Select Committee on Treasury Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Professor Iain Begg and Mr Brian Ardy, South Bank University

INTRODUCTION

  Despite the fall in the euro, the beginning of stage 3 of EMU has been relatively trouble-free. The institutions, particularly the ECB, have carried out their roles satisfactorily, although inevitably there have been some problems. The economic performance of the euro-area has been good with accelerating economic growth, falling unemployment and low inflation. Even the fall in the external value of the euro has been a mixed blessing, encouraging growth but undermining market and public confidence. For the UK the experience of being outside has been rather uncomfortable especially as the euro has continued to fall.

  This memorandum is written in response to the invitation circulated by the Treasury Committee to submit written evidence to the inquiry into economic and monetary union announced on 16 March 2000. Following the terms of reference, it covers the conduct of monetary policy in the euro area and the prospects for its economy, the UK position and the possible implications for the euro of enlargement. We do not feel competent to discuss the national changeover plan.

SUMMARY OF MAIN POINTS

    —  Euro area macroeconomic policy has been well judged over the last 18 months and has contributed to a favourable economic performance.

    —  The fall in the euro has been steep but is not unprecedented.

    —  The euro is now significantly undervalued and seems to be undergoing a correction.

    —  The rise in the value of Sterling against the euro has made it more difficult to satisfy the exchange rate stability criterion for the EMU entry, but the UK meets the other Maastricht convergence criteria.

    —  The UK is now much more convergent with the euro area than when the five economic tests were set.

    —  The risk for the future is that non-convergence could become self-fulfilling so long as the UK stays out of the single currency.

    —  There is unlikely to be any pronounced or immediate impact of enlargement on the euro.

OVERALL ASSESSMENT

  Seen from the UK or from City dealing rooms, the euro has had a rocky start. Its loss of value against other major currencies and the apparent inability of the members of the Governing Council of the European Central Bank (ECB) to sing from the same hymn-sheet, notably in commenting on the external value of the currency, have been seized upon by the euro's detractors as evidence that the whole enterprise is mis-conceived. But viewed from within the "euro area", the picture is much more rosy. Growth is picking up, unemployment is edging downwards and there is no sign of a resurgence of price inflation despite the fall in the value of the currency. On the whole, the economic management of the euro area has been sensible and fears of either an overly restrictive or a cavalier monetary policy have proved to be unfounded. Certainly, unemployment remains high, especially in the euro area's four largest economies (France, Germany, Italy and Spain), but the trend is manifestly in the right direction, although there is wide recognition that the pace of supply-side reform needs to be accelerated.

  The latest forecasts from the OECD, published in late May 2000, confirm those published by the European Commission in April in projecting that the EU economy will continue to grow at a healthy but sustainable rate this year and next. The OECD forecasts that the euro area's growth rate in 2001 will, at 3.3 per cent, be higher than the US, Japan and the UK. Moreover, inflation is expected to remain under 2 per cent and the current account balance is in growing surplus. Consequently, there is no obvious reason for the euro area economy to slow down. The OECD does forecast some further increase in the euro area interest rate, but expects rates to remain below those in the US and the UK. The gap between the UK and euro rates is, however, expected to narrow.

  The implication of all this is that euro area macroeconomic policy has, on the whole, been well-judged and that the ECB seems to have fulfilled its mandate to assure price stability while having regard to general economic conditions. There was undoubtedly a fear in advance of stage 3 that the ECB would implement an overly muscular monetary policy that would hamper recovery, but thus far monetary conditions seem to have been appropriate. In fact the early cuts in interest rates effected by the ECB in late 1998 and early 1999 suggest a greater willingness to ease than the Bundesbank showed a few years earlier.

THE FALL IN THE EURO

  What, then, of the fall in the euro? Although something of an embarrassment to those who expected or wanted the euro to be a rival to the dollar, it has not obviously damaged the euro area economy. Any devaluation has to be judged on whether the boost it gives to net export demand is offset by inflationary pressures emanating from higher import costs. The evidence on inflation, growth and trade performance suggests that this trade-off has, thus far, been favourable. This is not altogether surprising: the euro area (in common with the US and Japan) is a relatively closed economy which means that the shift in the currency has relatively little impact on consumer prices through imports, but that net exports are boosted.

  A more subtle question is whether the fall in the euro poses a longer-term threat. To answer this, it is useful, first, to consider what caused the fall, bearing in mind the widespread agreement that "fundamentals" point to a strong euro. Four reasons can be put forward:

    —  First, the difference in interest rates between the euro and the dollar has provided an incentive to hold the latter (and the pound). Plainly, though, this does not hold for the yen.

    —  Second, the boom in, especially, high-tech stocks across the pond drew capital from Europe, creating a demand for dollars and selling pressure on the euro.

    —  Third, the discordant voices from Frankfurt and elsewhere speaking on behalf of the euro have sown uncertainty that the markets have been quick to exploit. This reinforced worries about a new and untried currency.

    —  Fourth, the perceived slow pace of structural reform in the larger EU economies coupled with the relatively slow recovery from recession seemed to signal an underlying economic weakness compared with a dynamic US economy.

  It also has to be recognised that the fall in the euro between January 1999 and April 2000, though steep, is not unprecedented. The fall in the dollar in the mid-1980s was much greater, while the collapse of the pound between 1980 and 1985, and again in 1992, is too easily forgotten.

  Foreign exchange rates are notoriously unstable and difficult to predict, so it would be a mistake to read too much into the weakness of the euro over the last 18 months. The values of euro-area currencies have been lower than this before: in a previous period of dollar strength in 1985 the DM fell to a rate of 3.5 to the dollar compared to the current implicit rate of 2.2 to the dollar. By contrast, between 1996 and the end of 1998, the dollar languished at under 2 DM to the dollar.

  Today, there is, nevertheless, a general agreement that the euro is substantially undervalued. The ECB estimates that in terms of purchasing power parity the euro has lost 12.5 per cent of its value since its launch[1]. Even before the euro's slide began it was estimated that it was 7.4 per cent undervalued against the dollar and 15.5 per cent undervalued against sterling.[2] A rebound in the value of the euro is, therefore, likely and the recent fall in the value of sterling and the rise in the euro above $0.90 may indicate the start of this process.

THE MAASTRICHT CRITERIA

  The UK meets four of the five Maastricht criteria, but plainly cannot satisfy the exchange rate stability criterion embodied in the requirement that an aspirant to stage 3 should have participated in the ERM without parity change for two years. The degree of independence of the Bank of England also falls short of what is expected. However, neither of these is likely to be an obstacle to UK participation in stage 3 and a political fix would almost certainly be found if the UK wanted it.

THE FIVE ECONOMIC TESTS

  The first of the Chancellor's tests—cyclical convergence—is the one deemed by the Treasury to be most important and the one that has seemed most difficult to pass. It can, however, be argued that in the light of macroeconomic developments across the EU in the last 30 months, cyclical convergence is no longer the problem it was in 1997. After the slowdown in 1999, the UK is roughly in the middle of the EU league tables for growth and inflation, though still better than average for unemployment.

  Measures of "output gap" also suggest that the British economy is now much closer to the rest of the EU in cyclical performance. In 1997, according to the OECD, the UK economy was operating at 1.1 per cent above full capacity as measured by the difference between actual and potential output, whereas the euro area had a negative gap of 1.6 per cent, a difference of 2.7 percentage points. Projections are that the difference between the UK and euro area output gaps will narrow to 1.1 per cent this year and to 0.1 per cent in 2001. Although there are methodological problems in measuring and interpreting output gaps (European Commission estimates show a similar difference between the UK and the euro area in 1997 and 2000, but based on differing values), the steady narrowing of the gap is significant.

  In any case, total convergence within any monetary union would be exceptional and it is undeniable that there is continuing macroeconomic divergence in the euro area. Germany and Italy, in particular, have been laggards, whereas several of the smaller EU economies have been booming. But there is little sign that this is undermining the conduct of policy. Tensions are bound to increase as some of the euro area economies become more over-heated, but it is important to recognise that all sides are adapting progressively to the new monetary regime. A few years ago, it would have been inconceivable that Ireland, Portugal or Spain could have sustained their current growth rates without stoking inflation. Indeed one of the consequences of monetary union that has received too little attention is that it must be expected to alter the behaviour of economic agents, notably those in the labour market, by transforming expectations.


  The significance of such change is that it bears on how convergent economies are and thus on the suitability of a one-size-fits-all monetary policy for different parts of the economy. The Governor of the Bank of England found himself in hot water in the North of England for his admission that UK monetary policy is weighted towards the over-heating South East. Leaving aside the irony that current euro interest rates would be just about right for the North of England, though not for the South, the degree to which convergence occurs as a result of euro membership is a critical part of the UK decision on the five economic tests.

  The rise in the pound since 1996 does not appear to have much adverse effect on the UK growth rate and has probably helped to keep inflation low. But the volatility of the currency creates problems for the planning of investment and production. Anecdotal evidence suggests that UK manufacturing industry was badly hit by the appreciation of sterling against the euro, with the most obvious examples being the travails at Rover and the planned ending of car manufacturing at Dagenham by Ford. The risk for the future is that excessive sterling volatility will become a cause of further cycles of boom and bust. Non-convergence could, therefore, become self-fulfilling so long as the UK stays out of the single currency.

  Of the other four economic tests, one (the impact on the UK financial services industry) seems to us to point only one way, while the others are vague enough to be open to be adjudged either positively or negatively on the basis of the same circumstances.

    —  Flexibility: Some of the UK weaknesses noted by the Treasury in 1997 such as skill levels and workless households remain. The continuing reduction in unemployment coupled with the impact policy initiatives has helped to alleviate long-term unemployment. Unemployment is also falling in the euro area, although the pace of structural reforms (as noted above) has been subject to criticism. Whether the fall is a cyclical phenomenon or more permanent it is still early to tell. However with the increasing willingness across the EU to confront structural problems, it can be argued that flexibility is less of a problem today than it was in 1997.

    —  Investment: Greater macroeconomic stability in recent years has favoured investment, but many foreign investors complain that exchange rate instability outside EMU may discourage investment. Government figures (including mergers and acquisitions as well as new investment) show that the UK has continued to attract high inflows of inward investment, reaching a record figure in 1999, up 26 per cent on 1998. But a study by Ernst & Young (reported in the Financial Times, 30 May 2000) suggests that UK's share of new projects in the EU in 1999 dropped from 28 per cent to 24 per cent while euro-area countries France, Spain, Germany, The Netherlands, Ireland and Italy all recorded big investment increases. It is too early to ascribe any impact directly to the euro, but given the lags in the investment process, the likelihood is that the UK will be penalised by staying out of EMU.

    —  Impact on UK financial services particularly the City: Thus far the creation of EMU does not seem to have had much impact on the City and UK Financial Services. Consolidation has been taking place but this has primarily remained within national boundaries. Nevertheless, it is hard to see how British participation in stage 3 of EMU could damage the interests of the financial sector, whereas staying out could be a slippery slope. Hence for us this "test" can be interpreted only to favour membership.

    —  Employment and growth: It still remains the case that: "membership of EMU has the potential to enhance both growth and employment prospects."[3] With the euro area economy forecast to lead, rather than follow1 the "Anglo-Saxon" world in economic performance in the next couple of years, the immediate prospects are promising. Perhaps more important, the gradual coming together of economic management in the EU through the Luxembourg, Cardiff and Cologne processes should lead to more coherent economic management.

IMPLICATIONS OF ENLARGEMENT

  On the most optimistic scenario, enlargement of the EU to bring in some of the central and eastern European countries is three to four years away and much can happen in the foreign exchange markets over a period of this length. Even then, it is by no means certain that the new entrants would be allowed to join the single currency and might have to wait for some time before being eligible. If the five front runners were to join the EU, they would increase its population by about a sixth, but boost real GDP by less than half that proportion if measured in purchasing power parities and by about 3 per cent if measured in euros. To put the possible change in perspective, it would be the equivalent of adding a country of the economic weight of the Netherlands to the euro area. Since the mandate of the ECB is to set policy for the euro area as a whole, and thus to weight decisions according to the economic significance of different parts of the union, enlargement would not make much of a difference to this averaging process. There might conceivably be some adverse market sentiment based on a concern that the Central Bank Governors from new members would be less willing to favour price stability, but such a fear is likely to be proved unfounded for three main reasons:

    —  First, to join the euro, new members will have to fulfil the convergence criteria and to have put in place policies and legislation consistent with the acquis communautaire. Some of the candidates already do and the others aspire to, so that the risk of bringing in divergent economies is low.

    —  Second, central bankers tend to have common values which include a preference for price stability.

    —  Third, the Treaty provisions militate against individual members of the ECB Governing Council steering policy towards the needs of their countries.

  In short, any impact of enlargement will only manifest itself after a period of years and cannot be expected to be great even when it does.

CONCLUDING COMMENTS

  The implementation of stage 3 of EMU has, on balance, gone fairly smoothly, although the new institutional set-up is inevitably experiencing some teething troubles. The performance of the euro-area economies has been improving and looks to be soundly based. Although the fall in the euro presents the ECB with public relations and credibility problems, its impact on the euro area economy has been largely beneficial by enhancing growth without fuelling inflation.

  For the UK, the argument that the economic cycle is out of "synch" with the euro area looks much less convincing than it did two years ago. The slowdown in the UK economy in 1999 seems to have allowed the euro area to catch up and, with the difference between the two in output gaps set to fall away over the next 18 months, convergence from the perspective of monetary policy seems much closer.

  In the light of these conclusions, our view is that it is now time to assess the five tests and to move towards a decision on membership of the single currency.

NOTE

  The authors of this memorandum thank the ESRC for financial support under research project number L213252034. This project forms part of the "One Europe or Several?" Research Programme directed by Professor Helen Wallace.

June 2000


1   ECB European Central Bank (2000) Monthly Bulletin, May. Back

2   Alberola, E, Cervero, SG, Lopez, H and Ubide, A (1999) "Global Equilibrium Exchange Rates: Euro, Dollar, "Ins," "Outs," and Other Major Currencies in a Panel Conitegration Framework", IMF Working Paper, WP/99/175. Back

3   HM Treasury (1997) "UK Membership of the Single Currency: An Assessment of the Five Economic Tests" London: The Stationery Office. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 17 July 2000