Select Committee on Environmental Audit Appendices to the Minutes of Evidence


APPENDIX 20

Memorandum from Economics for the Environment Ltd (EFTEC Ltd)

INTRODUCTION: GOVERNMENT POLICY ON MARKET BASED INSTRUMENTS[30]

  1.  We wholeheartedly support the efforts made by government to introduce market-based instruments (MBIs) in an effort to make environmental policy more efficient. In particular, we support the introduction of environmental taxes on "externalities" (uncompensated environmental damage to third parties), the use of tradable permits and quotas, and "hybrid" instruments that combine these features with so-called "negotiated agreements". Indeed, one of us is partly responsible for the initial advocacy of such measures in the United Kingdom[31].

  2.   However, while it is generally correct to introduce MBIs, it does not follow that all and any MBI is justified. Much depends on the form taken by the MBI and the institutional and economic characteristics of the economic activity that is targeted by the policy initiative. Indeed, government has itself rejected MBIs in some contexts precisely because they are not always efficient when placed in the context of prevailing regulation[32]. Criticism of a particular initiative is not therefore a criticism of all MBIs. We believe that the proposed aggregates tax has a number of deficiencies. These are set out below. Our conclusions depend on particular factual issues being correct. If our assumptions can be shown to be incorrect, then our conclusions can be challenged. But we have not seen better evidence than we have assumed here.

THE AGGREGATES TAX

  3.  In order to build up our argument we focus first on the aggregates tax in isolation. We then consider its role in the overall package of tax plus negotiated agreement.

  4.  The proposed aggregates tax has its foundation in environmental economics analysis which indicates that a tax on the externalities from a given economic activity is an efficient way of reducing those externalities. The critical point of an environmental tax is that it can be avoided by undertaking changes that reduce the source of the externality. For this to be true, however, the tax must get as close as possible to the externality itself. For example, if a given product is associated with particular emissions of pollution, it is the emissions that should be taxed rather than the product. The exception to this rule occurs when there is a "one-to-one" relationship between the product and emissions. As an example, taxing vehicle fuels is a reasonable approximation of a tax on carbon dioxide for purposes of climate change policy because there is a specific relationship between fuel use and CO2 emissions. We acknowledge that it is often difficult to tax the externality directly and that real-world policy is often forced to implement less perfect ("second best") solutions. But this does not alter the fact that second best solutions can often be a very long way from a desirable solution. Hence the first point we make is that the aggregates tax is not a tax on the externalities from the use and transport of aggregates. It is a tax on the product, namely the tonnage of aggregates.

  5.  We are very aware that government economists know the second best nature of the aggregates tax. Product taxes on their own may not provide an incentive to reduce the externality. To see this, consider whether the industry, facing a per tonne tax, has any incentive to reduce the tax by reducing emissions and disamenity. It has none because changing the level of externality does not in fact reduce the tax at all. The only action that reduces the tax is to reduce the quantity of aggregates. The issue is therefore one of just how efficient or inefficient the actual proposal is. The main reason for supposing that it is inefficient is that the demand for aggregates is, on the available evidence, inelastic[33]. What this means is that the tax on the product will have a comparatively small effect on the demand for the product. Hence the overall tonnage of aggregates in the industry is not likely to fall much. But because the tax is a second-best solution, the main environmental effect of the tax works through the change in the tonnage. Hence comparatively small environmental gains would follow if the tax was implemented on its own. We have seen nothing that would alter our argument in this respect.

  6.  To make an inefficient tax more effective there are several things that can be done. The first is to differentiate the tax according to the type of product, in this case between recycled and "virgin" aggregates, and between quarries in sensitive areas and less sensitive areas. The second is to hypothecate some of the tax revenues into environmental schemes that are directed specifically at the externalities. The third is to use the tax as a threat to the industry so that it "puts its own house in order". The fourth is to retreat from a "pure tax" solution and mix the tax with other "command and control" regulations[34].

  7.  As far as we understand government policy, we believe that all these modifications are being proposed or are under consideration.

  8.  We understand the tax will not apply to recycled aggregates, only to virgin aggregates. This should have some effect on encouraging the use of recycled aggregates with a consequent reduction in quarrying. But the issue is how much substitution it would engender. ECOTEC (1999) suggests a number of reasons why this substitution effect is likely to be small[35]. The cross-price elasticity of demand appears to be small, total wastes available are a small proportion of total aggregates use, and qualities differ[36]. If the relevant elasticity is small, the tax will have little effect in encouraging substitution.

  9.  We are not clear if it is the intention to apply a different tax rate to quarries in national parks than outside national parks. Such a differentiated tax would have a justification because the externalities in national parks are very much higher than outside national parks[37]. An alternative to a differentiated tax would be to tighten planning restrictions in national parks, but if this is the intention then it is not clear why the elaborate structure of an aggregates tax is needed in the first place.

  10.  Given the precedent of the landfill tax, and the proposals for the Climate Change Levy, we would suppose that some hypothecation of aggregates tax revenues into externality-reducing schemes is also under consideration. To our knowledge, however, there has been little research that attempts to evaluate the environmental effectiveness of this particular form of hypothecation. We see no objection in principle to the idea of hypothecating revenues for environmental initiatives—indeed we can think of good reasons why it should be encouraged in principle—but it should be incumbent on those who advocate the tax to show that this is a socially efficient use of tax revenues.

  11.  The "threat" of a tax is perhaps the most powerful reason for supposing that the modified approach will work. If demand for aggregates is inelastic the effect of a tax is to transfer substantial resources from the industry to the government. To avoid this, the industry should therefore be prepared to implement its own measures to persuade government to reduce the tax. Fairly obviously, any such measure can secure its goal provided the industry has a credible programme to "beat the tax". The problem we drew attention to in our earlier report is that threats need to establish reasonable targets for the industry to beat the tax[38]. It seems to us that there is only one logical comparison: industry must do at least as well, and ideally better than the tax in reducing the externality. We have seen some of the exchanges between DETR and the QPA and we note some confusion over exactly what it is that the industry is expected to do. For example, it seems clear that, at one stage, the industry was being asked to secure externality reductions against the benchmark of the total estimated externality from the industry of some £250-300 million[39]. This is not the correct comparison. Not only should all the externality not be eliminated[40], but there can be no logical argument why industry should achieve far more than the tax would achieve. Otherwise the point of introducing the tax in the first place seems to be lost. One response might be to argue that the tax is known to be inefficient of itself but that, because it has the effect of transferring significant resources from the industry to government, it is nonetheless a powerful incentive for the industry to produce a radical programme for externality reduction. Again, for the threat to be credible, government must be prepared to introduce the tax. It seems to us to be a rather perverse threat that rests for its credibility on the introduction of an environmentally inefficient tax. Of course, if the tax can be shown to be environmentally efficient, this conclusion would not follow. But we are not convinced that the tax would be efficient.

  12.  If the aim is to mix the tax with command and control measures such as tighter land use controls, then, as noted above, it raises the question of why the tax is being introduced in the first place.

How much externality reduction should the industry achieve?

  13.  We think the only logical and fair comparison of alternatives is in terms of what each would achieve. Industry should therefore do better than the tax would have done if it was the sole instrument of policy. In our earlier report we estimated what we think the tax would achieve by calculating the reduction in demand for aggregates based on the ECOTEC estimates of demand elasticities. We did not take account of effects on the use of recycled aggregates, but, for the reasons stated above, we are not persuaded that these will be significant. We suggest that the tax would secure perhaps a 5 per cent reduction in the overall externality[41]. Our highest estimate was about 11 per cent and our lowest 2 per cent.

  14.  We conclude that industry must do better than approximately a 5 per cent reduction in the overall money value of the externality.

Can the aggregates industry achieve this target?

  15.  We do not know if the aggregates industry can achieve a target reduction in the externalities of some 5 per cent. It is for the industry to convince government that it can. But we can offer some guidelines. We can ask whether industry in general can achieve this kind of target through the introduction of various environmental measures. One problem is that there are few quantitative assessments of the achievements of environmental management schemes (EMASs). Given their extensive use we find this surprising, but one explanation may be that they are too recent to have been evaluated. We suspect, however, that another reason is that they are seen as ends in themselves, ie that once a management scheme is implemented this is seen as fulfilling the goal of environmental achievement. Since this most clearly cannot be assumed, our original report tried to focus on self-regulation and voluntary agreements (essentially the old name for negotiated agreements) where there was some quantitative information. We found that a reasonable number of such EMASs had quantitative targets and that these were often in terms of more than 5 per cent reductions in air emissions and water discharges.

  16.  The final issue, then, is whether the aggregates industry has a credible package of measures in its "New Deal" to convince government that it could secure reasonable externality reduction targets. We have not seen recent exchanges between QPA and government but earlier exchanges clearly indicated that government does not believe the industry has a sufficiently aggressive package of measures. Unfortunately, as noted above, we are not clear what the yardstick of achievement is meant to be—elimination of all the total externality (which would, in our view, be absurd) or some percentage of it, and if so what that percentage is. We cannot say if the 5 per cent target is achievable, but we can say that, as far as the limited data permit, we believe other industries are achieving that kind of target (even though those targets are not articulated as reductions in externality per se). There may be reasons for supposing the aggregates industry is "different" to other industries but, as noted above, we do not have the qualifications for making those judgements. We did survey a number of quarrying companies and we noted in our earlier report that the industry could not be classified as being in the forefront of environmental achievement. But if this is true it does indicate that it should be comparatively easy to make inroads into emissions and disamenity concerns, at least in terms of technological solutions. We did note that, on the basis of the industry proposals then before government[42] and on the basis of what we regarded as the criteria for the likely success of self-regulation, a number of further actions would be needed to make the New Deal successful. Most importantly, these included clearer quantitative targets and the design of more incentives for management and workers to comply with the self-regulation targets.

  17.  The aggregates industry proposes an "internal tax" of 10p/tonne and we understand from QPA that this continues to be one source of significant disagreement between the industry and government. If the 10p/tonne figure is meant to "mimic" the tax that government would impose, then it is clearly below the 34p/tonne average (for crushed rock) for non-national park areas, and well below the £2 per tonne for sand and gravel. The argument then is that it does not matter who imposes the tax—government or industry—since the effect should be the same. But the issue is again what is being compared with what. If we are right, and industry has to do better than the government tax would have done on its own, then the 10p internal charge may be sufficient to meet the target. It depends on the "productivity" of the internal tax and on the overall effectiveness of the "New Deal". Effectively, the government's position appears to be different to this. It appears to be saying the industry must raise as much revenue as the government's tax would raise (or somewhere near it) because the government revenues could have been hypothecated to externality reduction. Hence the internal tax revenues must be just as high because, ex hypothesi, they will be allocated to externality reduction.

Are all environmental taxes bad?

  18.  We indicated at the outset that we support government initiatives on environmental taxation and on other market-based instruments. How is it possible to express this general support whilst criticising the aggregates tax? First, general support carries with it no logical implication that a tax should be supported regardless of its context or design. Second, we are not alone among environmental economists in arguing that this particular context is not the best one for an environmental tax[43]. Third, we think there are some differences between this tax and other taxes.

  19.  To illustrate our third point above we can compare the aggregates tax with the landfill tax. Both taxes have been informed by careful studies of the externalities involved. Both are "product" based in the sense that the landfill tax is charged per tonne of waste and the aggregates tax per tonne of aggregates. Both taxes have the potential to be differentiated according to the externality. Thus, the landfill tax is differentiated between organic and inert waste and the aggregates tax could be differentiated between national parks and other sites. The landfill tax can be avoided by not sending waste to landfill at all, ie by recycling or source reduction. The aggregates tax has a similar potential incentive: by not producing aggregates or by using recycled materials, the tax is avoided. What limited evidence there is suggests that the relevant elasticities of demand are also low for landfill (perhaps lower). The difference, we think, is in the potential for self-regulation in the aggregates industry compared to self-regulation affecting the flow of waste to landfill. In aggregates the negotiated agreement is with one industry organisation, although we accept that there are quarrying corporations outside of QPA. It is less clear who the parties to a negotiated agreement on landfill waste would be. Separate agreements would be necessary for industrial landfill waste (about 45 per cent of the total going to landfill), households (17 per cent), construction and demolition (15 per cent), the commercial/retail sector (14 per cent) and the rest (about 9 per cent). In short, we see the rationale for a landfill tax despite the fact that it has some of the adverse features of the aggregates tax.

CONCLUSIONS

  20.  We are not convinced that the aggregates tax is a well designed tax, though we see the logic in some of the government's arguments so far as they have been made public. But by taxing the product rather than the externality, the government tax risks not being effective. If it exists as a threat rather than an actual tax, the threat of an ineffective tax seems to us to bring its credibility as part of government policy into some question. We accept that its effectiveness is improved by differentiating between recycled aggregates and virgin aggregates, and that revenues from the tax could be used to beneficial effect in reducing externalities. But we feel that the evidence for supposing these effects to be significant should be produced so that everyone can evaluate the argument. We are mainly concerned with determining what the "playing field" is for the tax: we remain unclear as to what the target is that the industry has to set itself. We think the only logical target is that the industry should do better than the tax. We cannot, and do not, speak for the industry but we estimate that something like a 5 per cent reduction in the externality is the relevant benchmark. Whether that benchmark is achievable is not for us to judge. We do point to the evidence, such as it is, that it has been secured by other industries which have a better record of compliance and environmental achievement. The consequent "environmental slack" in aggregates is therefore greater and environmental gains should be easier to achieve. We are not convinced that industry's "own tax" of 10p/tonne can be compared directly with the estimate of monetary externality from a tonne of aggregates once the context becomes one of "doing better" than the government tax would have done on its own. Ultimately, the issue may be one of belief about compliance, ie whether government believes industry. It is unclear to us why that cannot be tested by monitoring the progress of self-regulation in terms of setting quantitative targets for emissions and disamenity. We pointed to the need for such agreements to have clear quantified environmental targets and incentive systems in place. As far as we are aware, this has not been the setting for the negotiated agreement in the aggregates case.

December 1999


30   This evidence has been prepared by Professor David Pearce, Department of Economics, University College London and Senior Adviser to EFTEC Ltd, and Ms Tannis Hett of EFTEC Ltd. It draws on our earlier work for the Quarry Products Association-The Economic Benefits of Environmental Training and Awareness Programmes in the Aggregates Industry, QPA, 1999. The modifications reflect changes that have taken place since we wrote that report and/or clarifications about the intentions of the tax. Back

31   See D W Pearce et al, Blueprint for a Green Economy, Earthscan, London, 1989, and the subsequent volumes in that series. Back

32   For example, government has actively investigated charging systems for water pollution but has recently decided that they should not be introduced. Back

33   This is one of the assumptions that is important to our argument. We have not investigated the elasticity ourselves and the assumption that it is small is derived from work by ECOTEC, Environmental Effectiveness of a Tax on the Supply of Aggregates, Report to the QPA, 1999. We have not seen anything to suggest the elasticity is anything other than small, though we share most experts' concern that the short and long-run elasticities should have a different relationship than that elicited by ECOTEC. We are also aware that ECOTEC share that concern. But it does not follow from these concerns that the elasticities are bigger than ECOTEC's estimates. Back

34   Command and control regulations tend to focus on setting standards of behaviour or prescribing technologies that may be used or attenuating rights (eg land use planning controls). Back

35   ECOTEC, Environmental Effectiveness of a Tax on the Supply of Aggregates, Report to the QPA, 1999. Back

36   A cross price elasticity shows the effect on demand for virgin aggregates of changing the price of recycled aggregates. In this case, the price of virgin materials rises because of the tax whilst that of recycled products stays the same, so the relative price of virgin materials rises. We should be clear, however, that we have not attempted to estimate this cross price elasticity and ECOTEC's argument rests on their estimate of the "own" price elasticity being small. Back

37   The London Economics study estimates that the 633 hard rock quarries outside the national parks have externalities of £0.34 per tonne and that quarries in national parks have externalities of £10.52 per tonne. Back

38   EFTEC, The Economic Benefits of Environmental Training and Awareness Programmes in the Aggregates Industry, Report to QPA, 1999. Back

39   The sources are detailed in EFTEC, The Economic Benefits of Environmental Training and Awareness Programmes in the Aggregates Industry, Report to QPA, 1999. Back

40   This is because there is a certain amount of damage that is "optimal" in economic terms. This occurs when the costs of reducing the damage are greater than the value of the damage done. Back

41   This is £15-£32 million compared to what we estimate the total externality to be, namely £340-£470 million. Note that our estimate of the externality includes transportation externalities which were not included in the valuation study carried out by London Economics. In other words, our rough estimate is considerably higher than the London Economics externality estimate by some £50-180 million. Back

42   Our report to QPA was written in July 1999. Back

43   Ken Willis and Guy Garrod of Newcastle University have drawn a similar conclusion on the aggregates tax. See K Willis and G Garrod, Externalities from extraction of aggregates: regulation by tax or land use controls, Resources Policy, 25, 1999, pp77-86. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 3 March 2000