Select Committee on Treasury Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum by Mr James Barty, Chief European Equities Economist, Deutsche Bank

Table 1

MAASTRICHT CONVERGENCE CRITERIA

  
Time Period
Criterion
UK
1.  Inflation

Inflation to be within 1.5% of average of three members with the lowest inflation rates Based on lowest three EMU members (on inflation)
12m to March 2000
2.47
1.15
Based on lowest three EU members (on inflation)
  
2.38
  
2.  Fiscal balance

General government net borrowing (% GDP)
1999
3% or less
-1.2
3.  General government gross debt

General government debt % of GDP
End 1999
60% or less
46
4.  Average nominal long term interest rates

UK yields to be within 200bp of average of the three members with the lowest inflation rates

Based on lowest three EMU members (on inflation)
12m to May 2000
7.26
5.36
Based on lowest three EU members (on inflation)
  
7.39
  
Source: Deutsche Bank estimates





  The real problem is the exchange rate criterion. The Maastricht Treaty states that to qualify a currency must fulfil the following: "The observance of the normal fluctuation margins provided for by the exchange rate mechanism of the EMS, for at least two years, without devaluing against the currency of any Member State". Even if it is accepted that a currency can qualify without entering ERM2 (which is debatable since every country that has entered EMU has been a member of the ERM before entry), it is not clear that sterling would qualify as being stable enough. In theory over the last two years one could make a case that sterling had fluctuated within a plus or minus 15 per cent band (which is the official band range for ERM2) around its average rate over that period. Indeed, the average rate for sterling against the Deutsche Mark over the last two years is very close to DEM3.0, and peak of DEM3.41 and trough of DEM2.74 would represent a fluctuation band of plus or minus 10 per cent. I believe that would be stretching the point particularly as the normal fluctuation bands at the time the Maastricht Treaty was drawn up were either plus or minus 2.25 per cent or more generously plus or minus 6 per cent. Sterling would fail on either of those criteria.

  It is also far from clear that DEM3.0 would be a reasonable entry rate for the UK into EMU. Most economists would argue that the equilibrium rate is a good deal lower than that, with a range of DEM 2.6-2.8 often quoted (a range with which I broadly agree). Interestingly, if the time horizon over which sterling's stability is expanded—to four years—the average rate over the period drops to DEM2.87, but the fluctuation range becomes plus or minus 23 per cent.

  Accordingly, in my opinion, the UK convincingly fails the exchange rate criterion at the moment. If the government wants to prepare the economy for EMU entry at some point, some alteration to the Bank of England's mandate to focus more on currency stability is likely to be necessary. However politically unpalatable, membership of ERM2 may even need to be considered—indeed it would seem odd for a government to be prepared to fix a currency in perpetuity but unwilling to join an exchange rate mechanism with 15 per cent bands. In my view, the government's hope that macroeconomic stability alone will lead to currency stability is not particularly realistic. The US would score very well on macroeconomic stability through the 1990s and yet the dollar has oscillated substantially against the European currencies.





(ii)  The Chancellor's Five Economic Tests

  These are as follows:

    (a)  Are business cycles and economic structures compatible so that we and others could live comfortably with Euro interest rates on a permanent basis?

    (b)  If problems emerge is there sufficient flexibility to deal with them?

    (c)  Would joining EMU create better conditions for firms making long term decisions to invest in Britain?

    (d)  What impact would entry into EMU have on the competitive position of the UK's financial services industry, particularly the City's wholesale markets?

    (e)  In summary, will joining EMU promote higher growth, stability and a lasting increase in jobs?

  To a certain extent these tests overlap. Indeed, I would argue that if the first four tests are met the fifth will almost certainly be met. It is the first two questions, however, that cut to the core of the issue of whether the UK could successfully enter and remain in monetary union.

(a)  Are business cycles and economic structures compatible so that we and others could live comfortably with Euro interest rates on a permanent basis?

  In its assessment in October 1997 the Treasury concluded that "the UK is not convergent enough to commit to joining in the first wave". It argued that the economic cycle was not in line with others in the EU, that it was not clear enough that the shocks that had caused the UK to diverge in the past would cease to be a problem. Indeed, it argued that if the UK joined EMU too soon that there was a risk that rates would be too low for price stability in the UK. It went on to state that the UK needed a period of economic stability to demonstrate that convergence was sustainable.

  In my opinion little has changed over the last 2½ years to alter that judgement. There is little evidence that the correlation between the UK and Euro-area cycles has improved. In work carried out by my colleague George Buckley at Deutsche Bank, and shown in the table below, the addition of the years since 1987 makes little difference to the correlation co-efficients calculated by the Treasury in its 1997 assessment. If we look at 1980-2000 and compare it to 1979-1996 (which the Treasury used), there is little difference in the correlations reported. The only slight change is a small improvement in the correlation with the German economy, although it is still little better than zero. If we shorten the time horizon and look at 1992-2000, again there is a further improvement in the correlation with the German economy, although the correlation with France drops. However, it is worth illustrating just how sensitive these calculations are to the time periods used. If we move the calculations forward just one year to 1993-2000 the correlation with the US drops sharply from 40 per cent to 27 per cent, while that with Gemany jumps to 47 per cent. While it is possible that the UK cycle is more correlated with that in Europe in recent years, the evidence is far from conclusive. What we do know is that the correlation between the UK and Germany and France in all of these calculations is way lower than that between France and Germany, which hit 74 per cent between 1993 and 2000.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 17 July 2000