Select Committee on Treasury Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum by Mr James Barty, Chief European Equities Economist, Deutsche Bank

  The Treasury Committee has asked the author of this report for his personal opinions on the issue of the UK and Economic and Monetary Union. The report that follows outlines those views.

  The Committee asked for comments on a number of issues including an assessment of the ECB's and euro area's economic performance since its inception. The general conclusion is that the euro area economy has performed well, with growth improving and inflation remaining under control. In my opinion, the ECB has conducted an appropriate monetary policy, albeit that there were some teething problems. The euro has struggled, but this is probably a cyclical rather than a structural phenomenon. In terms of convergence between members of the euro area, on whole I believe it is too early to draw definite conclusions although there are some worrying signs in the likes of Ireland.

  On the question of the UK's suitability for entry into EMU there are still significant problems in my opinion. The UK continues to meet the quantitative Maastricht criteria on debt, deficits, interest rates and inflation. However, there would need to be amendments to the Bank of England's statute to meet the independence criteria of the Treaty. More importantly, in my view, the UK continues to fail the exchange rate criteria. Much more stability is needed in the currency if this is to be met and that would require either a change to the Bank of England's mandate or entry into ERM 2, or both.

  In terms of the Chancellor's five tests, the key problem is the failure of the UK economy to converge with that of the euro area. What signs there are of convergence are largely the product of different monetary policy settings in the euro area and the UK. In my opinion it is still the case that euro area interest rates would be inappropriate for the UK economy.

  If the Government wants to ensure macro economic convergence with the euro area it needs to be more proactive and cannot rely merely on the attainment of economic stability to generate convergence. Two areas in particular need to be addressed, the lack of currency stability and the UK's greater sensitivity to short term interest rates.

  The views contained in this report are those of the author and not those of Deutsche Bank AG.

INTRODUCTION

  The Treasury Committee asked for written evidence on Economic and Monetary Union addressing the following issues:

    —  monetary conditions to date (in the Euro area), including the value of the Euro and its position as an international reserve currency, and the actions and structure of the European Central Bank;

    —  the performance and the future prospects of the Euro area economy and the progression of economic convergence between member states since the Euro's launch;

    —  whether developments in the Euro area economy and the UK economy have made any substantive difference to an assessment of whether the UK satisfies (i) the Maastricht convergence criteria(ii) the Government's "five economic tests";

    —  the implications for the Euro of enlargement of the EU;

    —  the National Changeover Plan and the level of preparation undertaken by (i) UK firms and (ii) the public sector for possible entry into Stage III of EMU.

  I intend to address the first three points, the latter two are outside my areas of expertise. This note is not intended to be all-encompassing and will not attempt to go over ground already covered by the considerable literature on the issue of UK entry into Economic and Monetary Union. It will instead directly address the issues identified above, outline developments since the Euro's launch and, finally, assess areas that need to be addressed if the UK wishes to enter EMU. The views expressed in this note are those of the author and not of the Deutsche Bank Group.

1.  MONETARY CONDITIONS, THE EURO AND THE ECB

(i)  Monetary Conditions

  Monetary conditions in the Euro area in the run up to EMU were broadly stable with the appreciating Euro (or more correctly the Euro-area currencies) being offset by falling interest rates, particularly outside the core (ie Germany, France and Benelux). The combined effect of exchange rate and interest rate moves can be captured by a monetary conditions index[4] (see Figure 1). This initially rose in early 1998 as the Euro appreciated, but then fell back as interest rates were cut in the second half of the year. This was in response to the need for short rates to converge ahead of EMU and to offset the negative effects of the Emerging Market crises.

  However, after the start of EMU monetary conditions were relaxed markedly as the Euro fell and then the ECB cut short rates to just 2.5 per cent in April 1999. As can be seen from the chart below this produced a sharp easing of monetary conditions. I would argue that such a marked easing of policy was justified as growth slowed markedly into 1999 (annual growth dropped below 2 per cent in the H1 99) and inflation on a core basis fell below 1 per cent. Indeed, while much was made of the sharp decline of the Euro, given the limited external exposure of the Euro area (around 15 per cent of GDP), a sizeable decline in the currency was needed to generate a stimulus to the economy. Indeed while the pace of decline of the Euro may have been worrying from a credibility perspective, it was not a major concern from a policy perspective.

  This phase of easier monetary policy conditions came to an end in November 1999 as the ECB decided to reverse its 50bp rate cut of the spring, as growth recovered and headline inflation headed higher. It has subsequently followed this with a further 125bp of tightening, the latest move taking place on 8 June. This interest rate tightening was initially offset by still further declines in the Euro. Indeed, when the Euro dropped below 90c against the US dollar in early May, the Deutsche Bank MCI was actually lower than when the ECB began tightening back in November. It is only with the latest interest rate tightening and rebound in the Euro that the MCI has started to rise again. It still indicates however that monetary conditions are loose in the Euro area.




  It is also useful to consider current versus neutral or equilibrium levels of interest rates and exchange rates, to get a feel for the stance of monetary policy. First interest rates. There are a number of methods that can be used to calculate the neutral level of the interest rate, and there are no hard and fast rules to decide on which to use but one that is often favoured is that derived from the so called Taylor rule. This states that central banks set interest rates above or below a neutral level depending on the deviation of inflation from its target level and the amount of spare capacity in the economy (usually measured by the gap between actual and potential GDP). In work carried out by my colleague Carlo Monticelli he calculates that the neutral level of interest rates in the Euro area is around 4.5 per cent. At 2.5 per cent rates last year were clearly below neutral, but with the recent move up to 4.25 per cent it could be argued that interest rates are now only moderately expansionary. The same would be difficult to say about the exchange rate. Over time Deutsche Bank has calculated a number of different measures for the equilibrium exchange rate, which point to a fair value against the US dollar of at least 1.15 and some in excess of 1.20. That would suggest that the Euro is still 15 per cent or more undervalued at current levels. The combined effect of interest and exchange rate levels would again suggest that monetary policy is expansionary.

  Money supply and credit growth in the Euro area would also lead to a similar conclusion. M3 money supply growth consistently ran above the ECB's 4.5 per cent reference value for the whole of last year. Over the last six months it has been running at above 6 per cent on average with a further acceleration to around 6.5 per cent in the latest months. Credit growth has been even more buoyant with annual growth rates consistently in double digits.

  Accordingly, the evidence would seem to suggest that the ECB has been running an expansionary policy through the course of its first 18 months in existence. With unemployment high, significant spare capacity in the Euro area and inflation (on the core measure) comfortably inside the ECB's target such a policy has, I believe, been justified. Going forward with the Euro area economy likely to extend its recovery and inflation to pick up (see Section 2), such a policy is likely to become increasingly less appropriate. I would therefore expect the ECB to continue to tighten monetary policy. The primary route for this is likely to be through interest rates, with the money markets currently discounting rates rising to a little over 5 per cent by the end of next year, a level that I think is broadly appropriate. Some recovery in the Euro is also likely towards its equilibrium level, particularly if the US economy slows as is generally expected.





(ii)  The Euro

  As I have discussed above the Euro has struggled in its first 18 months of its existence. It fell from a peak of 1.18 in January 1999 against the US dollar, to a low of around 0.89 in May of this year, before recovering to around 0.96 at the time of writing. Despite the recent recovery that still represents a drop of some 20 per cent. On a trade-weighted basis the decline has been more modest, but at 14 per cent it still represents a significant fall. At this stage there is little to say whether this drop in the Euro represents a lack of confidence in the fledgling currency or merely a cyclical swing in the currency. As can be seen from Figure 5, swings away from equilibrium for the Euro against the dollar are not unusual. Back in 1995 the Euro (or its synthetic equivalent) rose well above its equilibrium rate in a period when the dollar was weak and European currencies strong. Moreover, with the Euro area now a more closed area because of the single currency, it can be argued that the ECB can take a more relaxed attitude to the currency than the Bundesbank did in the past. Accordingly currency swings could become more exaggerated.

  In terms of the Euro's status as a reserve currency, the evidence suggests that the dollar remains the predominant reserve currency and as yet there has been little switching of central bank reserves into the Euro. Again it may be too early to draw conclusions from this and the fact that the Euro has been weak has probably acted as a deterrent to central banks altering their portfolios. In financial market terms though there has been more evidence of success for the Euro, with bond and equity issuance rising markedly in the aftermath of monetary union. Indeed, in terms of corporate bonds, Euro denominated issuance is comfortably outpacing dollar denominated issuance. Figures supplied to me by my colleagues at Deutsche Bank show total issuance since the start of 1999 to be Euro 484 billion for Euro issues agains US$ 396 billion for Dollar issues. While the currency may not have achieved an international reserve status its arrival has undoubtedly allowed the creation of a much deeper and larger financial market in Europe.


(iii)  Actions and Structure of the ECB

  The ECB's monetary policy stance has, I believe, been broadly appropriate, with policy eased in response to weak growth and falling inflation and then more recently re-tightened as the economy has recovered and inflation has picked up again. If the ECB is to be criticised it should be in the way it has conducted itself, often sending confusing messages both on likely changes in monetary policy and on the currency. This may reflect teething problems as the ECB was still finding its feet last year. However, it may also reflect its structure as with 17 members it has a large decision making body. In the long run, with further members to join, starting with Greece and continuing through to some of the EU aspirants, the current structure of the Governing Council will almost certainly have to be changed. The six-member Executive Board of the ECB will have to take on a much more dominating role.

2.  PERFORMANCE OF THE EURO AREA ECONOMY AND PROGRESSION OF ECONOMIC CONVERGENCE BETWEEN MEMBER STATES

(i)  Performance and Prospects for the Euro Area Economy

  As discussed briefly above, conditions in the Euro area economy at the start of monetary union were difficult. Growth was slowing in response to the impact of the emerging markets crises, with the German and Italian economies, in particular finding life difficult. Indeed growth in Germany virtually stalled over the winter of 1998-99 with annual growth dropping below 1 per cent for the whole of the first half of 1999. Growth for 1999 as a whole was a disappointing 1.5 per cent in Germany (down from 2.2 per cent in 1998) and just 1.4 per cent in Italy. The peripheral countries, Spain, Ireland, and Finland weathered the storm better as did France, where growth came in at almost double that of Germany in 1999. The differences between growth performance came from two factors. First, Germany and Italy were more exposed to the emerging market countries than the others and accordingly their export sectors suffered more. Second and probably more importantly both lacked strong domestic demand as low real wage increases and continuing fiscal tightening constrained consumer spending.

  The easing of monetary conditions detailed above, particularly in the first half of the year, and a turnaround in the global economy, triggered a recovery in the Euro area economy. Growth having averaged little more than a 2 per cent annual rate through Q4 1998 to Q2 1999, accelerated to 3.6 per cent annualised in the second half of 1999. This recovery was led by the industrial sector where growth, having slowed to a halt for most of the first half, had accelerated to 5 per cent year on year by the early months of this year. With most surveys continuing to show buoyant conditions, the latest EU Commission survey saw consumer confidence hit a new record high and business confidence match its previous record; the recovery seems set to continue through the course of this year. Indeed, the Deutsche Bank official forecast is for growth in the Euro area as a whole to accelerate from 2.4 per cent last year to 3.5 per cent this year. Indeed, as can be seen from Figure 11 only Italy is expected to see growth below 3 per cent this year.

  Inflation has remained subdued since the start of EMU with the core measure oscillating around the 1 per cent level. Headline inflation has been more volatile dropping below 1 per cent in late 1998 and early 1999 as falling oil prices impacted. From the middle of the year onwards, however, headline inflation started to rise as oil prices began to recover, rising to 1.7 per cent by the end of 1999. In early 2000 it continued to rise, breaching the ECB's 2 per cent ceiling in March. Although it has fallen back below 2 per cent since, Deutsche Bank forecasts that it is likely to remain at or close to 2 per cent for some months to come.









  While such a rise in headline inflation might at first sight appear troubling for the ECB, the bulk of the upward move has come from higher oil prices. Indeed, as the chart shows, core inflation has been more stable, with the year-on-year rate currently 1.3 per cent. There are some signs though that core inflation is starting to pick up, with the three-month annualised measure of DBCI (Deutsche Bank core inflation) rising to 1.44 per cent in the latest month, largely reflecting the impact of the feed-through from higher oil prices and the weak Euro. This measure has a good track record of predicting future movements of the year-on-year core rate and Deutsche Bank expects core inflation to rise above 1.5 per cent by the year end.

  There may well be more cyclical pressure on inflation going forward as the Euro area economy continues to recover. Indeed, on Deutsche Bank estimates, which show growth of 3.5 per cent this year and next, the output gap (a measure of spare capacity in the economy) will be closed and even move into positive territory. There will therefore be an incentive for the ECB to push rates up to slow growth next year. That, in turn, will mean that the decline in unemployment which has dropped from 10.5 per cent at the end of 1998 to 9.2 per cent in the latest month (April) is likely to slow too. Indeed, most projections suggest that Euro-area unemployment will level out at or above 8 per cent. This reflects the higher natural rates of unemployment in the Euro area, which most economists, myself included, attribute to the still inflexible labour markets in most Euro area economies.

  On the whole I would conclude that the Euro area economy has performed reasonably well in its first 18 months of life. The more difficult challenges for the ECB lie ahead, as spare capacity is absorbed and it has to head off any cyclical inflationary pressures. In particular it is likely to find that some economies are running into bottlenecks much faster than others.

(ii)  Progression of Economic Convergence

  The evidence of economic convergence since the start of EMU is mixed. If we look at the charts on GDP growth (Figures 10 and 11) there certainly does appear to be some convergence on this front, particularly if the forecasts for 2000 prove correct. Whereas in 1998 the lowest growth rate was 1.2 per cent below the rate for the Euro area as a whole, that had narrowed to 1 per cent last year and this year is projected by Deutsche Bank to fall to just 0.8 per cent. The picture is more stable on the high side. Ignoring Ireland, which is just way ahead of everybody else the strongest growing country outpaced the Euro area by 1.2 per cent in 1998, 1.3 per cent in 1999 but narrowing to a projected 1 per cent in 2000. Even in Ireland, the gap between its growth rate and the Euro area is expected to narrow (on DB estimates) from 6.6 per cent last year to 5 per cent this year. Whether anything can be read into this convergence is unclear as it may just be cyclical and even three years is only a very short time period over which to judge this.

  The inflation picture is less clear. The gap between Euro area HICP and the lowest HICP is steady at 0.5 per cent in 1998, 1999 and 2000, although the highest, which is Ireland, in all three years shows a widening gap from 1.1 per cent in 1998 to 1.4 per cent in 1999 and a projected 2.7 per cent in 2000. While there are some special factors distorting the Irish inflation rate particularly in the current year (eg higher tobacco duty), inflationary conditions in Ireland do appear to have deteriorated relative to the Euro area. Outside Ireland however the picture is more encouraging with the highest inflation rate being 1.1 per cent above the Euro area rate in 1998 and 1999, but projected to narrow by DB to 0.9 per cent this year.

  More evidence should be forthcoming in the next few years as the stronger growing economies eliminate their spare capacity faster than the slower growing economies. This is already becoming evident in countries like Ireland and to a lesser extent Finland, Spain and Portugal. These countries have seen rapid credit growth, strong domestic demand, and in Ireland signs of labour shortages and wage and price pressures. If these trends continue then their inflation performance may start to deteriorate relative to other Euro area countries. Even this may not be undesirable in the medium term as price and wage levels in the less well off Euro area countries (eg Portugal, Spain, Ireland to a lesser extent) should converge with those in the better off countries. This is desirable, providing productivity rates converge too. Equally, those countries experiencing rapid credit growth now could find that they are more susceptible to rising interest rates going forward and therefore will slow more sharply as the ECB moves to a tighter policy stance.








  It is difficult to draw an overall conclusion on whether there has been convergence or not. To be sure there are some worrying developments in Ireland, which if they spread to other countries would signal potential problems. However, again it is far too early to draw definite conclusions.

3.  CHANGES IN THE ASSESSMENT OF WHETHER THE UK SATISFIES THE MAASTRICHT CONVERGENCE CRITERIA AND THE GOVERNMENT'S FIVE ECONOMIC TESTS

(i)  The Maastricht Convergence Criteria

  There are six criteria to be met to satisfy the Maastricht Treaty for entry into EMU. The UK has consistently met the ones on debt, deficits, interest rates and inflation and in the last couple of years this is even more the case now than a couple of years ago. Inflation has fallen further with the Harmonised CPI currently just 0.6 per cent; accordingly the UK is not just within 1.5 per cent of the average of the lowest three inflation rates but has the lowest inflation rate in the EU. Equally, the budget surplus and consequent declining government debt more than comfortably meet the 3 per cent of GDP deficit and 60 per cent of GDP debt limits. The combination of lower inflation and falling debt levels has allowed 10 year government bond yields to within a few basis points of those in Germany. So again the 200bp limit is more than comfortably achieved.

  Where the UK does struggle is on the central bank independence criteria and, most importantly of all, the exchange rate stability criteria. Although the Bank of England is independent in making its decisions there are a number of areas where the current statute fails to meet the Maastricht Criteria. The Chancellor retains the right to intervene in exceptional circumstances; he sets the inflation target while the Monetary Policy Committee rather than the Governor alone sets interest rates. All of these would have to change if the Bank of England is to be independent as defined by the Maastricht Criteria. That, however, would be relatively simple to achieve should the government so wish, given the size of its majority in Parliament.


4   The monetary conditions index is a weighted average of exchange rate and interest rate indices. Deutsche Bank uses a 15 per cent weight for the exchange rate and 85 per cent for interest rates. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 17 July 2000