Select Committee on International Development Appendices to the Minutes of Evidence


APPENDIX 3

Second supplementary memorandum submitted by the Bretton Woods Project

  The information contained in this briefing is based on meetings and conversations with staff at the IMF and a range of Executive Directors during the Spring and Annual Meetings and from recent reports published by the IMF and World Bank.

THE POVERTY REDUCTION AND GROWTH FACILITY—CAN ESAF CHANGE ITS SPOTS?

  It was announced at the IMF annual meetings in September that the Enhanced Structural Adjustment Facility (ESAF) is to be replaced with the Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility (PRGF). This change in name signals a change in approach. At the heart of the new approach is the commitment to poverty reduction. While the IMF will remain focused on macroeconomic concerns it will be required to consider the distributional consequences of its policy advice and advocate stabilisation and growth strategies that benefit the poorest.

  Other elements include:

    —  a focus on country ownership, ie participation of parliament, civil society, and the private sector in developing national poverty reduction plans;

    —  coordination with the World Bank to ensure coherence between macroeconomic, social and structural reforms.

  The tool for implementing this new approach is the Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper (PRSP) which will be a tripartite document jointly produced by the government, the IMF and the Bank. The PRSP replaces the IMF's Policy Framework Paper which was supposed to be a joint Bank-Fund document but which in effect never was. The government in consultation with civil society and with advice from the Bank and IMF will produce a PRSP which must be endorsed by the Boards of the Bank and the Fund. Based on this document the IMF will draw up a Letter of Intent and the Bank a Country Assistance Strategy.

  While this new approach offers a positive step forward there remains concern about how and whether it will be effectively implemented.

1.  The Link to Debt Reduction Could Put Pressure on Governments to Develop Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers Too Quickly

  The PRSP is linked to the HIPC debt initiative. It is anticipated that as many as 19 countries will reach decision point in 1999-2000. To reach decision point they must produce a PRSP; and to reach completion point they must implement several elements of it. While it is vital that countries receive debt reduction as soon as possible linking it to implementation of the PRSP could force them to be produced too quickly: limiting the opportunity for effective broad-based consultation and input into the process and giving the IMF grounds to carry on with business as usual.

  This problem has been noted by Clare Short and Gordon Brown in their communique to the WB-IMF Development Committee, "Good Poverty Reduction Strategies will, of course, take time to draw up. It would be wrong to rush the process, or make it a condition that such a Strategy is in place by the Decision Point. It should be sufficient that there be a clear process by which an agreed Strategy will be achieved by the Completion Point, and that the country has implemented two or three key benchmarks."

Suggested Questions

    —  What steps is the Executive Director taking to ensure that countries are not put under undue pressure to develop and implement a PRSP which would limit the involvement of civil society?

    —  Can the Executive Director give examples of what the "benchmarks" demonstrating adequate implementation of the PRSP might be?

2.  The Tripartite Nature of the Document Implies Equal Involvement of the IMF and Bank in the Government's Strategy—This May Not Lead to a Sense of Ownership

  A more useful approach maybe to require the government to develop a national strategy in consultation with civil society and the private sector. Once this is complete the IMF and Bank could then develop—in consultation with the government—a joint funding strategy (still called the PRSP) based on the truly nationally owned document.

Suggested Questions

    —  What steps is the Executive Board taking to ensure that governments lead the process of developing national poverty reduction plans?

    —  Does the Executive Director agree that the PRSP should be made available for comment in the country (beyond the government) before it is sent to the Board for approval?

3.  There Should be no Blueprints for the PRSP but Should the IMF Judge What is a Good Strategy for Poverty Reduction and can it be Flexible about the Means of Achieving it?

  A PRSP is not necessarily likely to look like a standard IMF programme (a) because it is focused on poverty reduction; and (b) because it should be written by the government not IMF staff. Because each country's circumstances are different each should be expected to have quite different strategies. This will require the Executive Board be flexible about what it considers to be a good programme to fund. If Executive Directors are not careful to give the right signals demonstrating this flexibility (to IMF staff and borrower governments), it may be the case that governments put together programmes which they know the IMF and Board will accept in order to access the IMF's money even if they themselves do not fully agree with the strategy laid down. Such a situation is likely to lead to continued problems with implementation and is unlikely to address poverty eradication (a recent World Bank review of the status of poverty found that in Sub-Saharan Africa—where many countries have been implementing the standard IMF prescription for many years—poverty is increasing not falling).

  At the moment the signals given by IMF staff are that the core elements of the economic strategy are not up for negotiation. As far as they are concerned, these elements (single digit rates of inflation, low budget deficits, minimal government involvement) are totally accepted by the economic community and only "economic luddites" (which presumably includes the World Bank's Chief Economist, Joseph Stiglitz) would challenge this. Furthermore, a recent staff review of efforts to implement the recommendations from the External Evaluation of ESAF overlooked the recommendation that, to encourage greater ownership, flexibility should be built into programmes by allowing governments to choose from a menu of options for achieving programme objectives: suggesting that staff are unwilling to loosen their grip on programme design.

Suggested Questions

    —  How will the Executive Board ensure that flexibility in programme design is encouraged?

    —  By what criteria will the Board judge whether a programme should be funded if it does not adhere to the standard IMF prescription?

GOVERNANCE AND TRANSPARENCY: THE IMF MUST PUT ITS OWN HOUSE IN ORDER

  The Fund is increasingly talking about governance in the countries which it lends to yet it has done little to ensure it is fairly governed and transparent. While the fund has taken some useful steps to improve its transparency by releasing some documents it should go further, and other elements such as voting and evaluation procedures and devleoping country representation on the IMF Board need to be improved if the institution is to be responsive and accountable to national democracies.

1.  Developing Countries Should be Better Represented in the Decision Making Processes

  There are only 24 Executive Directors (EDs) on the IMF Board, consequently only a selected few countries (those that provide the most funds) are represented by their own ED. Other countries are grouped into constituencies and jointly represented by an ED. This means that whilst the UK is represented by its own executive director, 43 Sub-Saharan African countries are represented by only two EDs. Moreover, these countries only hold a 4.76 per cent of the total votes on the IMF Board (less than the number held by the UK), thus not only are they under-represented in the IMF's decision making bodies they also have insignficiant voting power. Furthermore, out of a total of 87 countries which have contributed money to replenish ESAF (now known as the Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility), 64 are developing and transition countries. Whilst these countries are contributing to the financing facilities which other developing countries are borrowing from, they effectively have no means of directing how that money is used and for what priorities.

  The IMF's quota formula (which determines how much countries contribute to the IMF and therefore what voting rights and representation on the Board and Interim Committee they have) is being reviewed at the moment by a committee of external consultants. The committee will report its findings to the Board at the end of the year. While developing countries do not have as much money to contribute to the IMF as richer countries, they do represent a very large proportion of the World's population. The Brazilian Executive Director has suggested that population size should be incorporated into the quota formula.

Suggested Questions

    —  Does the UK support better representation for developing countries on the IMF Board and in the International Monetary and Finance Committee (previously known as the Interim Committee)?

    —  What changes need to be made to IMF structures to ensure that developing countries are better represented?

    —  Does the UK Executive Director agree that the voting system should be changed to include a country's population size in the formula? What other changes to the formula does the UK support and is it actively advocating these changes to other members of the Board?

2.  The Avoidance of Formal Voting Procedures Impedes Transparency

  A major impediment to accountability is that the Executive Board is not required to formally cast votes. Instead, an informal voting process exists, which is euphemistically referred to as a consensus approach, which means that the IMF management and the Executive Board can avoid making the results of votes known nor how each country voted. There is no good reason why voting should not be formalised and the results made public. If voting was formal it would allow each member country to vote as it saw fit, whereas the current process requires each ED to vote on the behalf of his/her constituency of countries according to the majority view point. It would also aid transparency if Board agendas were made public prior to its meetings and the minutes published. The UK's experience with publishing the minutes of Monetary Commitee meetings is that the benefits outweigh the costs.

Suggested Questions

    —  In the interests of transparency, does the Executive Director believe that voting procedures should be formalised and the results made public?

    —  What is the Executive Director's view on the publication of Board agendas and minutes?

3.  The IMF's Activities are not Systematically and Independently Evaluated

  The trial ad hoc external evaluation process tested over the past three years is currently about to be reviewed. A report will be discussed by the Board in the Winter and a decision on the type of permanent procedure to introduce will be made by the Spring Meetings in 2000. The current process is inadequate because it is very slow (one three reviews have been produced in three years instead of the anticipated three reviews per year) and it cannot systematically review the IMF's activities.

  The UK claims to support the introduction of a dedicated monitoring unit which would report to the Board. Whilst this is encouraging, the UK has done very little to identify how such a unit would function and to communicate this effectively to those on the Board who would rather keep with the existing process.

Suggested Questions

    —  What steps has the Executive Director taken to persuade his colleagues that a dedicated, independent monitoring unit is necessary and what success has he had?

    —  How should such a unit be structured?

    —  There has been no external evaluation of the IMF's role in and response to the financial crises which affected Asia, Russia and Brazil, does the Executive Director agree that this should be the subject on the new unit's first evaluation?

4.  Staff Reports Should be Published

  While the steps taken to make programme documents available to the public are very welcome staff reports are still not released publicly. The G22 recommended that the IMF should rectify this and the Board discussed the possibility of doing so earlier this year. However, no decision was made and the Board simply agreed to return to the issue later.

Suggested Questions

    —  Has the Board discussed this issue further? If so, what was the outcome? If not, when will it be discussed?

    —  What is the Executive Director's opinion on whether these documents should be released?

5.  There Has Been No Written Report to Parliament on the Activities of the Executive Director

  In its 1996-97 inquiry into the role of the IMF, the Treasury Select Committee recommended that the Treasury should produce a report to Parliament on the work of the Executive Director and his staff at the IMF. This report appears to be as mythical as DFID's Institutional Strategy Paper (which is still not available since the Committee interviewed Myles Wickstead in July). Despite many assurances from Treasury staff that a report is imminent it still has not been completed.

Suggested Questions

    —  When will a written report on the activities of the Executive Director be given to Parliament?

    —  Will this be an annual report and when in 2000 can the Committee expect to receive the second report?

THERE IS NO SUBSTANTIAL BODY OF EVIDENCE LINKING CAPITAL ACCOUNT LIBERALISATION (CAL) TO EQUITABLE GROWTH AND POVERTY ERADICATION

  Given the enormous social devastation caused by the financial crisis in what are relatively wealthy and strong economies in South East Asia it is of grave concern that the IMF continues to advocate capital account liberalisation (CAL) as the means for achieving growth in the poorest developing countries. Especially, given its own findings that CAL makes countries particularly vulnerable to financial crises.

1.  The IMF's Mandate Should Not be Extended to give it Authority to Pursue CAL in Member Countries

  During the height of crisis the Executive Board put on hold the debate about whether to extend the IMF's Articles of Agreement to allow it to pursue CAL systematically in member countries. However, Michel Camdessus, IMF Managing Director, is trying to reopen it. At the Annual Meetings in September he argued that, "liberal arrangements for capital movements are beneficial to global economic development . . . I would urge you, Governors, to lend your personal attention to this important proposal, thereby bringing to completion the support you gave us in Hong Kong two years ago for an amendment to the purposes of the Fund and to extend our jurisdiction, as needed."

  Camdessus argues that (1) there is general agreement that CAL is beneficial for world growth as long as (2) liberalisation follows an orderly path. Therefore, the IMF should have a remit to ensure that countries follow orderly paths to full CAL. In fact there is no strong evidence to suggest that it leads to equitable growth or poverty reduction in developing countries or that it leads to higher growth in the global economy. Experience would suggest that the costs—particulary the social costs which are borne by many—can substantially outweigh the benefits—which accrue to a few.

Suggested Questions

    —  What empirical evidence has the IMF produced to demonstrate that CAL leads to sustainable economic growth? Who in developing countries benefits from CAL and what are the linkages to poverty reduction?

    —  The IMF has produced evidence to demonstrate that CAL increases the likelihood of countries experiencing financial crises, has it been able to demonstrate empirically that the massive social costs caused by these crises are outweighed by the benefits of liberalisation in individual countries?

    —  Does the IMF Board intend to look again at extending the IMF's Articles of Agreement to give it a mandate to pursue orderly, carefully sequenced CAL? Does the UK support this?

2.  Good Regulatory Mechanisms are Not Enough Therefore Capital Controls are Essential to Protect Countries

  Mr Camdessus' argument attempts to preserve the market ideology by suggesting that countries can protect themselves with sound financial markets and regulatory mechanisms. This is not so. Even countries with these features and good economic fundamentals, such as the UK, are susceptible to crises. It may be many years before developing countries can develop similar institutions as well as sound social welfare institutions, in their absence, developing countries should continue to be free to use capital controls as they see fit; and the IMF should be required to advise governments on the appropriate use and application of controls and to research which are the most effective.

Suggested Qestions

    —  The IMF has recently completed a report examining various countries' use of controls, this report is not yet available to the public, when will it be?

    —  What were its conclusions and does the Executive Director agree with them?

    —  Should the IMF advise countries on the best use of controls?

Bretton Woods Project

October 1999


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 7 March 2000