Memorandum by Declan Gaffney and Dr Jean
Shaoul (FLU 06)
Questions raised by our analysis for the Minister,
London Underground and their financial advisors (the numbers in
brackets refer to the paragraph(s) in the submission):
1. Will the Minister/London Underground put the
output specification and the contract in the public domain so
that it will be clear exactly what work is to be carried out under
the PPP? (paragraph 52)
2. Will the Minister/London Underground
provide a detailed explanation of the work to be carried out with
the financial costs so that a comparison can be made with past
expenditure and investment schedules?
3. Our analysis, using estimates provided
by PwC, revealed an affordability gap of £175 million in
year two that was set to rise (paragraph 37). How will the affordability
gap be bridged? Does the government intend to provide a subsidy
of about £2.5 billion for the PPP as suggested by recent
press reports? If so, why, since giving the same amount of money
to LU without the PPP would ensure that it was spent on enhancing
the network not the financial institutions?
4. If the government does not intend to
bridge the affordability gap between the PPP and LU's cash flows,
will the Mayor have to increase fares above the rate of inflation,
something that LU has said will not happen, or divert funds from
other sources? (paragraphs 46-47)
5. Will the Minister/London Underground
put the full business case, including details of the risk assessment
in the public domain?
6. Which risks are included and excluded?
(paragraphs 49, 53 and 61)
7. What guarantees or assurances will be
given to the PPP's providers of finance? What are the implications
for the Mayor and TfL? (paragraphs 55-56)
8. There have been a number of failures
of high profile IT PFI schemes that failed to deliver, where the
public sector agencies bore significant financial costs and the
risk was in effect transferred back to the public sector. Given
this, how will the contracts protect London Underground in the
event of a failure on the part of an Infraco(s) to deliver to
specification when those for the IT projects did not protect the
public sector? (paragraphs 49-54)
9. How will performance standards be defined
for monitoring purposes? (paragraph 52) How will London Underground
be able to monitor the performance of the Infracos, a time consuming
task, if 6,000 staff, more than one third of the total workforce,
are to be transferred to the PPP?
10. In the light of the deteriorating safety
records of the privatised railway industry and London Underground,
what steps will be taken to ensure that the Underground's safety
is not jeopardised by the separation of functions and responsibilities
for the infrastructure and passenger services? How will responsibilities
be defined where the infrastructure overlaps between the three
Infracos? (paragraphs 40 and 57)
11. Given that the investment proposals
in effect do little more than prevent the tube collapsing, while
leaving several threats untouched, how does the government propose
to provide the funds for a modern, efficient Underground system?
(paragraph 32)
12. How are additional investment projects
to be awarded once the PPP is operational? What further legal
difficulties are posed by additional contracts to other contractors?
(paragraph 41)
1. We welcome the Committee's new inquiry
into the funding of London Underground (LU) in the context of
the government's proposals for a public-private partnership (PPP)
to finance LU's maintenance of the infrastructure. We would like
to take this opportunity to provide some financial analysis and
other background information to assist the Committee. The purpose
of this report is to:
show how LU has been funded over
the last 15 years, its financial performance, labour productivity,
maintenance and investment programme (paragraphs 5-19);
examine the funding of other major
metro systems in New York and Paris (paragraphs 20-25);
assess the degree to which the problems
confronting LU are in fact generic to infrastructure industries
rather than specific to and a result of LU failings (paragraphs
26-29);
evaluate the extent to which the
PPP proposals address and resolve the problems facing LU (paragraphs
30-46);
estimate the affordability and risks
of the PPP (paragraphs 47-58);
assess some of the alternatives to
the PPP (paragraphs 59-71);
draw some conclusions (paragraphs
72-76);
make recommendations about the future
organisation (paragraph 75) and funding of London Underground
(paragraph 77).
raise a number of specific questions
about the PPP that require detailed answers.
This submission is based on our report, Funding
London Underground: Financial Myths and Economic Realities.
That report was prepared for Listen to London and contains further
supporting detailed financial evidence and tables based on London
Underground's accounts and the briefing document prepared in December
1999 by Price WaterhouseCooper (PwC)[4],
London Underground's financial advisors, plus some additional
research. Our report has been publicly available since the beginning
of February 2000 and none of the financial assumptions, calculations
or conclusions have been contradicted by either LU, its financial
advisors or the government. On the contrary, all the subsequent
public discussion and announcements by government have confirmed
our analysis.
3. The problems confronting LU are widely
acknowledged and are not repeated here. They stem from a lack
of investment, and the government proposes to redress this by
a public private partnership (PPP) for London Underground. Thus
the government presents the PPP as a means of replacing government
funding and improving passenger services. The public-private partnership
proposals involve firstly, dividing LU's operations into two.
Operating the infrastructurethe network of tracks, tunnels,
stations, signals and rolling stock and so onwill henceforth
be separate from running passenger services. Secondly, the maintenance,
renewals and capital investment in the infrastructure will be
out sourced under three separate 25 to 30 year concessions to
private sector consortia after a competitive bidding process.
6,000 LU staff who currently perform these functions will transfer
to the infrastructure companies. Thirdly, the PPP is not intended
to expand the existing network. "The Infrastructure Services
[to be provided] will not include provision of new Underground
lines[5],
but to deal with the backlog in maintenance and renewal of the
infrastructure of £1.2 billion and to upgrade or replace
existing assets. Government has given no indication of how any
future expansion of the network, such as completion of the long-delayed
East-West Crossrail, is to be either financed or funded nor how
other problems, such as London's rising water table, which threatens
the Underground is to be managed. Fourthly, the rump of LU will
run the passenger services and pay an annual fee or Infrastructure
Service Charge (ISC) for the maintenance of the network to the
three infrastructure operators (Infracos). The scheme involves
no transfer of assets from LU to the Infracos. Rather, it rests
upon a complex set of contractual relationships not only between
London Underground and the infrastructure companies but also between
the three Infracos, since their use of some of the lines, signal,
stations, etc, will necessarily overlap. Each Infraco is a special
purpose vehicle or consortium of companies, which in turn will
have further contracts with the providers of finance. These proposals
will be evaluated in some detail later.
4. It is important to note that the government
justifies its policy of PFI/PPP in general and the Underground
PPP in two ways. The private sector will provide firstly, the
investment in the infrastructure that the government cannot afford,
and secondly, the private sector managerial skills that will lead
to increased efficiency, lower costs and benefits to the travelling
public. The clear implication is that inefficiency is one of the
major causes of the problems that daily confront passengers and
that as a public sector agency, LU is less efficient than the
private sector. We therefore examine LU's performance next.
5. LU's funding and financial performance
Since 1990 London Underground has been funded from two sources:
passenger fares and central government grant. Fares revenue increased
in absolute terms and as a proportion of income since 1984-5,
partly due to increased demand and partly to above-inflation fare
increases (Table 1). Travel patterns and trends are closely related
to the level of economic activity with more than half of all journeys
each day directly connected with work.
6. Rail revenues rose from £333
million in 1983 to £565 million in 1993, an increase of 70
per cent, less than the rate of inflation. As Table 1 shows, from
1984 to 1989, the number of rail passenger journeys rose by 45
per cent as Britain came out of recession. The number of journeys
fell by 1 per cent during the recession of the early 1990s. After
initially falling, rail fares per passenger km rose towards the
end of the period, from 7p per passenger km in 1989 to 9.8p in
1993, thus compensating for the decline in passenger volume. This
increase of 40 per cent was well ahead of the 23 per cent rise
in the Retail Price Index (RPI). Thus until 1990, the increase
in rail revenues was largely the result of rising demand. Between
1990 and 1993, the revenue increase was the result of fare increases.
Rail revenues rose from £642 million in 1993-94 to £1,009
million in 1998-99, an increase of nearly 60 per cent, considerably
more than the rate of inflation of 19 per cent for the same period.
By 1999, the number of passenger journeys had increased by 20
per cent and reached the highest level ever, as Britain climbed
out of recession. It was, however, also due to the increase in
fares: fares per passenger km rose from 11p per passenger km in
1994 to 15p in 1999, a 27 per cent increase.
7. Thus, the Underground is a cyclical industry
in which patterns of demand are closely tied to movements in the
economy. Demand decreases substantially during recession. The
continuous rises in LU's rail revenues both during and after the
1990s recession depended on above-inflation increases in fares.
8. Grants and subsidies have traditionally
provided a significant proportion of funding for LU and other
urban rail networks. The Greater London Council (GLC) funded 66
per cent of LU's grant through a precept on the rates. Since the
abolition of the GLC, grant has been allocated by central government.
Central government grants have been made to cover three expenditure
items: (i) revenue subsidy for passenger services; (ii) renewal
of the infrastructure, ie maintaining and replacing existing infrastructure
assets; and (iii) enhancement and expansion of the network.
9. Revenue subsidy: This ended in1994.
Since then, grants have only been made for maintaining and enhancing
the infrastructure. To put it another way, grants would only be
available for the network not for passenger services.
10. Grant for renewals: Since 1995-96
the grant for infrastructure renewals has declined from £398
million in 1994-95 to £160 million in 1998-99 (Table 2, column
1). For the last two years, the grant has not covered the cost
of maintaining the network. Thus, fares have had to rise to absorb
the full cost of running both passenger services and a significant
and increasing proportion of the cost of infrastructure maintenance.
According to the most recent estimates of government department
spending, the grant for renewals (approximately £156 million
in 1998-99) is set to disappear altogether, thereby constraining
the amount available for capital maintenance, without a further
round of cost cutting.
11. Grant for capital expenditure:
In the allocation of government grant, funding for enhancement
of the existing network is in general kept separate from funding
for major developments such as the Jubilee Line Extension, which
is ring-fenced by government. The Underground was starved of investment
until the 1990s when there was a very modest increase. However,
much of this capital expenditure went on the new Jubilee Line
Extension and other new, much needed lines rather than on the
existing lines. Table 2 (columns one and five) shows that according
to London Transport's accounts, of the £6.32 billion government
grants for capital expenditure since 1990-91, 40 per cent has
gone on the Jubilee and other new developments. While the grant
for capital expenditure on existing lines, including maintenance,
has declined from £533 million in 1990-91 to £143 million
in 1998-99 (Table 2, column 3).
12. LU has made significant reductions in
operating costs. Like any railway industry, while external purchases
of goods and services are low, a major internal cost is labour.
Labour costs rose from £246 million in 1985-86 to £581
million in 1992-93, (Table 3) and accounted for 60 to 73 per cent
of total internal costs (value added), more or less the norm for
British manufacturing industry. Employment fell from 21,598 in
1985 to 19,000, a fall of 14 per cent in 1993. Between 1993-99,
employment fell by a further 3,000 (16 per cent) to 16,000. Most
of the jobs lost were in engineering services as the number employed
fell by half from more than 6,000 in 1993 to 3,000 in 1999 (Table
3). Labour productivity, as measured by the number of passenger
km per employee, rose from 0.278 million km in 1992 to 0.423 million
km in 1999. As a result, between 1993 and 1999, labour's share
of internal resources (value added) fell to an average of 55 per
cent.
13. It is worth noting that labour's share
of value added is significantly lower than that of the former
British Rail (84 per cent in 1994). Yet British Rail had a labour
productivity that was much higher than the average labour productivity
in Europe railways and its subsidy was much lower.[6]
It is therefore likely that LU's labour productivity will also
compare well with its European counterparts.
14. Historically, the renewal of the infrastructure
was funded by government grant, which has declined in the last
period. For the last six years, renewals have been running at
about £200 million per year. For the last two years, grants
for renewing the network has been less than actual expenditure
on renewals. In 1998-99, the cost of renewals was £244 million,
considerably more than LU's grant of £108 million (Tables
4 and 2). In other words, the decline in infrastructure renewals
is directly the result of successive government policy aimed at
curbing public expenditure rather than LU's cutbacks on infrastructure
spending.
15. Investment in new or enhanced assets
during the 1980s was only slightly greater than the annual depreciation
charge, ie LU was barely replacing its worn out assets, let alone
enhancing the network. Since 1993, new asset formation has averaged
£680 million per year. However, much of this has been for
new lines, such as the Jubilee Extension rather than existing
lines. In all, for the last two years, the maintenance and investment
grants for existing lines have been less than actual expenditure,
as evidenced by the negative sign in column 6 of Table 5. In other
words, LU was funding some of the expenditure on maintenance and
investment from its own operational savings (Table 6).
16. Nevertheless, expenditure falls far
short of LU's requirements. There is a backlog of work arising
from past under-investment of about £1.2 billion. Therefore,
assets are being used beyond their design life with corresponding
increases in maintenance and inspection costs and increasing unreliability.
Expenditure of about £150 million a year for about seven
to eight years are required to remove the investment backlog with
a further £400 million a year required to maintain the system
in a "steady state" and prevent the backlog reappearing.[7]
17. The split of operational expenditure
on the infrastructure and train operations is crucial, since this
issue lies at the heart of the PPP proposals to outsource the
management of the infrastructure and rolling stock. The money
spent on the infrastructure will be used to pay the ISC. However,
unlike the former British Rail, LU provides no details of the
cost split. Prior to the privatisation of the national railways,
the infrastructure accounted for approximately 50 per cent of
revenue costs. There is no reason to suppose that LU would be
substantially different. The significance of this will be developed
in paragraph 45.
18. LU is a public sector corporation with
no interest or divided obligations or statutory requirement to
make a return on capital employed. Since it does not generate
a surplus either to distribute to external stakeholders (interest
or dividends to the providers of finance) or to pay tax, it spends
the entirety of what remains after paying for purchases and labour,
on maintenance (Table 5). More recently, any surplus after covering
the cost of renewing the infrastructure renewals has been ploughed
back into the business in the form of investment. LU would therefore
be incapable of servicing debt if grants were to be replaced by
interest bearing debt without subsidies, fare increases or increased
labour productivity. Neither would it be able to afford any extra
charges to cover the cost of the PPP.
19. This may not be readily apparent as
LU's accounts can easily be misunderstood. LU classes the revenue
remaining after paying for purchases and labourbut before
capital maintenanceas "gross operating margin".
Numerous commentators have taken this figure, positive for several
years to mean that LU makes a profit. They have further concluded
that LU would be able to meet the cost of debt service under the
PPP or a bond issue with no need for external subsidy. This is
potentially very misleading. Profit is what remains after providing
for depreciation and capital maintenance. After taking these charges
for capital maintenance into account, LU does not make, and indeed
does not report a profit. Furthermore, it is only in the last
two financial years that LU has reported positive cash flows from
operating activities.
20. We examine next the funding of metro
systems in other major cities. Contrary perhaps to expectations,
governments everywhere have provided funds for their transport
systems. This is because the capital-intensive nature of the industry
makes it impossible to recover the full cost of running a metro
system from user charges. Consequently, the funding of Paris and
New York, cities with very different political structures and
traditions, provide illustrative examples. The two organisations
concerned, corresponding to London Transport or Transport for
London (TfL), are transport authorities that cover both bus and
suburban rail.
21. Paris: The Parisian transport
authority, the Syndicat des Transports Parisiens, is funded through
a levy on employers, the "Versement de travail". It
also receives half the revenue raised from traffic and parking
fines. The proceeds of the Versement de travail are used to subsidise
fares and fund capital maintenance. Central government provides
the main source of funds for line extensions and new lines with
contributions from local and regional government. In 1998, passenger
charges contribute only 34 per cent of the costs of public transport.
The various transport companies generated 42 per cent of total
revenues. Local and regional tiers of government were the main
source of the remaining 58 per cent.
22. New York: The New York Metropolitan
Transportation Authority (MTA) is funded through a combination
of user payments and subsidies for both operating and capital
costs. In 1997, fares revenue accounted for 52 per cent of funding.
The State and the City of New York provide grants and subsidies,
which account for 46 per cent. A large proportion of the subsidy
comes from hypothecated taxation, which is in principle at least
targeted at the non-fare paying beneficiaries of the system. These
include "new charges on business and property owners, taxes
on commercial rents, business telephone charges [and] property
transfers."[8]
Because of these assured future revenues, the MTA is able to raise
finance through the revenue bonds that have attracted such attention
in the media here (paragraphs 64-65). The New York MTA receives
considerable subsidy for operating costs as well as infrastructure
costs. "In calendar year 1998, State and City operating assistance,
special tax-supported subsidies and reimbursements for the Transit
System constituted, on a cash basis, approximately 38 per cent
of the total revenues . . . not including reimbursements for capital
expenses or amounts used for debt service."[9]
23. Sophisticated arrangements exist for
spreading the burden of costs between passengers and beneficiaries
of the system and between different levels of government. In both
cities, transport companies are allowed to borrow and receive
subsidies to meet the costs of debt service. Thus in neither case
is national taxation the sole source; rather, forms of local taxation
are used to raise revenue from people who benefit from the existence
of an urban transport system. The costs of public transport are
thus spread between users, beneficiaries, regional and national
taxation in both the Paris and New York systems.
24. An important consideration here is the
highly centralised public expenditure system in the UK where most
of the taxation is raised by or under central government control.
Central government also exercises final control over the application
of funds, leaving considerably less room for the kind of distribution
of costs that takes place in Paris and New York. It should be
noted that until relatively recently the funding of the Underground
was much closer to the systems adopted in Paris and New York.
However, with the abolition of the GLC in 1984 the system of domestic
rates in 1990, control of funding for London Transport was taken
over by central government, which then reduced both the types
and level of funding. Prior to the abolition of the GLC, the proportion
of public funding was almost identical to the present arrangements
for the Paris metro.
25. The devolution plans for London will
not create the kind of structures whereby arrangements similar
to those in Paris and New York can be developed. Central government,
when setting up the GLA, as in its fiscal settlements for the
devolved assemblies in Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland, retained
control over both the level of resources available and the way
resources can be used. In particular, the Treasury restricts capital
expenditure by controlling the amount of borrowing by public authorities.
This restriction has led to PPP/PFI becoming "the only game
in town" for public bodies seek to renew their crumbling
infrastructure. Although the Mayor will have the power to levy
new taxes on road traffic, borrowing against these revenues will
remain under central government control. Consequently, the methods
used to fund the metro systems in Paris and New York are not available.
The funding of the Underground is therefore as much a political
issue concerning the relationship between central and devolved
government as it is about cost sharing and equity.
26. The essential problem for railways,
including the Underground, is that they are unable to generate
the revenues from fares that cover the full costs of and investment
in the infrastructure and train operations, ie distribution network
and passenger services. This is despite the fact that fares are
among the highest in Europe. A single adult fare of £1.50
for zone 1, the inner zone, is higher than the fare for one journey
of any length in both Paris (50p) and New York (£1). Full
cost recovery would entail fares that would choke off demand,
bring economic and social life in the capital to a standstill
and be politically unacceptable.
27. While LU has significantly increased
labour productivity, and it is difficult to increase it further
without additional investment, no amount of increased productivity
can release the resources to fund the necessary levels of investment
as the nationalised railways showed, LU has had to cover an increasing
proportion of its costs from user charges as successive governments
have scaled back the subsidies for passenger services, and cut
back on grants for maintenance and investment in the core business.
However, despite greatly increasing the contribution it makes
to infrastructure costs from fares income, LU is currently faced
with a backlog of £1.2 billion, representing infrastructure
assets (track, signalling, rolling stock etc) which are being
used beyond their design life.
28. The problem is not so much one of efficiency
but the capital intensive nature of the industry where a high
proportion of the costs is associated with providing the network,
relative to the ability to generate income. In this, the Underground
and the railways are similar to other public utilities such as
gas, electricity, telecoms and water where the main costs relate
to the distribution network. These industries, are however able
to recover their full costs because they have a very different
demand pattern. They are essentially universal providers.
29. Thus the problem is an income one. Yet
under current government expenditure plans, grants will play no
role in the future funding of the Underground with the possible
exception of new lines and extensions, meaning that all operating
and infrastructure costs will have to be met by passengers. The
Underground will then be the only metro system in Europe where
the entire cost of maintaining services is borne by passengers.
30. Under the concession agreements,
each of the three PPP companies will charge London Underground
a basic "Infrastructure Service Charge" (ISC) which
will be fixed for the first eight year period. The agreements
are to be subject to periodic reviews at roughly eight year intervals,
where the level of charges for the next period will be subject
to negotiation not regulation. Although little detail has been
made available on the intended form of the concession agreement,
it seems clear that the review process is not intended
to allow LU to end the concession agreements or to award them
to other contractors within the 25 to 30 years of the agreement.
In the event that LU and a PPP company fail to agree a level for
the ISC, a Statutory Arbiter will set the ISC. The Mayor, TfL
or LU will not be able to end any of the 30 year agreements, unless
of course a PPP operator fails to perform adequately against the
performance specifications, an issue we will return to later.
31. The ISC will depend upon the amount
of work to be carried out under the concession agreement and the
PPP's costs, including the cost of capital. The Infrastructure
Service Charge (ISC) will be set for the first eight year period
but "stepped up" when major enhancements are delivered.[10]
Thus the ISC will increase several times during the first eight
years. While as yet there is no information about the likely cost
of the ISC, we estimate this by reference to the amount of investment,
and the amount of private sector finance required after taking
into account the cash available from LU after paying for passenger
services. This information is presented in Table 7, provided by
LU's financial advisors.
32. There has been some confusion about
the amount of investment projected under the PPP. As we explained
at the outset, the plans, although not insubstantial, are for
little more than day to day maintenance, the £1.2 billion
backlog of maintenance, and some minor works to maintain the system
in steady state and prevent the backlog from reappearing. In
other words, these are not proposals that will radically transform
the Underground into a modern, efficient system but will simply
prevent the system collapsing. Government and others have
presented various figures, ranging from £7.5 billion to £15
billion as to the levels of investment projected under the PPP.
Because LU's financial advisors believe that the private sector,
despite never having run an Underground system before, can make
efficiency savings that LU cannot, they estimate the PPP companies
will spend £12.53 billion over the first 15 year period (Table
7). Of this, however, £4.15 billion consists of day to day
maintenance and other operating costs. The planned investment
is, on the most recent projections, £8.38 billion, an average
of around £560 million a year.
33. The funding available for the PPP, the
difference between LU's income (Table 7, line 1) and its costs
(Table 7, line 2), is the "operating cash flow" (Table
7, line 3). Private finance (Table 7, line 5) bridges the gap
between this available funding and the PPP's expenditure on the
infrastructure (Table 7, line 4). Since LU's advisors project
that rail receipts will rise by 40 per cent over the 15[11]
year period, most of the investment will be funded directly by
fares, leaving only £2.44 billion to be borrowed. However,
this borrowing, which is effectively substituting for government
grant, will have a significant impact on London Underground's
costs.
34. The ISC will be set so as to recover
the costs of the PPP companies. The main costs to be recovered
are those of maintenance and investment in the network (Table
7, line 4) and the costs of dividends on shareholders' capital
and debt service interest (line 6) and repayment of principal.
Repayments are not shown as PwC does not include principal repayments
for each year. PwC estimate an annual "cost of capital"
of 10 per cent. PwC's figures therefore imply an affordability
gap: the sources of funding do not match the costs of the PPP
in each year up to year 14. In other words, there is a shortfall
equivalent to the interest and dividend payments in each of the
15 years.
35. We have estimated the cost of repayment
of debt principal taking year two of the contract as representative
of the first eight years. In year two of the contract, PwC calculates
interest and dividend payments of £110 million. A 10 per
cent cost of capital implies that the capital raised by year two
is around £1.1 billion. Assuming 20 per cent of this is in
the form of equity, this leaves a gross debt of £980 million.
If this debt is paid off evenly over 15 years, then £65 million
is required in year two, in addition to interest and dividend
payments of £110 million. Thus the PPP's total costs are
£1,075 million as shown in Table 8. Of the £1,075 million,
external borrowing will provide £360 million, leaving £715
million to be raised through the infrastructure charge.
36. However, the funding stream identified
by PwC is not enough to cover the ISC. In year two for example,
PwC predict operating cash flows of £540 million and borrowings
of £360 million. This leaves an affordability gap of £175
million as Table 9 shows. Even this does not take account of the
extra costs of financing and legal fees incurred by the private
sector in undertaking the PPP and securing investment, already
estimated at £26 million by one bidder, and which they would
seek to recover through the ISC. Neither does it take account
of the requirements of the PPP companies to build up reserves.
In other words, it is likely to be an underestimate. The PPP might
be able to defer but not resolve the funding problem by the use
of sophisticated financing mechanisms.
37. In short, the PPP is not affordable
to LU on the basis of available revenues (income less costs).
By year two, there is a gap of nearly £175 million between
available revenues and the level at which the PPP charge would
have to be set to allow for debt service and returns to shareholders
at the beginning of the contract period. There is no reason to
expect that gap to diminish as the private sector takes out more
debt and seeks to recover the cost via the ISC. This gap can only
be met by increasing fares, which are already higher than in other
comparable cities, or increasing the subsidies as in the case
of the national railways. While there have been press reports[12]
that the Treasury will provide a subsidy of £2.5 billion,
there has been no explicit announcement to this effect. If this
is the case, this means that our calculations are indeed correct.
In that case, the government had either not worked carefully through
the financial implications of the PPP for LU or had hoped that
no one would notice the shortfall until after the contracts were
signed when it would become the responsibility of the Mayor and
TfL. But even more importantly from the perspective of financial
prudence, such a sum would finance the Infracos' interest and
dividend charges necessitated by the PPP, not improvements to
the Underground.
38. But these projections of future revenues
make assumptions about fare income, capacity and costs that are
not unproblematic. If we consider fare income first, the projections
assume constantly rising income from fares without any increase
in the fares level (price). In LU's projections, it is assumed
that this will be affordable because of increased revenues. However,
up until the first review period, the ISC will rise whether fares
revenue rises or not. The ISC will be the first claim on LU's
revenues, so any shortfall will be borne by LU, not by the PPP
companies.
39. The revenue generated by fares depends
on four factors: the demand for the service, the capacity of the
network, the level at which fares are set and the structure of
the fares system. The two last factors will, once the GLA takes
over TfL, no longer be within LU's control. Fare receipts are
expected to rise from £997 million in 1998-99 to £1,170
million in two years time and to keep rising every year thereafter.
LU's revenue projections for the next 15 years assume no increases
in fares more than 1 per cent above inflation after 2001-02. However,
they do assume a real increase in fares revenue of 40 per cent
due to increases in passenger traffic. The case for the financial
viability of the PPP proposals turns on this increase in revenue
from passengers.
40. Unless all this extra demand is confined
to off-peak times, these revenue projections clearly depend on
increases in network capacity. At current capacity levels, LU
has difficulty meeting existing demand at peak hours. The increase
in the number of passenger places has fallen far short of the
increase in the number of passenger journeys (Table 1), leading
to severe overcrowding. Overcrowding in turn reduces capacity
through the delays it introduces at stations (jammed doors, struggles
to get on, off). It can also contribute to injury rates. In public
transport (bus or rail), injury-producing accidents can occur
without vehicle or train collisions. Sudden or sharp breaking
and acceleration can cause accidents as passengers fall, particularly
in overcrowded trains with standing passengers. In this context
it is worth noting that serious injury rates have doubled in the
last six years (Table 10).
41. The Central London Study commissioned
in 1988 concluded that to increase capacity to meet forecast demand
in the central area, two new lines would be required.[13]
Yet the PPP proposals do not involve significant expansion of
the network. The new lines which, at least until recently, have
been regarded as essential to reducing unacceptable levels of
congestion in the central area would have to be funded separately,
and no plans to undertake this work have been announced. Furthermore,
the complexity of the legal arrangements if the contracts were
not awarded to the existing concessionaires would be enormous.
But that in turn means that the Infracos would be the preferred
candidates for any new lines of substantial investment programmes
on existing lines, with all the consequent implications for monopsonistic
bargaining power vis a vis LU/TfL, which does not appear
to have been considered.
43. How then do the PPP plans envisage dealing
not only with existing congestion but the greatly increased demand
which is so central to the scheme's viability? LU's advisors,
PwC have explained that a number of initiatives already in place,
will increase both capacity and generate the increase in passenger
receipts between 1998-99 and the start of the PPP.[14]
These include the opening of the Jubilee Line Extension, the new
rolling stock on the Northern Line and a number of measures being
taken to alleviate bottlenecks. They also believe that the planned
capital expenditure, and improved asset management, will increase
capacity by reducing journey times, time spent in stations etc.
The performance regime under which the PPP companies will operate,
it is argued, will tie their payments directly to increases in
capacity resulting from improvements of this kind. The assumption
on which the plans turn is thus that extra demand can be accommodated
by a more intensive use of the existing network.
44. These projections assume that, as with
new roads, increased capacity on the Underground will itself generate
increased ridership, thus securing the extra fares revenue needed
for the commercial viability of the scheme.[15]
There are two problems with this. The analysis of LU's rail receipts
over the last 15 years shows that the pattern of demand is closely
tied to movements in the economy (Table 1). If there is a downturn
in the economy, passenger numbers may decrease, as they did during
the last two recessions. Secondly, if passenger numbers do rise
to meet all available capacity, how will the existing overcrowding
on the network be relieved? Thus even in the most optimistic scenario,
it is unclear that the PPP can in fact ameliorate the problems
passengers presently face. Yet that was one of the justifications
for the PPP.
45. But the financial projections rest not
only upon demand and capacity but also upon costs. They assume
that costs will continue to fall relative to income. In this context
it is worth noting that costs are expected to be considerably
less at the beginning of the PPP than they were in 1998-99. This
is despite the increases in labour productivity and outsourcing
that have already occurred. LU's financial advisors explain this
in several ways.[16]
For the PPP, LU's costs refer to passenger services only, which
are necessarily lower than LU's present costs which include the
cost of the infrastructure as well as passenger services. A number
of investment initiatives are under way that will reduce costs
and wok done on the backlog of maintenance work will remove the
additional costs imposed by the poor condition of the infrastructure.
But it is unclear how removing the maintenance backlog will reduce
the cost of passenger services.
46. But if demand fails to rise sufficiently,
or the network is unable to absorb sufficient demand, or costs
cannot be further reduced, the Mayor will be faced with the choice
of increasing fares or providing subsidy. Any significant increase
in passenger farescoming on top of fare rises of more than
twice the rate of inflation in the last 10 yearswould be
deeply unpopular and politically difficultquite apart from
the risk of choking off demand. If LU is entirely dependent on
its passengers for revenues, either scenario could be disastrous.
This has implications for the financial viability of any long-term
recurrent expenditure commitments.
47. Several further questions arise. Firstly,
in the context of the transfer of responsibility for LU/LT to
the Mayor, the question arises of who will bear the cost of any
affordability gap? Will the DETR commit itself to meeting the
gap through grant over the concession period of 30 years? Oras
is surely more likelywill the Mayor and the GLA have to
choose between fare increases (for which they will be responsible
under the GLA Act) or diverting resources from other users?
48. Secondly, it is also worth considering the
position of LU, and by implication the Mayor and the GLA, if the
Infracos's performance is unsatisfactory. One of the main arguments
in favour of the PPP policy is that it allows the risk of things
going wrong to be privatised. In other words, all the claims on
LU's revenues arising from the PPP are held to be conditional
on the performance of the PPP companies. There are several inter-related
issues here: the financial implications of poor performance and
the termination of the contract.
49. We consider first poor performance.
The failed PFI Information Technology projects for the Home Office
and the Department of Social Security provide a precedent. All
PFI projects are predicated upon risk transfer to the private
sector corporations. In the event of failure, the private sector
is assumed to carry the cost of failure. Both the Passport Agency
and Social Security computer projects have gone massively over
budget and over time, yet the private sector will pay fines that
are nothing more than loose change in the context of the additional
costs to the public sector. In the case of the Passport Agency,
Siemens Business Systems will be fined £69,000 (as opposed
to the maximum £400,000 possible), whereas the costs to the
public sector are estimated at about £15 million.[17]
Additional staff will have to be taken on and the public will
have to bear the cost of higher fees for a new passport. In other
words, the risk has been transferred back to the public sector,
as the Public Accounts Committee noted. Thus while it is possible
to specify the risks to be transferred on an a priori basis,
it is an entirely different matter to transfer the risks in a
legally enforceable contract.
50. The first point to consider is that
the courts will not enforce the penalty clauses included in contracts
for failing to deliver on time, to budget or to specification.
Most commercial contracts rest instead upon the concept of "liquidated
damages". Under "liquidated damages", the contractor
is only liable for the financial losses incurred by the contracting
organisation where the organisation in turn has a contract with
the public and produces evidence of financial loss. But most public
agencies do not have such contracts with the public that enable,
at least in principle, the public to make a claim against it.
In the case of the Passport Agency, the public does not have a
statutory right to a passport and could not therefore make a claim
against the government for failure to provide a passport. In the
event, the government made ex-gratia payments to the public
for the inconvenience and these took in any event a minor second
place to the additional costs incurred by the late delivery and
operation of the computer system. Thus, neither LU nor the travelling
public will be able to seek redress from the contractors or LU
respectively.
51. It is noteworthy that in none of the
failed IT PFI projects has the government attempted to seek redress
via the courts. While this may be because the government is anxious
to get PFI contracts off the ground, it may also be because they
stand little chance of winning. While the PPP is not a PFI contract,
many of these contractual issues are the same. There is no reason
to assume that London Underground's lawyers will be any more successful
than those of government departments. In any event, recourse to
the courts consumes a huge amount of financial and human resources,
which are in short supply. Having consulted lawyers, we have found
a widespread belief that public agencies would be unable to enforce
liquidated damages clauses in practice. This is why the Treasury
has issued guidance for contracts that do not rely on "liquidated
damages".[18]
52. Instead, the government has decided
that contracts will rely on a reduction in the annual payment
for failing to deliver according to the contract. But output specifications
that depend upon quality as opposed to quantity are notoriously
difficult to determine, monitor and enforce. This was one of the
issues in relation to the failure of IT PFI projects. London Underground
has refused to make the output specification for the invitation
to tender publicly available on the grounds of "commercial
confidentiality". The failure to put that and any (future)
final contract in the public domain means that it is impossible
for the public or Parliament to scrutinise, comment or hold LU
and the PPP to account.
53. But reliance on withholding payment
by a fixed amount according to the output specification and contract
led the Passport Agency to withhold about £5 million from
Seimens. This was exceeded by the costs to the Passport Agency
of about £15 million.[19]
These costs of course leave out the cost to the public at large
then or later, any other public agencies that might suffer the
knock on effects of failure to deliver, as well as the wider political
damage, which in the case of the Passport Agency, were not inconsiderable.
It is worth noting that since the Passport Agency is required
to cover the full cost of operating its services, and the passport
departments of consular services overseas, from the travelling
public, the cost of passports has had to rise. Thus it is the
public who has borne the risk resulting from failure. All these
risks are excluded from any risk assessment, which is only required
to consider the risks to the two parties to the agreement.
54. We consider next the issue of termination.
Although logically distinct from the preceding discussion, the
same issues will apply if the amount withheld from the annual
payment were to threaten the financial viability of the Infraco.
Most of the finance to be raised will be in the form of debt,
with a minor contribution from shareholders in the PPP companies.
Debt service and returns to shareholders constitute completely
new claims on LU's revenues, and the nature of these claims needs
to be understood. PFI/PPP deals involve a three-way relationship
between the public sector, the PPP contractor and the lenders
providing debt to the contractor. The interest of the lenders
is to ensure that there is an assured stream of future revenues
to meet the cost of debt service. It is not, therefore, in their
interest to make it easy for the PPP contract to be terminated
due to poor performance by an Infraco. Under Treasury guidance,
public agencies are required to take this into account when drawing
up contracts. Thus, for example, contracts should make provision
for sufficiently generous "rectification periods" where
the Infracos have a chance to put things right rather than having
the contract terminated immediately.
55. Furthermore, if previous PFI arrangements
are anything to go on, LU/TfL will, implicitly or explicitly,
guarantee the debt even in the event that the contract is terminated
due to default on the part of the Infraco. An implicit acceptance
of liability by the public sector allows PPP companies to force
down interest rates and thus reduces the overall cost of the arrangement.
This is particularly crucial, as an Infraco is Special Purpose
Vehicle whose only activity is the LU concession, not a corporation
with multiple revenue streams. Some earlier PFI contracts have
guaranteed debt by simply including compensation clauses in the
contract specifying that debt will be repaid. The agreement for
London Underground will take a different form but will have to
achieve a similar effect: if the PPP company loses the contract,
and if the lenders fail to find another contractor to take it
on, London Underground will have to buy the contract back. While
the lenders may lose out to a certain extent under this arrangement,
they can count on LU meeting most of the cost of the outstanding
debt. There is also a commercial logic to these provisions. If
the public sector client could simply walk away from PPP debts,
there would be the possibility of "windfall" gains where
the public sector would benefit from any investment undertaken
by the PPP companies without, in effect, having to pay for them.
56. However, while this type of arrangement
may be commercially fair, it is not unreasonable to question the
fairness of the distribution of political costs it implies. Even
if the PPP failed to meet any of the performance targets set out
in the contract LU would still have to maintain debt service on
loans it has not itself taken out. In this event, the decision
on how the cost was to be handled would rest with the Mayor and
the GLA who will not, of course, be party to the negotiations
between LU and the PPP companies. Since the concession agreement
is expected to run for 25 to 30 years, the PPP will impose long
term liabilities on the Mayor and GLA.
57. Our analysis has concentrated on the
financial implications of the PPP. But little thought appears
to have been given to the consequences of fragmenting the Underground
in this way. All the evidence from the privatised rail industry
shows that the problems of planning and co-ordination have increased
while safety has decreased. The financial constraints under which
LU operates have already led to a doubling of the injury rate.
This can only increase further as the infrastructure and operations
are parcelled out to four separate entities and financial pressure
from the market.
58. In short, our analysis suggests that
the PPP is likely to be very much more costly than both PwC's
and our initial estimates. But either way, the scheme is simply
unaffordable. That in turn means that either the travelling public
and/or the taxpayers will bear the cost. All the evidence suggests
that the legal contracts will fail to protect the public sector
agencies. Several lawyers have said that the real winners in all
this will be the lawyers.
59. All the alternatives to PPP have
thus far focused on replacing government funding. The one that
has attracted public attention is the proposal that investment
could be financed through revenue bonds, which have been used
successfully in New York. Its proponents argue that this would
be cheaper than the PPP proposals, as bonds issued by a public
body would incur lower interest charges than borrowing by a private
company, and there would be no need to fund returns to shareholders.
60. We consider first the criticisms of
bond finance made by the government, LU and PwC. Firstly, they
claim that efficiencies under the PPP would easily outweigh the
higher cost of finance. This rests upon the briefing issued by
London Underground's financial advisers, PwC in December 1999,
which modelled the relative costs of the PPP and a bond financed
alternative. This document does not make the case to support the
government's argument, It assumes from the start greater inefficiency
on the part of the public sector, leading to higher costs over
the contract period and thus the need to borrow more than would
be necessary under the PPP. As the briefing assumes what it is
held to demonstratethe lower cost of the PPP optionit
provides no evidence to support the argument. Others point to
the "efficiency savings" made by other privatised industries,
particularly rail and water. But these are "own goals".
Services, however defined, have declined in the national railways,
as infrastructure investment by Railtrack has not risen commensurate
with need, expectation or commitments.[20]
The much vaunted "efficiency savings" that were assumed
to follow water privatisation came not so much from lower operating
costs but from a lower level of capital expenditure on both renewals
and investment than that predicted at privatisation.[21]
These in part at least were the result of inflated cost estimates
that provided the basis for price increases. More importantly
from the perspective of this study, while some performance targets
were set for the water companies, many of the targets were not
achieved,[22]
as the failure of the public water supply to West Yorkshire in
1995 and leakages running at a higher level than pre-privatisation
testify. Thus the "efficiency savings" were made at
the expense of consumers and the public at large. Yet proponents
of the PPP believe that private sector operators can make similar
savings in investment and maintenance expenditure.
61. Secondly the government has argued that
bond finance would risk leaving the public sector (and thus passengers
and/or the Mayor) with the bill for any cost overruns. The example
of the Jubilee Line extension, a major piece of civil engineering
whose costs are notoriously difficult to predict accurately is
frequently cited to this effect. But this is scare mongering rather
than argument, since the government is not comparing like with
like. The PPP involves numerous relatively small-scale projects
not new tunnelling and construction work. Risk can be shared between
the public sector and contractors by means of appropriate contracts,
without any need for private finance. In the PPP, the presence
of private finance militates against efficient transfer of risk
because in practice, LU cannot simply walk away from the debt
taken out by the PPP companies, whatever the cost overruns due
to incompetence or negligence, as we have seen. It also needs
to be remembered that cost overruns can occur for many different
reasons, many of which are unpredictable, such as new safety requirements,
environmental factors, including, just by way of example, London's
rising water table, and the unknown condition of many of the Underground's
assets. It is very unlikely that the PPP companies will be taking
on all such risks (and it would be prohibitively expensive if
they did). In other words, there are still plenty of reasons why
costs may still overrun under PPP, leaving the Mayor and TfL to
pick up the tab.
62. The third argument against bonds, that bond
issues would leave LU burdened with £8 to £10 billion
of debt applies equally to the PPP. To say or imply that PPP borrowing
is "investment", whereas borrowing through revenue bonds
is "debt", is pure sophistry. Under the PPP, LU will
have to underwrite and pay the PPP companies' debt service costs
as well as funding returns to shareholders through the ISC. The
difference between bond finance and the PPP is in essence little
more than whose balance sheet will show the liability for the
debtLU or the Infracos.
63. We made a direct comparison of the cost
of financing the investment through bonds on a like for like basis
with the PPP. We used the same assumptions about efficiency savings,
that LU would spend the same amount as the private sector, but
have replaced their 10 per cent private sector cost of capital
with a conservative public sector borrowing rate of 5 per cent.
The figures should not be taken as predictions of the cost of
the investment programme, any more than the models produced by
PwC should be taken as predictions of the cost of the PPP. They
are crude estimates based on the interest payments on the accumulated
debt in each year. The results of our calculations show the difference
in total costs over the 15 year period is around £1 billion,
on capital raised of £2.4 billion (Table 1). In other words,
as one might expect given the lower cost of public sector capital,
public sector borrowing costs half that of the PPP. In reality,
this underestimates the difference, as the interest rates at which
the Mayor could borrow are likely to be lower than 5 per cent.
We have not included the debt repayments to estimate total costs
but since the Underground does not make a profit on its existing
operations, bonds, like the PPP, are simply unaffordable. While
revenue bonds involve lower financing costs, in the absence of
government grants, fares would almost certainly have to increase
to meet the cost of debt service, albeit to a lesser extent than
under the PPP.
64. But bond issues have to be secured against
future revenue streams, and no such revenue stream is currently
available. Securing debt against fares alone is not a realistic
option. Debt financing does not replace public subsidy, it requires
it. The frequently cited example of New York's Metropolitan Transportation
authority provides a useful example. The revenues against which
the bonds issued by the MTA bonds are secured include both fares
and subsidies, in the form of hypothecated local taxes. Because
some of the MTA are secured against fares, there has been a misconception
that it meets the costs of its investment programme, at least
in part through fare revenue, and this has encouraged comparison
with London. However, while half of the bonds issued by the MTA
are secured against and payable out of fare revenues, fares alone
are insufficient to meet even the running costs of the Subway.
In other words, the fares against which bonds are issued are subsidised,
and without subsidy, fares would have to rise to meet the costs
of debt service.
65. Without an assured stream of public
funding to supplement fares revenue, the Underground is in no
position to take on the financing costs of an investment programme.
This is all the more true for the more expensive PPP option that
is equally dependent on finance. The New York example demonstrates,
and herein lies its significance, the importance of public funding,
rather than the advantages of bond issues.
66. Under the GLA Act, revenues from proposed
congestion and workplace parking taxes would be earmarked for
public transport. To the extent that these provide a predictable
stream of future revenues their benefit could be maximised by
borrowing against them. Bond issues on a similar model to New
York might then be possible.
67. However three aspects of such taxes
need to be borne in mind: firstly, their successful implementation
requires increased capacity on public transport, which means that
capacity would have to increase before the revenues from the taxes
began to come in. In other words, there would still be a problem
in funding investment in the early years of such a scheme. Secondly,
such charges would be politically unpopular particularly when
it becomes clear that the revenues will be used to fund returns
to the financial institutions not improvements to the Underground.
Thirdly, it should not be assumed that the aim of reducing motor
traffic dovetails neatly with that of bringing in revenue for
public transport. The more successful road taxes are in reducing
traffic, the less they may bring in if people walk, cycle, work
from home via the Internet, or relocate. Moreover, if the revenues
from road taxes become the main source of funding for transport
other than fares, other measures for reducing traffic, which do
not yield revenue such as pedestrianisation, reduced speed limits,
and bans on traffic during certain hours, may come to be unfairly
neglected.
68. Furthermore, while revenue raising via
bonds seems to offer of allowing the Mayor a certain independence
from the Treasury in making investment decisions, no function
is more jealously guarded by the Treasury than the power to borrow.
Neither the GLA nor TfL will be able to borrow to finance investment
without approval by central government. GLA and its functional
bodies (which include TfL) will be subject to the local government
financial regime and will therefore require credit approvals from
the Secretary of State for the Environment, Transport and the
Regions before undertaking any borrowing.
69. Borrowing will therefore be limited
to the credit approvals set by the Secretary of State. The possibility
of extending those approvals by finding a formula under which
the borrowing would not count towards the Public Sector Borrowing
Requirement or the General Government Financial Deficit may appear
attractive. However, the frequently cited example of the Channel
Tunnel Rail Link, where the government argued that its guarantee
of a loan should not count towards the PSBR because of the limited
risk of the guarantee being called in, is not applicable because
the government was guaranteeing a loan on the part of the private
sector. No such arrangement is possible with TfL because TfL will
itself be a local authority and therefore part of the general
government sector. As such its borrowing will count towards any
measure of government debt (PSBR and GGFD) whether guaranteed
by central government or not.
70. It is of course possible for government
to make an exception to its own accounting rules in order to allow
LU to undertake borrowing without affecting the PSBR/GGFD. This
has already been done for investment in local authority owned
airports. However, this option is only available to central government,
not the GLA. Thus while revenue bonds might allow the future Mayor
of London to divert new forms of taxation to the financial institutions
via subsidies to London Underground, this will only be possible
if central government agrees to relax its control over the finances
of devolved administrations. As in the financial settlement for
the devolved assemblies in Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland,
the nominally extensive powers of the mayor are restricted by
the existing public expenditure control system.
71. While our analysis therefore refutes
three of the criticisms raised against bonds, it does show that
a bond issue does not provide an affordable, sound or political
alternative. Indeed, the apparent popularity of the bond proposal
owes more to the unpopularity of the PPP and the refusal of the
Treasury to fund the much needed investment in the Underground
despite running a fiscal surplus, than any merits of bonds per
se.
72. To conclude, London Underground is a
high fixed cost industry where a high proportion of the Underground's
costs are associated with providing the rail network as distinct
from running the trains. Like the former public utilities (gas,
electricity, telecoms and water) its main costs and much of the
investment relate to the distribution network. In effect, all
these industries operate two businesses, the distribution network
and the supply of services. Because of the high cost of maintaining
the network, the supply side of the utilities is more profitable
than the distribution as the gas, electricity and telecoms industries
demonstrate.
73. However the utilities differ on the
demand side. They supply an (almost) universal, essential and
unavoidable service in ways that are reasonably predictable. It
is therefore possible to devise methods of payment (monthly direct
debit, pre-payment cards, social security allowances, etc) that
spread the burden over time and do not require consumers to pay
up at the point of use. Thus, both their pattern of demand and
method of payments allow full cost recovery from consumers.
74. In contrast, while many people do use
rail services, not all do, or do so very infrequently. Furthermore,
pre-payments, season tickets and other payment devices that spread
the cost of user charges through time are not as well developed
in the rail industry. As a result, many people pay at the point
of use. LU also faces competition from other forms of transport.
In the absence of adequate demand, full cost pricing may be self-defeating
in that it chokes off demand, quite apart from the implications
for equity. Thus the essential problem for the Underground is
that it is unable to generate the revenues that cover the cost
of the network and the train operations, even without the requirement
to provide a return on capital employed. Operating costs and the
(inadequate) annual capital spending on the Underground network
exceed total revenue, and the Underground currently depends on
annual grants to make up the difference. The use of public grants
to support rail networks and operations in this way is, as we
have shown, the norm not the exception in industrialised countries.
75. Government-instituted funding, commercial
and charging policies have prevented the former state-owned railways
and London Underground from developing an appropriate cost structure
that could be used to apportion costs and set prices. Given that
rail is essentially two businesses, the network and passenger
services, which combined are unable to make a profit or break-even,
the solution is to set prices to cover only passenger services.
Public funding, paid for from taxation, would cover the cost of
maintaining and enhancing the network which would be free at the
point of use to the travelling public in the same way as roads.
The fact that road infrastructure is free is, of course, why road
haulage and commercial bus and coach services are able to run
at a profit. While this would not be any cheaper, it would mean
that the Underground would be the beneficiary not the financial
institutions as in the case of the PPP or bond finance. It would
lead to lower fares, passenger traffic and receipts, a more rational
service, greater accountability, and train operations that at
least broke even, with all the associated environmental and social
benefits. This pattern is adopted in five Western European countries,
where the state owned railways are funded as two distinct entities.
76. While the PPP proposals in effect split
the Underground into its two constituent parts, the network and
passenger services, it does so in completely the opposite way.
Instead of providing a network at a lower (or no) cost that will
enable the Underground to operate efficient passenger services,
the PPP will raise the infrastructure costs and hence the cost
of passenger services, and exacerbate the existing problems.
77. Our recommendation for the development
of a modern, safe and efficient Underground is that expenditure
on the enhancement of existing lines and the construction of new
ones is significantly increased beyond that proposed for the PPP.
As the Acheson Report on health inequalities showed, public transport
is an economic, social, environmental and public health issue
that affects the lives not simply of those who use the services
but of those who do not[23].
The most economic and socially efficient way of running the Underground
is to retain its integrated structure while at the same time providing
the required level of funds. These are conditions that the proposals
for the PPP and bond finance will not and cannot satisfy. The
basic economic realities of this industry, both in Britain and
overseas, show that these conditions can only be met by funding
the full cost of the infrastructure through taxation, which may
be local, national, or a mixture of both, without charge to London
Underground.
Declan Gaffney,
School of Public Policy, University College London.
Dr Jean Shaoul,
School of Accounting and Finance, Manchester University
4 PwC, "London Underground", a briefing
report, 6 December 1999. Back
5
Public Private Partnership for London Underground, briefing for
bidders. Back
6
Shaoul J, "Railpolitik: A Stakeholder Analysis of the Railways
in Britain", Manchester University, paper presented at the
CIMA Public Sector Accounting Workshop, University of Edinburgh,
September 1999. Back
7
House of Commons, Transport Committee Seventh Report: London
Underground, Vol 1, p viii. Back
8
Robert A Gerard "New York can teach us a lot about our Tube",
London Evening Standard, 25 November 1999. Back
9
Metropolitan Transportation Authority, Combines Disclosure
Fillings 1999. Back
10
PwC, Briefing Note, December 1999. Back
11
PwC Briefing Note, December 1999. Back
12
See for example the Guardian 13 March 2000 "Taxpayers
to bail out tube". Back
13
As cited in MMC, London Underground Ltd, a report on passenger
and other services supplied by the company, HMSO, 1991, p 120. Back
14
PwC, personal communication. Back
15
PwC, personal communication. Back
16
PwC, personal communication. Back
17
National Audit Office, "The United Kingdom Passport Agency:
the passport delays of summer 1999", report by the Comptroller
and Auditor General, HC 812 27 October 1999. Back
18
Treasury Taskforce Private Finance. Standardisation of PFI contracts,
July 1999. Back
19
National Audit Office, "The United Kingdom Passport Agency:
the passport delays of summer 1999", report by the Comptroller
and Auditor General, HC 812 27 October 1999. Back
20
Booz, Allen and Hamilton, "Railtrack's Performance in the
Period 1995-2001", report to the Office of Rail Regulator,
1999. Back
21
J Shaoul, "A Critical Financial Analysis of the post-Privatisation
Performance of the Water Industry in England and Wales",
Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 1997, Vol 8, pp 479-505. Back
22
Schofield R and Shaoul J, "Regulating the Water Industry:
By Any Standards?" Utilities Law Review, Vol 8, Issue 2,
March to April 1997, pp 56-70. Back
23
Sir Donald Acheson, "Independent Inquiry into Inequalities
in Health", The Stationery Office, November 1998. Back
|