Select Committee on Social Security Appendices to the Minutes of Evidence


APPENDIX 18

Memorandum submitted by Mr Tony Lynes (CP 16)

  I have been invited to submit a written memorandum on the future of the contributory principle. Some of the points to which I would like to draw the Committee's attention are discussed in a short paper, drafted by me, which the National Pensioners Convention submitted to the Government's pensions review on 10 November 1997 and which is attached as an annex to this memorandum.

1.  SUMMARY

  1.1  The contributory principle is defined in terms of (1) dependence of benefit rights on a record of contributions and (2) the contractual or quasi-contractual nature of those rights. (Paragraph 2.1)

  1.2  Unlike commercial insurance, social insurance need not be self-financing, rights to benefit may be modified by legislation, the system may be deliberately redistributive, both between classes of contributors and between generations, and contribution conditions may be relaxed for certain benefits on social or other grounds. (Paragraph 2.2)

  1.3  Social insurance is compulsory, subject to contracting-out arrangements under which the contribution rebates broadly cover the cost of the benefits forgone. (Paragraph 2.3)

  1.4  Paragraph 3.1 lists some advantages of the contributory principle; but where contribution conditions are not relevant, benefits should be non-contributory. (Paragraphs 3.2-3.3)

  1.5 Means-testing is generally felt to be incompatible with the contractual nature of insurance. Receipt of income from other sources may provide evidence that the contingency which the benefit is intended to meet has not arisen, but recent means-testing measures are seen as an infringement of the social insurance contract. (Paragraphs 4.1-4.3)

  1.6  The transfer of responsibility for the National Insurance Fund to the Treasury reflects the view that NI contributions are simply a tax and not relevant to the affordability of benefits. (Paragraph 5.1)

  1.7  National insurance should be a separate financial institution. Its governing body, consisting largely of representatives of contributors and pensioners, would be responsible for fixing benefit and contribution rates and proposing structural changes, subject to endorsement by the relevant government departments and by Parliament. The roles of the Benefits Agency and the Inland Revenue in the administration of benefits and the collection of contributions would remain unchanged. (Paragraphs 5.2-5.3)

2.  THE CONTRIBUTORY PRINCIPLE IN COMMERCIAL AND SOCIAL INSURANCE

  2.1  The contributory principle comprises two elements: (1) that entitlement to benefit depends, among other conditions, on a record of contributions paid or treated as paid by or for the beneficiary; (2) that payment of contributions results in the acquisition of rights and, accordingly, any modification of those rights should take into account their contractual or quasi-contractual nature.

  Commercial insurance (I use the term to cover all types of private insurance, whether profit-making or not) provides the simplest examples. Entitlement to benefits under a house or car insurance policy is established by and dependent on payment of contributions (premiums) directly related to the risk insured. The direct relationship between premiums and benefits is a necessary consequence of the commercial nature of the contract: the system is viable only if the premiums paid by holders of a particular type of policy at least match the liability undertaken by the insurer. Provision may be made for crediting of premiums, e.g. during periods of unemployment or sickness, but this is, in reality, an additional insurance for which an appropriate premium is paid, again reflecting the degree of risk. While an insurance company may alter the terms of a policy in respect of future premiums, it cannot refuse to honour its commitments in respect of premiums already paid.

  2.2  Social insurance operates differently. The principle is the same: benefit entitlement depends on a record of contributions paid or credited. The relationship between contributions and benefits, however, differs from commercial insurance in a number of ways:

    (1)  The system as a whole need not be self-financing, since provision can be made for deficits to be made good out of taxation.

    (2)  Rights based on past contributions may be modified by new legislation, provided that such modifications respect the legitimate expectations of contributors and do not undermine confidence in the system.

    (3)  All insurance schemes are redistributive in that they involve the sharing of risks (only people whose cars are stolen benefit financially from car theft insurance, though all policy-holders gain peace of mind), but social insurance may deliberately offer a better deal to some classes of contributors; e.g. the low-paid, carers and others with interrupted earnings due to sickness, unemployment etc.

    (4)  Contribution conditions in a social insurance scheme may be more or less stringent, reflecting social or other objectives. The national insurance death grant, before its abolition, was a striking example of an insurance benefit (admittedly of very small value) which came close to being non-contributory: payment of contributions in a single year, either by the deceased or by his or her spouse, was enough to qualify for the grant.

    (5)  Social insurance may involve deliberate redistribution over time and between generations. This is most visible where pensions and other long-term benefits are financed on a pay-as-you-go basis: current contributions confer entitlement to future benefits but do not pay for them. When new benefits are introduced, contributions may be credited for past years although the cost of the benefits was not reflected in the contributions paid in those years.

  Social insurance, therefore, is an extremely flexible instrument which can be used in pursuit of a wide range of social and economic aims.

  2.3  A fundamental characteristic of social insurance, which underlies many of the differences noted above, is the fact that it is compulsory. Although, in the UK, contracting out of the state earnings-related pension is allowed, the resulting contribution rebates have until now been intended broadly to cover the cost of the benefits forgone, so that the redistributive element in the contribution system is not affected. That principle, however, has not been applied rigidly. The rebates have always been pitched on the generous side and, for the six years 1987-93, an additional 2 per cent rebate was paid to those newly contracting out, mainly at the expense of other contributors. A more radical departure seems to be envisaged in the Government's current proposals, as the pensions Green Paper explains: "Once stakeholder pension schemes are well established, we plan to ensure that all moderate and higher earners would be better off contracting out of the state second pension . . . " (Cm 4179, p 80).

3.  THE ROLE OF CONTRIBUTORY BENEFITS

  3.1  The British social security system has never been wholly contributory. The contributory principle is more appropriate for some benefits than for others. Its advantages (which are as relevant for the 21st century as they were for the 20th) include the following:

    (1)  In the words of the 1942 Beveridge Report, "benefit in return for contributions, rather than free allowances from the State, is what the people of Britain desire". People like to feel that, when they need to claim benefits, they have a right to do so, based not only on their past contributions but, in the case of those of working age, on their willingness to pay contributions in the future when in work.

    (2)  Viewed as a form of taxation, compulsory contributions are more acceptable than other taxes, precisely because they confer rights to benefit.

    (3)  If benefits were wholly tax-financed, they would inevitably be pitched at the lowest possible level. If the system is to provide more than a bare minimum, it is essential that those who are called on to meet the cost should see a clear connection between their payments and the benefits to which they will be entitled.

    (4)  The fact that benefits are based on contributions makes it more difficult—though by no means impossible—for governments to reduce benefits earned by past contributions. This, too, can make payment of contributions more acceptable—but only to the extent that governments, in practice, respect acquired rights.

    (5)  Contribution records provide evidence of recent attachment to the labour force where benefits are intended to replace earnings during temporary interruptions of employment.

    (6)  Contribution records also provide a basis for calculating earnings-related benefits. Payment of higher benefits to higher earners would be difficult to justify in a non-contributory system.

  3.2  A limitation of the contributory system is that, by restricting benefit entitlement to those who satisfy contribution conditions, it may exclude people equally in need of benefits but who, for reasons beyond their control, have neither paid nor been credited with the required amount of contributions. This limitation can, to a large extent, be overcome by means of contribution credits awarded to people in defined situations: sickness, unemployment, full-time caring responsibilities etc. If all gaps in contributions were to be filled by credits, however, the contributory principle would cease to have any meaning. Where the intention is to make a benefit payable to all those in a given situation, regardless of their contribution record, it is simpler and more honest to finance it out of taxation.

  3.3  Child benefit is an obvious example. It is payable whether the parents are currently in paid work or not, and the need for it is in no way dependent on their past history of employment or payment of contributions. To impose contribution conditions would create unnecessary anomalies. Child benefit and the family allowances which preceded it have, therefore, always been non-contributory. On the other hand, the post-war national insurance scheme recognised the need for a supplementary family allowance during periods of unemployment, sickness etc., and this was provided, in the form of "child dependency increases", as part of the contributory national insurance system (over the past 20 years, these increases have been steadily reduced and, in the case of short-term benefits, abolished—an interesting example of the ways in which government action can undermine the contributory principle without any overt change of policy).

4.  MEANS-TESTING AND THE CONTRIBUTORY PRINCIPLE

  4.1  It is generally assumed that benefits earned by contributions should not be subject to a means test. Means-testing is felt to be incompatible with the contractual nature of insurance. Moreover, if the purpose of a benefit is to guarantee a minimum level of income, it seems inappropriate to deny that minimum to those who fail to satisfy contribution conditions. The main means-tested benefits, such as income support and housing benefit, have therefore never operated on a contributory basis and are financed out of general taxation.

  4.2  It would, however, be wrong to assert that means-testing can have no place in a contributory benefit system. Receipt of income from other sources may constitute evidence that the contingency which the benefit is intended to meet has not, in fact, arisen. For example, benefit entitlement may be subject to an earnings limit, as was the case with retirement pensions until 1989 when the earnings rule was abolished. The purpose of the rule was not to exclude those with income above a certain level from drawing a pension (income other than earnings was not taken into account) but to set a limit to the amount of paid work a person could do while still being treated as retired. Similar earnings limits still apply to increases of contributory benefits for both adult and child dependants. The justification for these limits is that a person earning more than a certain amount is regarded as self-supporting and therefore not a `dependant' (in the case of a child, it is the other parent's earnings or private pension that are taken into account; it is assumed that the child is dependent on the earning parent, not on the benefit claimant).

  4.3  More controversially, rules have been introduced to prevent payment of contributory benefits to people in receipt of other privately-financed benefits. Contributory jobseeker's allowance is reduced by any amount over £50 a week received from an occupational or personal pension scheme, on the questionable assumption that anyone of whatever age receiving such a pension cannot be regarded as a genuine jobseeker. The Government now proposes to introduce a similar restriction of entitlement to incapacity benefit, which would be reduced by half the excess over £50 a week received from a pension or permanent health insurance scheme. The rationale of this restriction is not that the person concerned cannot be regarded as incapacitated, but simply that the existence of non-state benefits makes payment of incapacity benefit unnecessary. It is an undisguised means test, which has understandably aroused grave concern among the Government's supporters. Measures of this kind are seen not only as a disincentive to private insurance but as an infringement of the social insurance contract, in contrast to the SERPS contracting-out arrangements under which those opting for private insurance pay reduced NI contributions.

5.  FINANCE AND POLICY CONTROL

  5.1  The British social insurance system is unusual in that the National Insurance Fund is administered directly by a central government department—until recently the Department of Social Security but now the Treasury. The transfer of responsibility to the Treasury has aroused fears that the distinction between contributions and taxes may be blurred and the distinction between contributory and non-contributory benefits undermined. It is certainly rather odd that, in theory at least, the Secretary of State for Social Security remains responsible for fixing benefit rates while the Chancellor of the Exchequer decides the contribution rates. The formal transfer, however, merely reflects the way in which the system has in practice operated for many years. As a DSS official wrote in the letter quoted in the Annex to this memorandum, national insurance expenditure "is no different from expenditure financed by tax receipts, only the method of finance is different". NI contributions are regarded simply as a tax, changes to which are announced by the Chancellor in his Budget (he frequently refers to reductions in contributions as "tax cuts"). Decisions about the affordability of benefits are taken without any regard to the fact that they are financed by contributions and that (as the NPC pointed out—see Annex) when benefits are increased people expect to pay higher contributions.

  5.2  The alternative which I would advocate is that national insurance should be a separate and largely autonomous financial institution, with a governing body consisting largely of representatives of contributors and pensioners which would be responsible for fixing benefit and contribution rates and for proposing structural changes, such as the introduction of new benefits or the modification or abolition of existing benefits. Any such changes would have to be endorsed by the relevant government departments, including the Treasury, and by Parliament. The governing body would be required to have regard to the financial equilibrium of the system, both short-term and long-term, to the reasonable expectations of contributors as to the benefit rights acquired by their past contributions, to the available evidence as to the benefits and rates of benefit for which contributors would be willing to pay, and to the broader economic implications of its actions. Its primary responsibility would be to ensure both the effectiveness and the financial viability of the social insurance system and to justify its actions and proposals in terms of these objectives. A reform of this kind would help to restore public confidence in the system; and this, in turn, would discourage any attempts by future governments to take it over.

  5.3  The changes proposed in the preceding paragraph would mainly affect policy-making and financial planning. The role of the Benefits Agency in the administration of both contributory and non-contributory benefits would remain unchanged, as would that of the Inland Revenue in the collection of contributions.

17 May 1999


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 21 June 2000