Select Committee on Social Security Appendices to the Minutes of Evidence


APPENDIX 26

Work commissioned by the Committee from Ms Holly Sutherland (CP 36)

THE FINANCIAL CONSEQUENCES OF MOVING TO A FULLY MEANS-TESTED SOCIAL SECURITY SYSTEM

SUMMARY

  This paper explores the short-term financial implications of abolishing earnings replacement social security benefits and relying on the system of means-tested benefits to replace them.

  One of the major differences between the non-means-tested system of benefits and the means-tested system is that the former is based on individual entitlements and circumstance, whereas the latter depend on the income and circumstances of all the people in the benefit unit. In the case of couples, both of their circumstances affect their joint entitlement. This is the major factor which explains the failure of the means-tested system to compensate for the abolition of non-means-tested benefits.

  A third of benefit units in the UK would face a loss of income from the abolition of non-means-tested benefits (including the basic pension). Even after accounting for consequential rises in means-tested benefit entitlements, around 25 per cent of all UK benefit units (7.5 million) remain worse off (Para 2.3 and Table 1).

  If the basic pension is retained, the scale of the losses is smaller, but the means-tested system is even less effective in taking the place of the earnings replacement benefits: only about a fifth of losers are fully compensated and 8 per cent of all UK benefit units would remain worse off in cash terms (Para 2.4 and Table 1).

  The lower are the rates of take-up for means-tested benefits, the greater is the extent of net losses (Table 1).

  The net effect of the abolition of earnings replacement benefits would be a considerable reduction in spending. This would permit a cut in income tax rates of about 7 percentage points if the basic pension were included in the benefit cuts and 2 percentage points if it were not (Table 4).

  However, the logic behind the abolition of National Insurance benefits would also imply that National Insurance contributions should be abolished. If this were done, the increase in means-tested benefits could be financed by a rise in income tax rates of 4 percentage points (if the basic pension were retained). The marginal rate of alternative forms of taxation would be higher if the base were narrower than income tax (eg using the present NIC base) or lower if the base were widened (eg creating a new flat tax on all income except benefits). (Table 4)

  In general, a revenue neutral package involving cuts in tax as well as in non-means-tested benefits is not able to reduce the number of losers from the benefit cuts alone. The number of family units losing when income tax is cut remains the same as when there is no tax cut. Alternative financial adjustment mechanisms all involve additional losers as well as gainers (Para 3.5).

  Reforms to the means-tested system of benefits to make it more generous do have the capacity to reduce the number of benefit units that lose. Three enhancements are examined:

    (i)  A disregard of up to £85 per week for income from private or occupational pensions.

    (ii)  An increase of capital limits to £20,000 and capital thresholds for tariff income to £10,000.

    (iii)  A general increase of 10 per cent in all personal allowances and premiums, with a 100 per cent increase for the carer's premium.

  Of the three, the most expensive and effective enhancement is the £85 pension disregard, closely followed by the increase in all means-tested benefit rates. The increase in capital limits has a relatively small effect (Para 4.3 and Table 5).

  In combination, the three enhancements reduce the proportion of losers from 25 per cent to 14 per cent (or 26 per cent to 19 per cent if benefit take-up is incomplete) in the scenario where the basic pension is abolished. Where it is retained, the reduction is proportionately less—from 8 per cent to between 6 per cent and 7 per cent (Para 4.5 and Table 5).

  Overall, the enhancements have very little effect on family units in the top 40 per cent of the income distribution. At no point in the distribution can the enhancements guarantee that there will be no losers. (Para 4.7 and Table 6).

  Much of the impact of the enhancements is on benefit units not currently in receipt of earnings replacement benefits (Para 4.4).

  The following table summarises the main result of the analysis. It shows the proportion of all UK family units who are losers after each of three stages: (i) abolition of earnings replacement benefits, (ii) allowing means-tested benefits to compensate for the loss in income and (iii) enhancement of the means-tested system to make it more generous. The differential effects across the income distribution are shown in Table 6 and Figures 1 to 4 (Para 5.1).

PERCENTAGE OF ALL UK FAMILY UNITS WORSE OFF AFTER THE SHIFT TO MEANSTESTING, WITHOUT AND WITH ENHANCEMENTS

  
All earnings replacement benefits abolished (scenario A)
Basic pension retained (scenario B)
(i)  abolition of earnings replacement benefits
33
10
(ii)  after means-tested benefits adjust
25 (26)
8 (8)
(iii)  after enhancement of means-tested benefits
14 (19)
6 (7)


  NOTE: Figures assume 100 per cent take-up of all benefits. Figures in brackets show percentages of losers under incomplete take-up for means-tested benefits.

  We conclude that the means-tested system is not an effective "shadow" for the non-means-tested system of benefits, nor can it be made so. Many individuals qualify for the latter type of benefit without being in families that are entitled to the former type of benefit.

1.  INTRODUCTION AND METHODOLOGY

  1.1  This paper explores the short-term financial implications of abolishing earnings replacement social security benefits and relying on the system of means-tested benefits to replace them. We use a tax-benefit model, POLIMOD, to calculate the aggregate revenue effects as well as the losers and gainers from each option. This model uses representative household survey micro-data from the Family Expenditure Survey to calculate taxes and benefits before and after policy reforms.[72] In these calculations we inevitably focus on the short term cash effects of the changes. We limit the analysis to the impact on family units, or benefit units,[73] rather than individuals. This is an important limitation since one of the major differences between the non-means-tested system of benefits and the means-tested system is that the former is based on individual entitlements and circumstance, whereas the latter depend on the income and circumstances of all the people in the benefit unit. In the case of couples, both of their circumstances affect their joint entitlement.

  1.2  The following additional points deserve attention but are not explored here.

    —  The changes may involve redistribution of income within households or between partners in couples.

    —  There may be a differential impact on men and women.

    —  There may be an impact on work incentives, particularly on the incentives of the partners of current recipients of earnings replacement benefits.

    —  The incentives to participate in the formal economy will be reduced.

    —  The costs of administration (for the government) and of compliance (for claimants) are different in the two systems.

    —  Shifting the focus of the social security system away from earnings replacement and more firmly onto short-term poverty relief could have many long-term effects on the acceptability and sustainability of the system. Such a fundamental change may have implications way beyond the cash accounting that is the basis of this paper.

  1.3  Even in terms of cash changes, the model results should be treated as estimates with a margin of error. In particular, they do not incorporate the effect of any changes in behaviour that may come about following this major shift in policy. As stated in a recent Government report "Models do not give answers, they give insights". (PIU, 2000; page 62). The modelled scenarios should be treated as illustrations, not forecasts.

  1.4  In particular, the analysis uses the post-October 1999-2000 tax and social security system as the baseline. SERPS and other pension incomes in payment at that time are assumed to remain in place. None of the changes to pensions that are under discussion are included in the modelling.

  1.5  Section 2 examines the revenue and distributional implications of abolishing earnings replacement benefits. Section 3 explores ways of financing the new system. Section 4 discusses ways of improving the extent to which the means-tested system can compensate for losses of non-means-tested benefit. Section 5 concludes.

2. ABOLITION OF CONTRIBUTORY AND EARNINGS-REPLACEMENT BENEFITS: WHO LOSES?

  2.1  We explore two alternative scenarios. The first (A) involves the abolition of all contributory benefits and those non-contributory benefits that are intended for earnings replacement. Details of the benefits abolished and those that remain are listed in the appendix. The second scenario (B) does the same, but retains the basic state retirement pension. In each case we expect entitlements to means-tested benefits to rise, involving increased entitlements for some existing claimants of these benefits as well as an increase in the number of family units in receipt of benefits.

  2.2  One of the issues to be addressed when comparing benefits of different types is the fact that rates of take-up may not be the same. Contributory benefits have rather high take-up, with rates close to 100 per cent. There is evidence to show that take-up of means-tested benefits is much less complete (DSS, 1999). Our modelling makes two alternative assumptions. The first is that take-up behaviour corresponds to that estimated by the DSS.[74] Under this assumption some families do not receive the means-tested benefits to which they are entitled. The second assumption is that all family units with entitlements to benefits do in fact receive them.

  2.3  Table 1 summarises the revenue effects and number of benefit units who would lose from the reform for both scenarios under the two take-up assumptions. It also shows the number of benefit units who would be worse off if the means-tested system did not take the place of non-means-tested benefits. Under scenario A, a third of benefit units in the UK would face a loss of income from the cut in non-means-tested benefits. However, the majority of this group is not compensated by the means-tested system: around 25 per cent of all UK benefit units (7.5 million) remain worse off. There are enormous net savings. Less than half the savings from the non-means-tested system are absorbed by extra expenditure in the means-tested system. There are also relatively minor reductions in income tax revenue due to the fall in taxable income, mainly in pensioner benefit units. The net reduction in the cost of all social security benefits is between £20 and £25 billion a year, depending on the take-up assumption.

  2.4  The scale of the effect of the switch in benefit type is smaller if the basic pension is allowed to remain (scenario B). However, the proportion of benefit units who lose non-means-tested benefits who are not compensated by the means-tested system is even larger: only about a fifth are fully compensated, compared with a quarter under scenario A. Two and a half million family units (or 8 per cent of the total) would remain worse off in cash terms. The net revenue gain is more modest but still substantial: around £7 billion per year.

Caseloads

  2.5  In moving to a means-tested system some benefit units, already receiving top-ups to their non-means-tested benefits, will find that abolition of non-means-tested benefits results in an increase in their entitlements to means-tested benefits. In general they as a family will not become worse off in cash terms, but there may be some re-distribution of income within the family. For example, take the case of a couple where one receives incapacity benefit but because they have no other income they are jointly entitled to some income support. On abolition of incapacity benefit the spouse entitled to it loses this source of independent income. It is replaced by income support for them both, but the pattern of income receipt by the couple will be altered. These benefit units are not included as "losers" in Table 1 but individuals within the units may well consider themselves to be adversely affected by the reform.

  2.6  In other cases, the unit becomes newly qualified for means-tested benefits. In general in these cases they will suffer a reduction in income. There is a third group who may currently be entitled to one set of means-tested benefits (housing benefit or council tax benefit) and, on the loss of non-means-tested benefit become entitled to income support.[75] In general in these cases there will be some loss of income. Table 2 shows the percentage increase in benefit units receiving Income Support and Working Families Tax Credit (WFTC) under the two scenarios and the alternative take-up assumptions. The Income Support caseload would increase by about 40 per cent under scenario A and by 13 per cent under scenario B. The increase is between 4 per cent and 5 per cent for WFTC. Some benefit units will also become newly entitled to housing benefit and council tax benefit.

  2.7  However, the net effect on housing benefit is to reduce the number of benefit units entitled, as more move from housing benefit onto income support than move from receiving no means-tested benefit onto housing benefit and/or council tax benefit.

Distributional effects

  2.8  Table 3 shows how these losses are distributed by benefit unit income level. For clarity we focus on the calculations that assume full take-up. The table shows the average reduction in benefit unit income across the income distribution. This is done in two stages: first, following the reduction in non-means-tested benefits and secondly, after the rest of the tax and benefit system has made adjustments. The proportion of the income lost from earnings replacement benefits that is made up by increases in means-tested benefits is also shown.

  2.9  Not surprisingly, the means-tested system of benefits is more effective at mitigating the loss of non-means-tested benefits at the bottom of the income distribution than at the top. However, two important observations can be made.

  2.10  Firstly, not all the poorest benefit units would be fully compensated. In the bottom 30 per cent of the distribution, around 78 per cent of the aggregate loss is compensated under scenario A and around 83 per cent under scenario B. The failure to compensate fully is due to a combination of factors including:

    —  the capital rules in the means-tested system: benefit units may have amounts of capital that disqualify them from means-tested benefits or that reduces their entitlement to benefit. It is worth noting that people who qualify for contributory benefits necessarily have a history of earnings, and are more likely to have savings than those that have depended on means-tested benefits for some time. Thus, potentially, the capital rules may have a greater impact on entitlements for those brought into the means-tested system, than for existing claimants;

    —  the fact that some benefit units with incomes just above income support level may not qualify for tapered means-tested benefits (eg they may be owner occupiers and not qualify for housing benefit).

  It is also worth noting that the extent of the failure to compensate at the bottom would be worse than that shown in Table 3 if take-up of means-tested benefit is any less than 100 per cent.[76]

  2.11  Secondly, there are many losers among higher income benefit units who are not compensated at all. The rate of compensation in the top half of the distribution is just 25 per cent under scenario A and 18 per cent under scenario B. This is due to:

    —  the fact that many people in receipt of earnings replacement benefits have partners who have earnings or other income,

    —  some people have other sources of income that do not affect entitlements to contributory benefits but which are included either fully or partly in the income tests for means-tested benefits. Examples include income from private and occupational pensions and income from Child Support and other maintenance payments,

    —  the capital rules, as above.

3.  FINANCING THE MEANS-TESTED SYSTEM

  3.1  As shown in Table 1, significant reductions in public spending on social security benefits are implied by the abolition of earnings replacement benefits. Thus in this context "financing" means ways of reducing government revenue. Four illustrative financial adjustment mechanisms are explored. In each case they are taxes or contributions which depend on individual, not family unit, incomes.

  3.2  The four financial adjustments that are considered are:

(a)  Retain all NICs and cut income tax rates

  This option uses the existing NIC system as a revenue-raising mechanism and reduces income tax. However, the logic behind the abolition of National Insurance benefits would also imply that National Insurance contributions should be abolished. The following three options do just this, assuming that:

    —  SERPS is retained.

    —  In Class 1 employee National Insurance contributions (NICs) a 1.6 per cent contribution is retained and paid by those not Contracted Out of SERPS.

    —  Employers' NI contributions are retained.

    —  The equivalent contributions paid by the self employed (Class 4) are retained.[77]

  They raise the necessary revenue using three alternative tax bases and schedules.

(a)  Raise income tax rates

  The logic behind this option is that existing means-tested benefits are financed out of general tax revenue. The extension of meanstesting is financed in the same way.

(b)  Use the existing NIC structure as the basis for an earmarked social security tax

  The equivalent of Class 1 contributions on earnings and Class 4 contributions on self-employment income are levied (the Contracted Out Class 1 rate and the addition to the Class 4 rate are set at the same level, between the existing lower and upper limits).

(c)  A "flat" tax on all earned and unearned income

  This is an alternative structure for an earmarked or hypothecated social security tax. It is levied at a single rate on all non-benefit income.

  3.3  Table 4 shows the revenue-neutral rate(s) of NICs and/or tax for both scenarios under each take-up assumption. In fact, scenario A reduces the cost of social security by such a large amount that even the abolition of Class 1 (employee) and Class 2 NICs does not reduce revenue sufficiently to result in a revenue neutral combination. Thus no figures are provided for financing mechanisms (b) to (d). The combination of scenario A and abolition of NICs raises £1.0 billion under 100 per cent take-up and £5.6 billion under partial take-up. Abolition of NICs on its own costs £19.6 billion, equivalent to 6 percentage points on income tax rates.

  3.4  To aid comparison of the effects of the financing measure Table 4 also shows the fall in the combined marginal rate of tax and contributions for a single person with (Contracted Out) earnings of £20,000 per year (and no other income) under each financing system. Under the current system this marginal rate is 33 per cent. Not surprisingly the financing mechanism with the widest income base (d) produces the largest cut in marginal rate as well as the greatest number of losers.

  3.5  The proportions of benefit units gaining and losing from the combination of benefit changes and financing mechanism are also shown. In general we see that the cuts in tax or NICs are not able to reduce the number of losers from the abolition of non-means-tested benefits. This is because at any one time the two groups—non-means-tested benefit recipients and income taxpayers—are largely different. Tax cuts are not a viable mechanism for compensation for the loss of benefits. The number of family units losing under financial adjustment (a) remains the same as when there is no tax cut. The other financial adjustment mechanisms all involve additional losers as well as gainers.

4.  ENHANCEMENTS TO THE MEANS-TESTED SYSTEM

  4.1  In order to explore whether there are ways of making the means-tested system better "shadow" the effect of the non-means-tested system, particularly in the lower half of the income distribution, we examine three possible enhancements to the means-tested system.

    (i)  A disregard of up to £85 per week for income from private or occupational pensions (Including SERPS). This disregard is on an individual basis (both partners in a couple may claim it if they each have pension income in their own right).

    (ii)  An increase of the capital limits to £20,000. For Income Support this is an increase of £12,000 from £8000 and for housing benefit and council tax benefit it is an increase of £4000 from £16,000. The capital thresholds for tariff income are also increased from £3,000 to £10,000. The capital limits for Working Families Tax Credit remain unchanged.

    (iii)  A general increase of 10 per cent in all means-tested benefit personal allowances and premiums, with a 100 per cent increase for the carer's premium. (These increases are not applied to Working Families Tax Credit.)

    (iv)  A combination of (i), (ii) and (iii).

  4.2  The effects of these enhancements are examined individually and in combination in the context of both scenario A and scenario B and for both take-up assumptions. Table 5 shows the effects on the net cost, and benefit units gaining and losing. These are compared with the results for the scenarios without enhancements ("None").

  4.3  The most expensive enhancement is the £85 pension disregard (i), closely followed by the increase in all means-tested benefit rates (iii). The increase in capital limits has only a small effect, and this mainly among pensioners.

  4.4  There are gainers from the enhancements in addition to the family units being compensated for the loss in earnings replacement benefits. Not surprisingly, increasing benefit rates has a particularly large effect beyond compensation.

  4.5  Focusing on the losers—those who remain not fully compensated, in spite of the enhancements—we find the following.

    —  The enhancements are most effective at reducing the number of losers among pensioners (ie in scenario A).

    —  Not surprisingly, enhancement (i)—the pension disregard—is most effective among ex-recipients of the state pension (scenario A).

    —  Relaxing the capital limits is not effective at all in decreasing the numbers of non-pensioners (scenario B) who lose, although the degree of compensation may be increased among losers.

    —  Enhancement (iii)—increasing benefit rates—is most effective among pensioners.

    —  All the enhancements are less effective if means-tested benefit take-up is incomplete.

    —  Overall, the combination of three enhancements reduces the proportion of losers from 25 per cent to 14 per cent (or 26 per cent to 19 per cent for incomplete benefit take-up) under scenario A.

    —  Under scenario B the reduction is less—from 8 per cent to 6 per cent or 7 per cent.

  4.6  Clearly it is difficult to target losers among the non-pensioner population with means-tested benefit enhancements. This is mainly because working age claimants of earnings replacement benefits are more likely to have non-pension income, or partners with independent income, than are people of pension age.

  4.7  The position in the income distribution of the losers under each combination of scenario and benefit enhancement is shown in Table 6. This confirms that the enhancements have very little effect in the top 40 per cent. Nor is there any point in the distribution where they can they guarantee that there will be no losers.

5.  CONCLUDING COMMENTS

  5.1  Figures 1 to 4 summarise the effect across the income distribution by showing the proportion of losers that remain after each of three stages: (i) abolition of earnings replacement benefits, (ii) allowing means-tested benefits to rise for those entitled and (iii) then enhancing the means-tested system to make it more generous. The black parts of the bars show the benefit units that remain as losers after means-tested benefit enhancements. The dark grey sections show the reduction in the number of losers dues to the benefit enhancements. The pale grey sections show the benefit units in receipt of earnings replacement benefits that are compensated for the loss of these by the current means-tested system.

  5.2  For example Figure 1 shows that 55 per cent of the 4th decile group of family units receive earnings replacement benefits (including the basic retirement pension). When these are abolished, 17 per cent of the decile group are fully compensated by the means-tested system. When this is enhanced with all three changes a further 26 per cent of the group are compensated, leaving 12 per cent worse off than under the current system. In the 7th decile 30 per cent receive benefits that are abolished, 6 per cent are compensated by the existing means-tested system and a further 3 per cent by enhancements. This leaves 21 per cent (or three quarters of the original losers) remaining uncompensated.

  5.3  Each figure shows a similar pattern, although the scale of the changes is larger under scenario A (Figures 1 and 2) than B (Figures 3 and 4) and compensation using the means-tested system (MTB) with or without enhancements is less successful when take-up rates are less than 100 per cent (Figures 2 and 4).

  5.4  Significant numbers of losers would remain even when enhancement of the means-tested system is on such a scale that it costs more than the existing non-means-tested system (scenario B with the combination of three enhancements). Most of the losers are in family units with above median incomes, but this is certainly not uniformly the case. Sizeable proportions of losers are in the poorest third of families.

  5.5  We conclude that the means-tested system is not an effective "shadow" for the non-means-tested system of benefits, nor can it be made so. Many individuals qualify for the latter type of benefit without being in families that are entitled to the former type of benefit.

REFERENCES

  Department of Social Security, 1999, Income Related Benefits: Estimates of Take-Up in 1996/7 (revised) and 1997/8, Analytical Services Division.

  Performance and Innovation Unit, 2000, Adding It Up: Improving Analysis and Modelling in Central Government, The Stationery Office.

  Redmond G, H Sutherland and M Wilson, 1998, The arithmetic of tax and social security reform: a user's guide to microsimulation methods and analysis, DAE Occasional Paper No. 64, Cambridge University Press.

Table 1

THE COSTS OF MOVING TO MEANS-TESTING

Scenario:
A
B
Take-up:
Full
Partial
Full
Partial
Net revenue cost £ billion/year
-20.56
-25.23
-6.70
-7.58
Abolition of Non-means-tested benefits
-41.20
-41.20
-12.75
-12.75
Means-tested benefits
+18.74
+14.06
+5.80
+4.92
Income tax
+1.90
+1.91
+0.25
+0.25
Benefit units losing income, thousand(per cent)
7,420 (25 per cent)
7,960 (26 per cent)
2,410 (8 per cent)
2,510 (8 per cent)
Benefit units losing Non-means-tested benefits, thousand (per cent)
9,820 (33 per cent)
3,140 (10 per cent)
Source: POLIMOD


Table 2

PERCENTAGE INCREASE IN BENEFIT UNITS ENTITLED TO INCOME SUPPORT AND WORKING FAMILIES TAX CREDIT

Scenario:
A
B
Take-up:
Full
Partial
Full
Partial
Means-tested benefit
Income Support
43 per cent
37 per cent
13 per cent
13 per cent
Working Families Tax Credit
5 per cent
4 per cent
5 per cent
4 per cent
Source: POLIMOD


Table 3

LOSSES IN BENEFIT UNIT INCOME FROM MOVING TO A FULLY MEANS-TESTED SYSTEM (£/WEEK) ASSUMING FULL BENEFIT TAKE-UP

  
A
B
Decile group1
Non-means-tested benefit changes
All changes
Mean compensation per cent
Non-means-tested benefit changes
All changes
Mean compensation per cent
bottom
-4.57
-0.64
86
-4.05
-0.48
88
2nd
-33.62
-6.43
81
-8.52
-1.13
87
3rd
-39.87
-12.87
68
-10.61
-2.70
74
4th
-44.36
-15.34
65
-12.25
-4.24
65
5th
-36.97
-19.01
49
-9.86
-5.20
47
6th
-29.64
-20.56
31
-9.87
-6.46
35
7th
-24.69
-17.53
29
-9.17
-7.34
20
8th
-19.31
-14.30
26
-7.35
-5.96
19
9th
-17.59
-14.80
16
-6.68
-6.17
8
top
-12.45
-9.75
22
-3.06
-2.81
8
all
-26.30
-13.12
50
-8.14
-4.25
48
1 Benefit units are ranked by family disposable income, equivalised using the OECD equivalence scale(=1 for a single person (aged >13), 1.7 for a couple and 0.5 for each child aged 0-13.). Losses are expressedin £/ week without equivalisation.

Source: POLIMOD


Table 4

REVENUE NEUTRAL SCHEMES: TAX RATES, GAINERS AND LOSERS

Scenario:
A
B
Take-up:
Full
Partial
Full
Partial
Financing mechanism
(a) NICs retained; income tax rates cut by (per cent points)
6.5
8.0
2.1
2.3
(b) NICs abolished; income tax rates raised by ( per cent points)
*
*
4.0
3.7
(c) NICs abolished; hypothecated tax based on Class 1 NIC of ( per cent)
*
*
5.3
5.0
per cent point fall in Marginal Tax
*
*
2.9
2.7
Rate for "standard person"
(a)
6.5
8.0
2.1
2.3
(b)
  
  
4.4
4.7
(c)
  
  
3.1
3.4
(d)
  
  
5.5
5.7
per cent benefit units gaining
49
50
57
57
(a)
  
  
44
44
(b)
  
  
46
46
(c)
  
  
42
43
(d)
 
  
  
  
per cent benefit units losing
24
26
8
8
(a)
  
  
23
23
(b)
  
  
11
11
(c)
  
  
34
34
(d)
  
  
  
  


  *  No revenue-neutral tax rate.

  NOTES: Under Scenario B, full take-up

    (a)  Current of tax rates of 10 per cent, 23 per cent, and 40 per cent become 7.9 per cent, 10.9 per cent and 37.9 per cent; taxable investment income not in the higher rate band is taxed at 17.9 per cent instead of 20 per cent.

    (b)  NIC NCO Class 1 rate is 1.6 per cent instead of 10 per cent; CO Class 1 and Class 2 are set to zero; Income tax rates become 14.0 per cent, 27.0 per cent and 44.0 per cent (investment income 24.0 per cent).

    (c)  NIC NCO Class 1 rate is 6.6 per cent instead of 10 per cent; CO Class 1 is 5.3 per cent instead of 8.4 per cent, Class 4 is 11.3 per cent instead of 6.0 per cent and Class 2 is set to zero.

    (d)  NIC NCO Class 1 rate is 1.6 per cent instead of 10 per cent; CO Class 1 and Class 2 are set to zero; Flat tax on all income (on an individual basis, no allowances, reliefs or credits) at a rate of 2.9 per cent on all income except benefits.

  Source: POLIMOD

Table 5

THE COSTS AND BENEFITS OF MOVING TO AN ENHANCED MEANS-TESTED SYSTEM

  Enhancements (i) to (iv)

Scenario:
A
B
Take-up:
Full
Partial
Full
Partial
Additional cost £ billion / year1
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
None
6.26
4.42
4.14
3.35
(i)
2.65
2.10
1.10
0.92
(ii)
4.49
3.52
3.99
3.29
(iii)
15.93
11.89
10.98
8.83
(iv)=(i)+(ii)+(iii)
  
  
  
  
Total net revenue gain £ billion/year
20.56
25.23
6.70
7.58
None
14.30
20.81
2.56
4.23
(i)
17.91
23.13
5.60
6.66
(ii)
16.07
21.71
2.71
4.29
(iii)
4.63
13.34
-4.28
-1.25
(iv)=(i)+(ii)+(iii)
  
  
  
  
Family units losing income (per cent)
25
26
8
8
None
18
22
7
8
(i)
23
26
8
8
(ii)
20
24
7
7
(iii)
14
19
6
7
(iv)=(i)+(ii)+(iii)
  
  
  
  
Family units gaining income (per cent)
0
0
0
0
None
12
8
14
11
(i)
3
3
5
4
(ii)
27
22
30
25
(iii)
34
27
35
29
(iv)=(i)+(ii)+(iii)
  
  
  
  


  1 The cost of the three enhancements combined is greater than the sum of the cost of each enhancement because both enhancements (i) and (ii) cost more when benefits are made more generous as in enhancement (iii).

  Source: POLIMOD

Table 6

FAMILY UNITS LOSING FROM THE SHIFT TO MEANS-TESTING, WITH ENHANCEMENTS (I) TO (IV) PER CENT

  (a)  with full take-up

  
A
B
Decile group
None
(i)
(ii)
(iii)
(iv)
None
(i)
(ii)
(iii)
(iv)
bottom
3
3
2
2
1
2
2
2
2
1
2nd
23
13
18
13
4
6
6
6
3
2
3rd
37
19
35
27
10
10
8
10
7
5
4th
38
20
36
25
12
12
10
12
8
5
5th
36
23
35
29
17
10
9
10
9
7
6th
30
26
30
29
22
10
10
10
10
8
7th
24
23
24
23
21
9
9
9
9
9
8th
20
19
20
20
19
8
8
8
8
8
9th
20
20
20
20
20
7
7
7
7
7
top
15
15
15
15
15
4
4
4
4
4
all
25
18
23
20
14
8
7
8
7
6


  (b)  with partial take-up

  
A
B
Decile group
None
(i)
(ii)
(iii)
(iv)
None
(i)
(ii)
(iii)
(iv)
bottom
5
5
5
5
4
3
3
3
3
3
2nd
27
21
24
20
15
6
6
6
4
4
3rd
40
29
38
33
22
11
10
11
8
7
4th
44
31
43
35
25
13
11
13
10
7
5th
38
29
37
33
25
11
9
10
9
8
6th
32
29
31
30
26
11
10
11
10
9
7th
25
24
25
24
23
10
9
10
9
9
8th
20
20
20
20
20
8
8
8
8
8
9th
20
20
20
20
20
7
7
7
7
7
top
15
15
15
15
15
4
4
4
4
4
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
  
all
26
22
26
24
19
8
8
8
7
7


  Source: POLIMOD

Figure 1

PERCENTAGE OF FAMILY UNITS WITH EARNINGS REPLACEMENT BENEFITS BY INCOME LEVEL: EXTENT OF COMPENSATION BY MEANS-TESTED BENEFITS AND BENEFIT ENHANCEMENTS

Scenario A, full take-up



Figure 2

PERCENTAGE OF FAMILY UNITS WITH EARNINGS REPLACEMENT BENEFITS BY INCOME LEVEL: EXTENT OF COMPENSATION BY MEANS-TESTED BENEFITS AND BENEFIT ENHANCEMENTS

Scenario A, incomplete take-up



Figure 3

PERCENTAGE OF FAMILY UNITS WITH EARNINGS REPLACEMENT BENEFITS (NOT INCLUDING THE BASIC PENSION) BY INCOME LEVEL: EXTENT OF COMPENSATION BY MEANS-TESTED BENEFITS AND BENEFIT ENHANCEMENTS

Scenario B, full take-up



Figure 4

PERCENTAGE OF FAMILY UNITS WITH EARNINGS REPLACEMENT BENEFITS (NOT INCLUDING THE BASIC PENSION) BY INCOME LEVEL: EXTENT OF COMPENSATION BY MEANS-TESTED BENEFITS AND BENEFIT ENHANCEMENTS

Scenario B, partial take-up





72   See Redmond et al (1998) for more information. Data from the Family Expenditure Survey are Crown Copyright. They have been made available by the Office for National Statistics (ONS) through the Data Archive and are used by permission. Neither the ONS nor the Data Archive bears any responsibility for the analysis or interpretation of the data reported here. Back

73   We refer to benefit units, family units and families interchangeably. They are defined as single people or couples and any dependent children. The whole resident UK population, not living in institutions, is included. Back

74   We attempt to capture the effects of non- take-up of means-tested benefits (FC/WFTC, IS, HB and CTB) by applying the take-up proportions estimated by the Department of Social Security (DSS, 1999). For example we assume that some 20 per cent of lone parents do not receive the FC/WFTC to which they are entitled, and 15 per cent of people of working age do not receive the Income Support to which they are entitled. We assume that take-up behaviour is not affected by changes in the size of benefit entitlements. Back

75   Plus 100 per cent support for rent and council tax. Back

76   For example, using our partial take-up assumption the mean rate of compensation in the bottom two deciles is 59 per cent in scenario A and 73 per cent in scenario B. Back

77   Class 3 contributions, which are voluntary, are not modelled. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 21 June 2000