualifications show much the highest level of joblessness (figure 2). In 1997 around 40 per cent of men aged 25-64 without qualifications were not working, compared to around 10 per cent of those with degrees.

  3.  Regional and educational disadvantage are not separate and independent. On the contrary they interact with each other so that differences in joblessness between regions are far larger for those with poor educational qualifications and they are far higher for non-employment as a whole than for unemployment as registered in the surveys. Figure 3 shows that regional variations in non-employment are comparatively moderate for those with qualifications ranging from university degree to O levels; but regional differences are much higher for those with the lower categories of vocational qualifications and they are absolutely huge for those with no qualifications. Even in the most prosperous regions (South East excluding London and East Anglia) the non-employment of men without qualifications was nearly 30 per cent in 1997. Obviously some non-employment reflects genuinely voluntary early retirement, or other causes such as illness unconnected with the availability of work. However, a good deal of this joblessness must have been involuntary in origin and suggests that the disadvantage suffered by the least qualified is not confined to the less prosperous regions. However, in the older industrial areas the situation of the least qualified is truly catastrophic: a majority of men without qualifications do not have work.

  4.  Joblessness for the least qualified men rose sharply in the recession of the early 1980s (see figure 4, though it should be noted that the rise between 1981 and 1983 is exaggerated by a change in the way the Labour Force Survey was conducted). Since then non-employment has fluctuated with the economic cycle, but around a seemingly inexorable upward trend. Differences between regions in non-employment have remained very large (in contrast to the dispersion of unemployment rates which has declined).

  5.  Those without qualifications are a declining smaller proportion of the labour force. More than 45 per cent of men aged 25-64 had no qualifications in 1979, whereas in 1997 the proportion was 15.8 per cent. The least prosperous regions have the highest proportions (over 20 per cent in four cases—see the table). This reflects both the tendency for school students to gain fewer qualifications in these areas and for outward migration from these areas to affect mainly the more qualified sections of the labour force. It would be absolutely wrong to conclude from the declining number of those without any qualifications that problems in the labour market for the less qualified will soon vanish. Figure 5 shows the regional evolution of non-employment for the first educational quartile of men aged 25-64 (the least educated quarter); up till the early nineties all the bottom quartile had no qualifications, so the chart exactly mirrors figure 4. Thereafter the bottom quarter includes some of those with some "other" vocational qualifications. They also have low employment rates with wide regional variations, although their position is better than those with no qualifications. Moreover the higher proportion of the unqualified in the poorer regions means greater disadvantage in the first quartile as compared to that in the higher employment areas. Thus looking at the bottom quarter, non-employment rates are still extremely high and with a very large regional variation. The problem cannot be written off as confined to a small and diminishing minority.

  6.  Nor should the problem of very high regional joblessness for the less qualified be seen mainly as a problem for older workers. Figure 6 shows the regional variation in non-employment for the bottom one quarter of the educational distribution in each 10 year age group between 25 and 64. For the oldest age group these are all without qualifications; for those aged 25-34 the bottom quarter includes a substantial number with "other" vocational qualifications. Joblessness is highest of course for those over 55, but it is both extremely high and very regionally dispersed across all the age groups. This pattern—a very high and regionally very diverse pattern of non-employment for the least qualified, extending across all age groups—presents an extremely sombre and depressing picture of the UK labour market and one that should be at the centre of concern.

  7.  If the position of regions fluctuated quite rapidly in the league table of joblessness, this would suggest that the regional differences tend to right themselves (by job creation or migration) and thus do not merit special attention. This is far from the truth. Figure 7 plots the non-employment rate for the unqualified in 1979 against the corresponding figure for 1997. In general the low employment regions in 1979 were in a similar position in 1997 (the correlation between their rankings in the two years is highly significant). The fit is not perfect of course; Northern Ireland's relative position has improved, whilst joblessness in South Yorkshire has increased more than would have been expected on the basis of the position in 1979.

  8.  The analysis thus far has concentrated on men. Their experiences exemplify the educational and regional dimensions to the problem of joblessness, and it is simpler to follow through the argument in relation to one group of the labour force at a time. However, it would be quite wrong to suppose that the underlying upward trend in women's participation in the labour force means that less qualified women have escaped the joblessness described above. Figure 8 shows the very high level of non-employment for women without qualifications, substantial regional variations and the fact that this group has singularly failed to benefit from the increased job opportunities for women generally. Figure 9 confirms that, for women as well as men, the high level of, and wide regional variations in, joblessness for the least qualified is spread across all age groups.

  9.  Why are the least qualified far less likely to have work in some regions than in others? It seems obvious that the most important influence is the general level of employment. Figure 10 illustrates this relationship by comparing non-employment for men without qualifications in 1997 with the average level of non-employment for men from all the educational groups. Less obviously, the least qualified are disproportionately affected by lack of work generally; a 1 per cent higher non-employment rate generally in a region is associated with almost a 2 per cent higher employment rate for the least qualified and this relationship is highly significant statistically, whilst those with degrees have regional employment rates virtually independent of average employment rates in the region. This pattern is consistent with the general idea that in areas with low employment many of the least qualified get "bumped down" the jobs ladder and out of work.

  10.  The very fact that the regions with particularly low employment for the least qualified are universally thought of as the old industrial areas suggests that the problem is that decline of traditional industries has deprived the least qualified of work. This is of course exactly what happened. However, it would be wrong to conclude that only industry provides work for the least qualified (especially men) and that services jobs cannot fill the gap. Simply in terms of providing work (and leaving aside pay and conditions) a statistical analysis reveals that an extra 1 per cent of people employed in services brings as many jobs for the unqualified as the same amount of extra employment in industry (true for men as well as women). The problem of the old industrial areas is that, having lost very large numbers of industrial jobs (especially in the most urban parts, see Turok and Edge 1999), they have not replaced them with additional service jobs. Whilst the majority of service jobs depend on regional incomes generally (like retail trade) or on population (like health and education jobs largely financed by central government), the finance and business services sector in particular produces "regional exports" just like manufacturing. Preserving and extending what remains of the industrial base, and extending it into service sectors with the potential to bring income into the regions, is essential for meeting the jobs crisis for the least qualified.

  11.  The degree of regional joblessness market poses severe problems for the government's "welfare to work" programme, as has been forcefully pointed out (Turok and Webster 1998). This note has documented how regional employment problems are overwhelmingly concentrated on the least qualified. Though the regions considered here are large, some of them have astoundingly high levels of joblessness amongst the least qualified and the problem extends through the full range of age groups. Local concentrations of joblessness are far worse still. It is very hard to see how the government's strategy centred around Welfare to Work can be adequate to meet these problems. All the focus is on the "employability" of targeted groups of individuals—their attitudes, experience and the response of employers to them. Even if this programme was very successful, and large numbers of people are induced to search more actively for work, the process by which this is supposed to create more jobs is essentially macroeconomic. It is presumed that a larger labour force looking actively for work, a bigger reserve army of labour, will hold down wage pressure generally; this in itself is a debatable assumption given that those involved in Welfare to Work policies (long-term unemployed, people on sickness benefit, single parents, workless households and so forth) are disproportionately concentrated in the low employment areas where the labour market is already very weak especially for the least qualified. If there was a significant effect on wage pressure generally, the argument is that the Monetary Policy Committee would respond by running a more expansionary policy, which in turn would tend to increase employment generally. However, there is no way that this would have a disproportionately large impact in creating work in the areas where joblessness is disproportionately concentrated. Even on very optimistic assumptions about the chain of effects from policies to increase the effective labour supply to the macroeconomic creation of jobs, there is no mechanism for bringing the jobs to the areas where they are most needed.

  12.  This memorandum has attempted to highlight the extreme regional concentration of joblessness amongst the less qualified. The conclusion is that analysis of policies to actively steer demand for labour into the low employment regions (Gudgin 1995) should be brought back to the centre of policy discussion.

Andrew Glyn and Ersa Erdem
Corpus Christi College, Oxford and Oxford Institute of Economics and Statistics
October 1999


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 18 May 2000