Select Committee on Environment, Transport and Regional Affairs Appendices to the Minutes of Evidence


Annex

TIME FOR THE RDAs TO GET STUCK IN

  1.  The EC has put an end to gap-funding with its ruling on PIP (Partnership Investment Programme). Government is having to curtail grants to the private sector dramatically—down to state aid limits (20 per cent in development areas) and is now looking at other ways of getting development underway in areas where it is needed but does not stack up.

  2.  The whole thing has been handled abysmally. Government is pussy-footing round Brussels when the solutions are staring it in the face. It even says grants cannot necessarily be given to not-for profit organisations. But national governments throughout Europe support cultural and heritage projects. Do we stop handing out lottery funds? This is really silly. And when DETR does eventually decide what it wants, the EC bureaucracy will take years to grind through negotiations and the approval process. Meanwhile regeneration will be stopped dead—unless someone takes a lead.

  3.  Step forward the RDAs. They have a real opportunity to do something at last. Up to now they have done little more than produce wishy-washy motherhood and apple pie strategies that amount to little more than a Utopian wish list. They can take now the lead in helping secure the economic and physical regeneration of their distressed areas and derelict sites—rather than just talking about it.

  4.  In some ways a move away from gap-funding could be a good thing. The eighties laissez-faire approach was never the success it was cracked up to be. As far as employment space was concerned, gap-funding failed to deliver on any scale. The private sector was put off by an appraisal process that was inevitably time-consuming and bureaucratic. Some applicants secured offers of grant based on spec development and treated them like options—to be implemented very profitably when they secured a pre-let.

  5.  The laissez-faire experiment of the 80s, when major developers such as BUD tried to undertake mega schemes, often "in partnership" with local authorities, is largely discredited. They found them too difficult and quite simply were not prepared to take the risks required. At the first whiff of the recession, such companies did a hasty retreat back down the M1 and thence down the tubes. Those that stayed simply did nothing—regarding the partnership as little more than a free option to be exercised as and when the market picked up.

  6.  Developers are impatient and risk averse—that's why they like green field sites. They want clean opportunities on which they can make an early start. Rather than hand out grants willy-nilly, RDAs, local authorities and other development agencies can target resources on selected public sector owned sites and either develop themselves or market them competitively for private sector development. This allows them to put money into development without falling foul of Europe—and does away with the unloved appraisal process.

  7.  But to do this they need to secure sites into public ownership. Many authorities are sitting on large tracts of suitable land, but in the main any major development programme would involve the public sector acquiring land from the private sector—if need be using compulsory purchase.

  8.  RDAs must not be squeamish about using CPOs for site assembly. And government must stop consulting the world and his wife and do something about the crazy compulsory acquisition procedures, which take forever and are open to all sorts of abuse by difficult landowners and indeed anyone who wants to put a spanner in the works. In the meantime it is worth RDAs and local authorities using EP and its CPO powers which are akin to those of the former UDCs. EP can acquire for regeneration purposes without the need for a specific scheme and developer and with a lesser burden of proof on funding and viability.

  9.  With standard, simple products like sheds it is axiomatic that the only way of the public sector getting what it wants, where it wants, when it wants, is to build it itself. And it will probably get it cheaper, because it cuts out developer's profit. There is no need for it to hold it forever. Once it's up and let, it can just turn the investment and re-invest the proceeds. Up to now, this inescapable logic is not something government wants to hear. Yet direct development worked well for years with the hugely successful advance factory programmes of English Estates and the Welsh and Scottish development agencies.

  10.  Such an approach won't work with less standard products—housing, leisure, retail, and to some extent offices. The answer here is for the public sector to assemble sites (using CPOs if needs be); undertake reclamation; put in infrastructure and landscaping, and sell off attractive, manageable-sized, serviced plots to the private sector under tight development agreements.

  11.  If the agencies really do not want to get their hands dirty, they can market public sector owned sites competitively for a specified scheme with an offer of grant. All things being equal, the developer who put forward the lowest grant requirement (or best offer for the site) would win the day. He would be given a licence to develop the site with grant payable on satisfactory completion of the scheme.

  12.  As a complementary measure, RDAs might be give responsibility for allocating tax allowances. The agencies have lobbied government to bring such incentives back on selected schemes in particularly difficult areas and there is the possibility that they might get an airing in the Urban White Paper.

  13.  Enterprise Zones (EZs) have been hugely successful—if only in terms of generating development—perhaps too successful. They have brought a whole new class of investor to some of our most deprived areas. Investors' greed—and perhaps stupidity—know no bounds when they see the words "tax free". And from the developers' viewpoint, tax allowances are automatic—they obviate the problem of a lengthy and off-putting grant appraisal process.

  14.  However, the EZ is a blunt policy instrument. Rate relief has been unnecessarily generous. Tax allowances have gone to schemes that do not really need them. The EZ needs fine-tuning. It needs limiting to schemes developed under building agreements and to public sector-owned sites. Such restrictions would eliminate land speculation and ensure that any "surplus" tax allowances were clawed back by the public sector in the form of enhanced land values.

  15.  To fulfil any new, wider and more interventionist remit, RDAs need cash, clout and people in top positions who understand property.

  16.  Come what may, they will have to take a more pro-active role and brush up on their property development skills. Many, if not most, local authorities do not have the necessary hands on skills to implement major regeneration schemes. In fact broadly-based regenerationists are pretty thin on the ground—the RDAs will therefore need to become a centre of excellence and expertise on which local authorities can draw.

  17.  Whitehall RDAs given them a pittance. Although in theory they have a budget of nearly £1 billion between them, most of this is already committed to on-going SRB programmes. The amount of money they have at their disposal is minimal—and much of it is taken up in running their administration.

  18.  Most of the agencies' top people wouldn't recognise a house brick if it hit them on the head. The people in charge know about training and competitiveness but simply do not understand property—an equally important element in any economic development strategy. They need to listen more to what their property people have to say.

  19.  The loss of PIP will only be a disaster if government chooses to turn it into one. It has the Regional Development Agencies to hand which could and should take a more hands on approach to development and mitigate the effects of the loss of gap-funding.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 14 September 2000