Select Committee on Environment, Transport and Regional Affairs Memoranda


Memorandum by Professor Iain Begg and Barry Moore Esq (UWP 41)

THE PROPOSED URBAN WHITE PAPER

INTRODUCTION

  This memorandum is a response to the request from the Committee, published as Press Notice 02/1999-2000, to comment on various matters relating to the anticipated Urban White Paper. Our comments draw on research in progress under the Cities: competitiveness and cohesion Research Programme, funded by the ESRC, under which we are carrying out a project on the economic "performance" of British cities.

  Our primary focus in this note is on the UK urban system as a whole. In reviewing urban policy, it is important to recognise that cities within this system have different histories, functions and opportunities and that their prospects are affected by what happens elsewhere in the system. The extent and nature of a city's economic and social problems reflect not only the effective and efficient functioning of the individual city as a place supporting the employment, income and quality of life of its residents, but also the city's competitiveness and role within the wider urban system. Successful cities are cities that both function well and compete effectively with other cities for private and public sector resources which are the source of jobs, income and quality of life in the city. A one-size-fits-all policy is unlikely to be either desirable or viable in addressing urban issues. Moreover, there are important national goals to bear in mind when formulating urban policy.

SUMMARY OF MAIN POINTS

  1.  The UK must be seen as an urban system in which individual cities both compete with and complement one another. As a result, policies aimed at countering urban problems have to be tailored to the circumstances of individual cities and sensitive to their potential role in the system.

  2.  Within this system, there are some cities which have consistently prospered in recent decades, while others have lost ground. The large conurbations, on the whole, continue to have the most acute problems, although London seems to have staged a recovery in the 1990s. Most New Towns have done well. Amongst smaller cites and large towns, proximity to London and an absence of traditional industry are characteristics associated with dynamism, whereas many coastal urban areas and those in traditional industrial areas—especially in the "North" have endured decline. In addition, there has been a long-term drift of both population and economic activity from cities to small towns and rural areas, although this appeared to slow in the last decade.

  3.  It is noteworthy that these patterns of economic performance have been persistent, and that there are few examples of urban areas achieving substantial turnarounds in economic performance. Urban change does not happen quickly, so that policy has to be set in a long-term framework.

  4.  Deprivation is found across the urban system and requires action everywhere, but there are aspects of "place" that are central to lasting solution. In many areas, concentrations of dereliction, dysfunctional property markets and a high incidence of social exclusion are significant sources of competitive disadvantage. Dealing with such spatial concentrations of problems must be a priority.

  5.  Many of the policies that shape the performance of urban areas and affect social cohesion in cities are outside the usual definitions of urban policy. We strongly support the proposal, set out in the Urban Task Force (UTF) report, for an Urban Policy Board to co-ordinate policies explicitly targeted at urban problems and national functional or sectoral policies in a coherent urban policy strategy.

  6.  Looking at urban policy from the perspective of the urban system has a number of implications. First, it has to be recognised that policy has simultaneously to manage problems of growth and of decline. The evolution of city economies is driven by market forces and long-term structural trends, but there are obvious problems of over-heating and environmental pressure in "favoured" southern cities just as there are problems of decline elsewhere. Second, in an urban system there is bound to be specialisation, so that not all cities can expect to attract those activities that seem most attractive. Equally, viable "clusters" can be developed in activities that are not at the leading-edge.

  7.  Taking a cue from the term "employability" that is used in employment policy, we propose a new concept: "investability". It can be thought of as a target for the various supply-side enhancements underlying the competitiveness of a city and their integration into a package of measures. This would shift the emphasis from direct steering of activity to problem areas to equipping them to attract activity when opportunities arise.

  8.  While we agree with the spirit of UTF recommendation to devolve responsibility for specifically urban policies to local government, it is important to recognise that there is often a strategic dimension to policy that also has to be accommodated. It may be that the new regional development authorities (RDAs) are the appropriate level at which to reconcile the policies implemented by different cities. In so doing, their remit should be to integrate "top-down" policies from central government and agencies such as the Learning and Skills Councils and the Small Business Service with "bottom-up" regeneration initiatives coming from individual cities.

  9.  Past urban policy has been bedevilled by two opposing trends. On the one hand, there has been a tendency to have too many poorly co-ordinated programmes—what the Audit Commission writing in 1989 memorably described as "Programme overkill within a strategic vacuum". On the other hand, policy has gone through phases where there has been an excessive reliance on measures affecting one dimension of cities, such as property or training provision, while overlooking others.

  10.  We have reservations about the Task Force recommendations concerning design quality and promotion of "information" related activities. The danger is that a new, and unduly narrow, policy focus will emerge in which other facets of urban regeneration are neglected. A solution may be to make economic development a strategic function within local authorities with direct lines to RDAs.

LONG-TERM TRENDS IN URBANISATION

  The UK is a heavily urbanised country, with a preponderance of "older" industrial cities that grew rapidly in the 19th Century. Their history inevitably affects their prospects, and the scope for policy to improve their functioning and competitive advantage. Cities cannot easily shed their historically determined institutional, economic, social and physical structures and the performance of a city in maintaining full employment and a high quality of life for its residents is crucially determined by this legacy. For example, cities in geographical locations and with institutional structures, industry and occupational mix etc which once provided competitive advantages for traditional manufacturing, are often ill-suited to a national economy increasingly dominated by modern service industries.

  Our research on the urban system in the UK strongly suggests that over periods of several decades broadly the same cohort of cities perform well in terms of net job creation, rates of unemployment and residential preference (population growth). Such cities include the majority of New Towns, other cities and towns in the immediate hinterland of London including those formerly designated as "overspill towns" and selected cities generally located close to the other major conurbations in the UK. Equally the "bottom" cohort of cities identified in the 1950s remains very much the same now. This stability in the ranking of the top and bottom cohorts raises awkward questions concerning the role of government policy in securing greater cohesion across the city system. It also exposes the limitations of market adjustment mechanisms in achieving convergence in unemployment rates and access to new job opportunities over an acceptable time period. Overall, the relatively successful cities (in terms of relative population and employment growth and unemployment) in the post-War period have been the smaller cities, typically but not exclusively located in the South.

  A feature of poorly performing cities in the past 50 years, is that they entered the post-War period with relatively high concentrations of traditional manufacturing industries compared with the more successful cities. Coastal cities and towns which in the 1950s and 1960s developed assets and services to support growing domestic tourism now struggle to compete with overseas tourism and adapt to changed competitive conditions. By contrast many of the new and growing industries are located in New Towns and cities that entered the post-War period with low concentrations of traditional manufacturing industry. Many New Towns in particular, not only offered factory and office space more suitable for modern industries, but also better quality housing, infrastructure, transport systems and other amenities, supported by institutional structures more suited to dealing with change.

  The major conurbations continue to present problems for policy makers. Although the absolute decline in employment and population has attenuated (with the exception of Merseyside) their relative decline continues. Decline per se is not necessarily a problem, particularly if the loss of jobs in the city is matched by a parallel decline in the economically active population and problems of occupational mismatch are not severe. But problems arise because of geographical concentrations of disadvantaged groups and such concentrations have always been a feature of our major cities.

WHAT MAKES A CITY MORE OR LESS COMPETITIVE?

  Making effective use of urban "assets" requires that the differences as well as the complementarities of cities in the urban system be recognised. There are gains to be achieved from exploiting the characteristics that distinguish cities and give them their identity. Specialisation is also relevant and it is worth reflecting on what it is that makes individual cities more or less competitive. Four categories of determinants of urban competitiveness can be identified. Some are mutually reinforcing, others contradictory; some characteristics may be favourable for a period, but turn sour subsequently. They are:

    —  Sectoral trends which captures the main influences on the structure of economic activity in a city and its prospects. These factors encompass the city's inheritance in terms of the mix of industries and functions and the incidence of "top-down" policy measures such as macroeconomic or structural policies which have an uneven effect on different activities.

    —  Company characteristics refers to attributes of the companies in the local area, including ownership. Are they, on average, large or small, dynamic or sluggish, financially robust or precarious? Do they have access to efficient financing or are they reliant on costly capital? An urban area with dynamic companies, selling in growing markets and with strong growth potential will tend to perform better.

    —  The business environment comprises those factors which exert a significant influence on the attractions of the locality for businesses. Many of the most telling influences on urban competitiveness concern the mix of factors that affect the input costs of employers. Some of these can shift from being favourable to adverse fairly quickly as circumstances change. Thus, if there is a good stock of desirable property which draws in investment and raises rental values, but there is negligible scope for new property development, the outcome could be to undermine the initial locational advantages. Social and environmental factors, such as the quality of residential accommodation, the crime rate, schools and so on will play a significant part in persuading investors to select a city to invest in. The availability of civic amenities can be expected to work in a similar way.

    —  Innovation and learning refers to those factors that inhibit or encourage the capacities of firms to develop new processes and products. Investment in intangible assets such as knowledge, or encouragement of the propensity of the local area to foster entrepreneurship, especially in technologically advanced areas, will be important. The hardware and software that, together, provide the tools of the computer age have, it is argued, to be complemented by brain-power or "wetware".

URBAN PROBLEMS AND CHALLENGES

  The ultimate target of public policy is the standard of living, adjusted to allow for non-pecuniary influences on the quality of life. This will encompass a range of variables and be open to subjective weighting criteria, and tensions between different objectives will arise. Higher incomes plainly raise the standard of living, but could be offset by environmental degradation or threats to personal security. Some thought consequently needs to be given to how to weight targets in order to appraise the relative merits of progress on some fronts but not others. In the same way, it is likely that progress towards one target may impede advances towards another, and such a trade-off has to be looked at with care. The economic performance of cities can be achieved in a number of ways. The most obvious and enduring is to raise productivity, enabling an economy to generate more output from a given supply of inputs. Regeneration can, however, also be attained by activating otherwise unemployed resources. This suggests that the focus of attention should be both on capacity building and on capacity utilisation.

  Historically the geographical distribution of low cost public housing and private rented accommodation has been an important factor concentrating socially and economically disadvantaged groups and impeding mobility. Sometimes the concentrations are located in the inner areas of our major cities and in others in the peripheral estates. An important question for policy is whether these concentrations matter for welfare and quality of life and if so, whether they would be better resolved by the dispersal of disadvantaged groups or by local regeneration and raising the employability of those seeking jobs.

  In assessing the new demands on policy, two emerging trends have to be accommodated. Globalisation limits the freedom of manoeuvre of individual governments at whatever level of governance, obliging them to moderate regulatory demands and tax rates. In parallel, changes in the organisation of production have seen new forms of co-operation emerge alongside more extensive competition, blurring the boundaries between bundles of assets that comprise separate firms. Clusters of firms in similar activities have been recognised as having the potential to be greater than the sum of their parts because of various spillovers, and it is arguable that the "assets" of the city complement these private assets.

  Various characteristics of different cities that have in the past worked to their advantage or disadvantage. Many of these features will have gone or moderated in their importance. However in developing a framework for urban policy, it is important to recognise that today's cities have different starting points and that these starting points will in part shape the future trajectory of the city and influence the role and effectiveness of urban policies. In other words urban policy must be both sensitive to its context and recognise that the context differs from city to city ie bottom-up. At the same time, policy must take due cognisance of the city as competing with other cities and being embedded within an evolving urban system.

URBAN POLICIES

  At its most general level, urban policy comprises all those government measures specifically aimed at increasing the economic welfare and quality of life of city residents by influencing and regulating the economic, social and physical development of cities. Other government policies, not specifically focused on cities, may also influence their development beneficially or detrimentally. Because cities differ in their structure and responsiveness to non-urban policies, urban policy requires a strategic framework that explicitly recognises the significant economic and other impacts on cities arising from non-urban policies and the potential interaction between urban policy and non-urban policies. Three broad areas for urban policy intervention can be usefully distinguished:

    —  Policies to facilitate economic adjustment and improve competitiveness.

    —  Policies to reduce social inequities and social exclusion.

    —  Enhancing the management of cities and the co-ordination between different levels of government, different functional activities of each tier of government and public and private sectors.

  These three areas are not independent and policy measures which fall under one can affect others.

  The rationale for policy intervention and the design or form that intervention takes to facilitate urban adjustment and improved competitiveness, turns critically on the theoretical framework within which urban problems are analysed. From the traditional so-called "neo-classical" perspective the focus and rationale for policy intervention is "market failure".

  "A key argument for promoting economic regeneration is that markets are not working properly. This may be because of institutional constraints that prevent markets from working freely (or adjusting quickly), or an external effect that is not properly reflected in market prices. Correcting market failures improves the supply side and increases the productive potential of the economy as a whole, either in the short term (by promoting flexibility and more rapid adjustment of the economy to external shocks) or in the longer term (by increasing productive capacity)". A Framework for the Evaluation of Regeneration projects and Programmes. HM Treasury January 1995.

  On this view, poor urban economic performance and inadequate adjustment to a changing environment arises because land, property, labour, housing and capital markets do not function as efficiently in some cities as in others, so that policy intervention is required. Policy informed by this view tends to be dominated by supply side measures designed to compensate for, or remove, market failure. What may be missing from this view is a statement of those specifically urban constraints and factors which cause market failure in cities or neighbourhoods, and an explicit treatment of dynamics. General policies to correct market failure may miss those causes of failure specifically arising from the urban location of economic activity, leaving the urban problem untouched.

  An alternative view is offered by evolutionary economics and competence theories of the firm and city. On this view the "dynamic" capabilities of firms and cities are the outcome of their ability to raise their performance by incorporating new information into their knowledge base. Instead of seeing knowledge as a freely available input, this alternative theoretical stance places great importance on investment in knowledge by firms and other organisations in the city. Policy concern with these dynamic processes has become more important with the growing importance of knowledge and learning and therefore the need for co-operation amongst firms and knowledge institutions. Existing networks in the diffusion and absorption of knowledge can, for example, form obstacles to the development of new competencies requiring openness to other "knowledge and learning systems". This points to a role for policy that extends beyond the correction of market failure. Some cities are well-equipped to compete in the new knowledge-intensive industries and thus to develop new strengths. Others will struggle and will need a concerted policy response to help them adapt.

  Relatively little attention in these theories is given to the distributional dimensions. Competitive success by one firm or city may be at the expense of other firms and cities, and within cities one social group may be more effective than another at appropriating the benefits from co-operation and growth. Much will depend on the bargaining power of the participants and on how distributional disputes are resolved. In this respect, an important role for policy is the development of institutional structures, regulatory frameworks and codes of practice to limit the exploitation of competitive advantage and strengthen social cohesion.

THE NOTION OF "INVESTABILITY"

  A key plank of the European Employment Strategy is the concept of "employability", which means equipping workers with the attributes that they will need to be competitive in the labour market. The significance of the concept is that it is "upstream" of actual employment. The essence of this philosophy is that an "employable" worker will be better placed to compete for jobs when opportunities arise.

  We suggest that a parallel notion of "investability" should be developed to capture those characteristics of cities that improve or worsen their capacity to attract investment and thus to create employment. Many past policy initiatives have been predicated on shifting economic activity from one area to another, and can therefore become a zero-sum game in which one city's gain is another's loss, often with a cost to the public purse. Sensibly applied, an investability approach would emphasise upgrading of each city's attributes so that it is better able to attract private investment of all sorts and to compete for public investment when opportunities arise. In principle, this would become a positive sum-game. What it makes sense to support will vary between cities and over time. The UTF is correct to identify design and built quality as factors in economic success, but it would be wrong to focus urban policy largely on these factors. The obstacles to competitiveness may lie elsewhere and it is also important to take account of the appropriateness of measures for the structure, or potential, of the city economy.

POLICIES TO IMPROVE THE MANAGEMENT AND CO -ORDINATION OF POLICY AFFECTING CITIES

  Key issues here relate firstly to the management and co-ordination problems that arise from the existence of different tiers of government. What should be the respective roles and responsibilities of central, regional and local government, including the many agencies which operate at each tier of government, in the formulation and delivery of urban policy? How should the development and implementation of policy take account of the urban impact of non-urban policies? With the increasing collaboration of the public and private sectors in urban policy implementation there is a third issue relating to the appropriate vehicles for managing and developing this relationship. A distinction must also be made between the formulation of an overall strategy for urban policy and the delivery of the various programmes, measures and initiatives which operationalise that strategy. This further entails separating out the different policy functions which include: funding of the policy package; formulation of programmes; and delivery. It can be argued that delivery is the function where the case for being close to policy "clients" is most persuasive, because local knowledge and identity can be expected to improve quality, whereas a greater top-down element is needed for funding and policy formulation.

  Cities differ in the nature, scale and causes of the economic and social problems they confront. An urban policy appropriate for one city is therefore unlikely to be suitable for another. Moreover, it is at the level of the city that the "city specific" problems can be most easily recognised and quantified, priorities established and detailed measures and initiatives agreed. A bottom-up approach, albeit within the context of the wider strategy for the region, is therefore desirable for efficient and effective urban policy implementation. Similarly, knowledge of local priorities can lead to better customisation of programmes or policy instruments, including experimentation with new schemes or innovative approaches.

  Strategic policy formulation is, arguably, best undertaken at the national and regional level of government in the context of the evolution of national and regional urban systems. In part, this conclusion reflects the fact that resources devoted to improving the competitive position of one group of cities will have implications for other parts of the urban system to which they are denied and the full implications of this are best considered at a national and regional level. The correct balance needs to be struck between encouraging fruitful rivalry between cities and wasteful competition. Equally, cities co-operate through specialisation and exchange of goods and services, and as components in an urban system that increasingly, transcends national borders. Co-operation is also needed in dealing with common problems such as social exclusion or environmental degradation. Co-ordination must, consequently, try to steer a (third?) way between competitive and co-operative exigencies.

  The current debate on the emerging imbalance between population growth and future housing land requirements across the urban system clearly requires a strategic view. The concentration of successful cities in the south of the country, particularly in the hinterland of London, also demonstrates the need for high-level strategy development. At the regional level there is a need for urban policy strategy to recognise the heterogeneity of its city system, the different problems faced by its cities and the need to co-ordinate these policies with other functional policies aimed at securing wider regional objectives. More generally, national and regional based strategies are important because many central government and regional based policies and actions have impacts on the city and indeed may be inconsistent with the central (and regional) governments' own urban policy objectives.

  An effective urban system ought to have benefits for the economy as a whole. The challenge for the White Paper will be to ensure that regeneration initiatives improve urban competitiveness and, by being more than a zero-sum game, contribute to improved overall economic performance.

January 2000


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 21 February 2000