Select Committee on Treasury Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum by Roger Bootle, Specialist Adviser to the Committee

CAUSES OF THE EURO'S WEAKNESS

  1.  To some observers, the weakness of the euro since its inception are obvious and require little thought or analysis. They do, to some eyes, though, have equally obvious implications for Britain's stance with regard to membership. In my view, however, a careful look at the arguments reveals that the extent of the euro's weakness, if not the mere direction of its movement, presents something of a puzzle. Although enormous uncertainties remain about the relative roles of different factors in explaining the currency's weakness, the conclusion reached here is that the likely factors which explain it have few, if any, implications for the question of whether the UK should adopt the euro.

  2.  There are umpteen suggested reasons for the euro's weakness but they all fall into one of two camps: reasons why a rational analysis of the economic fundamentals in the euro-zone justifies something like the euro's current value; and structural reasons why the market has reached and sustained a value for the euro which cannot be justified by reference to the economic fundamentals. It is helpful to analyse the euro's value by asking whether any of the reasons appearing under the first group can justify the current level and if they cannot, then going on to ask whether any of the structural factors can offer a convincing explanation.

  3.  Euroland is a sluggish, slow growth area. It is true that for much of the last decade, growth has been lower in Euroland than it has been in the United States, but the gap looks set to narrow sharply and soon may even reverse. But in any case, the growth explanation on its own is pretty unconvincing. Comparison with the UK is particularly interesting in this regard. You would think that the logic of the "slow growth" explanation would tie in with strong UK growth, since the pound has been so strong against the euro. In fact, last year the UK was well down the European growth league and will be so again this year. Both France and Germany will probably grow faster than the UK.

  4.  Moreover, such "explanations" do not justify exchange rate levels. For according to efficient market theory, it should not be possible systematically to make a profit by exploiting publicly available information. Now if an exchange rate were systematically depressed by equity capital deserting the euro-zone because of poor real growth and hence earnings prospects, but which did not adversely affect prospective inflation, then it would be possible for speculators to take an open position in euros, invested in bonds or deposits and hope to gain substantial profits on an eventual recovery of the euro. Theoretically, the interplay of these forces should mean that a currency never becomes "under-valued" or "over-valued".

  5.  European interest rates are low. This is a variant of the low growth argument but it can be deployed somewhat differently. The elementary idea is that a currency which offers higher interest rates should be stronger than one which offers lower rates. But in fact this simple idea does not get you very far. If interest rates are increased by 1 per cent and will be sustained at that level for a year, the simple increase in interest income would be offset by a prospective fall of the exchange rate of only 1 per cent. Once the exchange rate has risen by 1 per cent following an interest rate increase of 1 per cent, other things equal, the currency can now be viewed as prone to a 1 per cent greater fall over the year than before. So the exchange rate should strengthen by only 1 per cent. Therefore, the simple argument can explain only tiny movements of the exchange rate yet the movements that we actually observe in currencies are enormous.

  6.  Nevertheless, once you assume that investors may continue to be attracted by a higher interest rate even after the currency has risen, (and indeed they may be even more attracted if they now believe the currency is set to appreciate in the future), then interest rate differentials can have a powerful effect on currency values.

  7.  But in this case the really powerful factor is how investors' expectations of future currency values are determined. In this story, it is the fact that once the currency has risen they think it no more likely to fall than before, and perhaps even more likely to rise, which gives the apparently striking relevance of interest rate differentials.

  8.  Moreover, differentials often do not have the effect described in the above account. Raising interest rates can depress a currency, as happened when sterling failed to hold its floor in the ERM. Equally, low interest rates may be no barrier to great currency strength, as has happened several times with Japan. In the case of the euro, it is striking that on several occasions, prominent market players have argued that higher interest rates would depress the euro because they would tend to reduce growth prospects. If that view is correct then higher interest rates would only serve as a boost to the euro by proxy, that is to say when they were a reflection of a strong growth environment in Euroland, but when they were imposed by the ECB for some real or imagined policy reason, but without justification from a strong underlying growth environment, then they might depress the currency.

  9.  Long-term inflation prospects in Euroland are poor. This is the view encapsulated in the notion that whereas investors were sold the idea of the euro as a super-deutschmark in fact it is more like a souped-up lira. Again this view has several variants. The ECB is incoherent and subject to national pressures; under fire it would not be resolute in the way that the Bundesbank would; now that they are inside the single currency, countries with a poor past record on financial discipline and the control of inflation, such as Italy, will relax fiscal restraints and return to high wage inflation, thereby presenting the ECB with a classic stagflation dilemma, and it would be inclined to take the line of least resistance; the eastward expansion of the EU, and ultimately the euro, will increase the force of this factor; some countries (and Austria is the most frequently quoted example) may seek to leave the euro and perhaps even the EU, thereby provoking a wholesale political and economic crisis.

  10.  There are undoubtedly widespread concerns of this sort in the markets but I find this class of explanation for the weakness of the euro wholly unconvincing. You do not need to weigh up the merits of each individual argument, although many look pretty shaky, but rather observe the behaviour of European bond markets. If the euro is so weak because of investor fears of long-term inflation, why are European bond yields so low?

  11.  So I come to the conclusion that the low value of the euro is not reasonably explicable by reference to the economic fundamentals and accordingly that it is appropriate to seek an explanation from structural factors. There are two which appeal to me, with a third which may play a powerful supporting role.

  12.  First, when the euro was about to be launched, most market analysis centred on the way that the new currency would prove much more attractive as an investment than its forebears, the constituent currencies. In fact it might soon come to rival the dollar. They mostly neglected the other side of financial balance sheets. In fact, what has happened is that the euro has greatly increased the attractions for borrowers by forging a single unified capital market, much more liquid than before. Increased international borrowing in euros for sale into various domestic currencies will have weakened the new currency.

  13.  Meanwhile, investors and depositors have had one reason, at least, for finding the euro less attractive than its constituent currencies, namely the reduced demand which results from pooling. Depositors, who include many multinational companies, have been used to keeping balances in several European currencies to facilitate transactions. Now they need balances only in one, and balances held in euros can serve as a "float" or buffer for prospective expenditures or financial flows in any part of the euro area.

  14.  For real investors, the change comes about mainly from the loss of diversification possibilities from the merging of the European currencies. While they were separate monetary areas, investments in these different countries possessed rather different risk characteristics. Now they are more similar. So, ironically, while the euro has been attractive to borrowers, it has been rather unattractive to depositors and investors.

  15.  Nevertheless, such structural explanations still leave most economists rather uneasy because they leave an apparent opportunity for profit—in this instance, by buying the euros which the borrowers and uninspired depositors and investors sell, whenever the price in the market dips below "fair value". So why has this not happened?

  16.  One answer is that the currency markets rarely work this way because they are dominated by short-term players whose expectations are extrapolative, rather than being fixed by ideas of reversion to some measure of fair value. And, in my view, this point has much to commend it as an explanation of why currency markets behave the way they do.

  17.  But there has been something more specific about the market structure of the last year which may bring added explanatory power to bear. For the one category of market player who might be thought likely to place big bets on the direction of currency movements on the basis of fundamental economic analysis is the hedge funds. It is notable that the two large macro funds, Quantum and Tiger, have virtually shut up shop. Perhaps this has something to contribute to an explanation of why the market price of the euro has not reflected economic fundamentals.

CONCLUSION

  18.  The weakness of the euro on the exchanges is not to be interpreted, in my view, as a sign that the currency is fundamentally flawed, nor even that international investors see it, and its prospects, as dire. Indeed, the scale of the market movement is well within the scale of movements seen in the value of currencies such as the dollar, yen and pound over the last twenty years. Frequently over that period, abrupt movements in one direction have been reversed, without obvious or convincing justification from the economic fundamentals.

  19.  In my judgement, this is likely to happen with the euro. Given that its weakness cannot reasonably be said to reflect a genuine market assessment of long run value, the fact that the currency has been weak so far should play very little part in any decisions the UK takes about adopting the euro—except in so far as it affects the exchange rate at which entry might be possible.

25 May 2000


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 17 July 2000