Select Committee on European Scrutiny Twenty-Fourth Report


COMMON ORGANISATION OF THE MARKET IN RICE


(21358)
9439/00
COM(00) 278

Draft Council Regulation on the common organisation of the market in
rice.

Draft Council Regulation amending Regulation (EC) No. 1251/99
establishing a support system for producers of certain arable crops, in
order to include rice.


Legal base: Articles 36 and 37 EC; consultation; qualified majority
voting
Document originated: 7 June 2000
Forwarded to the Council: 13 June 2000
Deposited in Parliament: 27 June 2000
Department: Agriculture, Fisheries and Food
Basis of consideration: EM of 4 July 2000
Previous Committee Report: None
To be discussed in Council: 24-25 September 2000
Committee's assessment: Politically important
Committee's decision: Not cleared; further information requested

Background

  7.1  The common organisation of the market in rice contains many of the features associated with the various régimes under the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP), notably provision for public intervention, import levies, and export refunds. In recent years, however, two main changes have been made. First, by analogy with the reforms made in 1992 in other arable areas, the intervention system was weakened (by reducing both the support price, and the period in the year in which intervention is available): in return, producers became eligible for direct area payments (though, as with flax and hemp, these have hitherto fallen outside the main Arable Area Payments Scheme (AAPS)). Secondly, following the GATT Uruguay Round negotiations, the system previously in force (under which import levies varied according to the difference between the Community threshold price and world prices) was replaced by a series of fixed tariffs. (In common with other agricultural commodities, these tariffs, and the level of export refunds, were also reduced by 36% over the period 1995-2000.) Other aspects of the import régime include a ceiling on the price of imported rice linked to the level of the Community intervention price (see paragraph 7.5 below), and preferential access for up to 160,000 tonnes of husked rice from the ACP/OCT countries.

  7.2  Despite these changes, the Commission says that the market is not in balance, with prices well below intervention price levels, and stocks in intervention now equivalent to 20% of annual production. Moreover, the Commission estimates that, as things stand, these stocks are likely to increase each year by about an amount equal to 10-15% of production. It has, therefore, concluded that a "rapid solution" must be found, and has sought to achieve this by proposing in this document a number of amendments to the common market régime.

The current proposal

  7.3  In setting out the detailed case for reform, the Commission recalls that there are basically two types of rice covered by the present arrangements. Japonica, which is round and medium grain, has traditionally been produced within the Community and consumed in the Member States concerned (Italy, Spain, Greece, France and Portugal). Indica rice, on the other hand, is long grain, imported from the United States, ACP/OCT countries, Thailand, India and Pakistan, and accounts for the major part of consumption in Northern Member States. The Commission points out that the Community has previously attempted to reduce the surplus of Japonica rice by encouraging the growing of Indica. As a result, Community production of Indica in 1999-2000 is likely to be more than twice that five years ago. However, production of Japonica has remained close to previous levels, and this, together with increased imports and a ceiling on exports following the changes made in the Uruguay Round, has led to an accumulation of intervention stocks since 1996-97. These now total some 400,000 tonnes, with market prices over the last three years having been well below the intervention price.

  7.4  The Commission has accordingly proposed a number of changes to the rice régime. The most significant of these so far as the internal support arrangements are concerned would be:

  • the abolition of the intervention system, and the provision instead of a legal basis for private storage, in order to overcome any market disturbances;

  • the inclusion of rice as an eligible crop under the AAPS, together with an increase in the area payment from 52.65 euro per tonne (£32.78 per tonne) to 63 euro per tonne (£39.22 per tonne), the rate agreed for cereals under the Agenda 2000 reforms; the other main consequences of the inclusion of rice in the AAPS would be the application of the base area restrictions applicable to other eligible arable crops, and of compulsory set-aside.

  7.5  The abolition of intervention would also have major implications for the import arrangements for rice. Notwithstanding the fixed levy introduced after the Uruguay Round, there are in practice ceiling prices for imported husked rice equal to 188% and 180% of the intervention price in the case of Japonica and Indica rice respectively. In addition, Basmati rice (aromatic Indica rice from India and Pakistan) has been granted a special duty abatement of 250 euro (£158) per tonne, in recognition of its higher price. The Commission points out that, with the abolition of the intervention price, the full fixed tariff should in principle be applied to all rice imports now entering the Community under the ceiling system, thus increasing duties from around 200 euro (£126) per tonne to 264 euro (£167) per tonne. The abatement for Basmati rice would also disappear, though the preferential arrangements for ACP/OCT countries would not be affected. The Commission suggests that these changes would greatly simplify the import duty system, making it more transparent, and thus likely to lead to a more stable international trading environment. However, although it believes that the special type and consumer preference for products such as Basmati rice makes it unlikely that imported quantities would diminish, it says there will be an impact on the trade in other varieties. The Commission therefore says that it is ready to find a negotiated solution with supplying countries, which takes account of the Community's obligations.

  7.6  The Commission's introduction to this proposal also refers to the need to respect the environment and the "multifunctionality" of agriculture by ensuring the continued growing of rice in areas where careful water management is important for the maintenance of specific environmental characteristics. With this in mind, it says that it will be requesting Member States to submit by 31 December 2003 a special report on the impact of the measures proposed, as well as any national measures taken.

The Government's view

  

  7.7  In her Explanatory Memorandum of 4 July 2000, the Minister of State at the Ministry of Agriculture, Fisheries and Food (The Rt. Hon. Joyce Quin) says that the proposals to abolish intervention and to integrate rice into the AAPS are in line with the Agenda 2000 approach of moving away from market price support towards helping farmers via direct payments. She points out that there is no commercial rice cultivation in the UK, but that, if abolition of intervention were to lead to the disappearance of the current duty ceilings and hence to higher import duties, this would have an adverse impact on the competitiveness of the UK rice milling sector (where she says there is a significant economic interest), and on consumer costs and choice. She goes on to suggest that this would almost certainly be challenged by supplying countries, and that the Commission will, therefore, need to pursue negotiations with them as early as possible to avoid a potential dispute within the World Trade Organisation (WTO). The Minister also points to the particular difficulties which would arise in the case of basmati rice, where she says the ending of the current duty abatement would lead to a substantial rise in the price of a product largely consumed by ethnic communities in the UK, which is the main importer of basmati.

  7.8  The Minister says that consultations are being held with interested parties, including consumers, ethnic groups, and millers and traders, and that a Regulatory Impact Assessment will be supplied in due course. In the meantime, she points out that the Commission estimates its proposals would save 16 million euro (£10 million) in 2002, rising to 38 million euro (£24 million) in 2006, with net savings to the UK in these two years of £0.5 million and £1.2 million respectively. According to the Commission, there would also be an increase in budgetary revenue through own resources (duties) of 36.6 million euro (£22.8 million) by the year 2002.

Conclusion

  7.9  As the Minister points out, the abolition of intervention in this sector would be a welcome step, both in principle and (given the prospect that the already high level of stocks would otherwise increase in the years to come) in practice as well. Likewise, the incorporation of direct aid payments for rice producers into the Arable Area Payments Scheme makes sense, though it seems to us that this could possibly give rise to one point of potential concern. Since there is no commercial rice production in the UK, cereal producers in this country would clearly not be directly affected by this change. On the other hand, depending on the relationship between production and base areas in the mainly southern European producer Member States, the incorporation of rice into the AAPS might, in theory at least, have a bearing on the aid payable to cereal growers in those countries, and hence on their relative competitive position vis-à-vis those in the UK. We would like to know if the Government considers whether this is likely to happen in practice.

  7.10  Notwithstanding this point, it seems evident that the main implication of the proposals would arise from the abolition of the intervention and hence the duty ceilings as currently calculated. The Minister has also made it clear that this could adversely affect both the rice milling sector and consumers in this country, particularly as regards basmati rice. However, this situation arises only because the present duty ceiling is defined somewhat arbitrarily in terms of the intervention price of rice, and, if the Community wished to do so, there seems no reason why some alternative basis for setting a ceiling could not be found. In short, it seems to us that the disappearance of the ceiling need be by no means as foregone a conclusion as the Commission suggests. Again we would welcome the Government's comments, and, given the concerns expressed by the Minister about the effect of the current proposal on millers and consumers, we would like to know if the UK intends in the negotiations in Brussels to press for the retention of some kind of ceiling.

  7.11  In addition to the Government's comments on theses two points, we also await with interest information about the outcome of its consultation exercise and the Regulatory Impact Assessment which the Minister has promised. In the meantime, we are not clearing the document.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 24 July 2000