Select Committee on Treasury Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 40 - 59)

TUESDAY 13 JUNE 2000

MR JAMES BARTY, PROFESSOR IAIN BEGG, MR ROGER BOOTLE, PROFESSOR WILLEM BUITER AND DR DANIEL GROS

Sir Michael Spicer

  40. I just have a supplementary on that: that depends on the goodwill of the European Central Bank, does it not? They would not have to appear before national parliaments at all; they have entire discretion as to who they appear before as well as setting the rules.
  (Dr Gros) I was not suggesting that the European Central Bank has to go to every national parliament; on the contrary—that national parliaments send observers to the European Parliament so they can help the EP in its decision-making. It would be too much for the ECB personnel to go around to fifteen national parliaments.

Sir Teddy Taylor

  41. I have a question for Professor Buiter because I think he is aware that there was a creation of panic in this Committee and also throughout the country when he said in "Alice in Euroland" on 17 March last year, "The legal framework, institutional arrangements and emerging operational practices of the ECB . . . are flawed and in urgent need of modification . . . They could put the common currency's survival at risk.", and now we find a document here called "Britain in Europe" which some people would regard as rather enthusiastic propaganda for the whole business. What I am really wondering is, in view of the worries we all had, when you said that the common currency's survival could be at risk because of the whole business being flawed and in need of modification, what has changed your mind and what changes have taken place in the ECB since you expressed these rather alarming sentiments?
  (Professor Buiter) I have not changed my mind. Even when I wrote that, I still stated very clearly if you read the rest of the article—

  42. I read it all.
  (Professor Buiter)—that, despite my reservations on especially the accountability, openness and transparency of the ECB, I favoured not just monetary union as it had taken place but also a UK participation in that. I do think that no operationally independent central bank can, in the long term, survive in a democratic polity unless it is truly accountable to the duly constituted Parliamentary body. Accountability, of course, requires transparency and openness and, in my view, there were deficiencies and there continue to be deficiencies as regards the openness and transparency, and that would have to do with the publication of votes—indeed, the practice of voting at meetings—and the publication of a proper set of minutes related to the deliberations of the rate-setting committee, the ECB Council. I think the ECB, without making any formal change in its operating procedures, has showed great awareness of the need to try and explain itself so something like what the MPC achieves through its minutes is now achieved through extensive briefings, both orally and in writing, about the deliberations and the considerations that went to the decision. But they have a very different model—a consensus model of decision-making—which involves no voting, or only in exceptional circumstances, and therefore basically decision-making by unanimity. We in the UK have a model of collective decision-makers, individual accountability, the practice of always taking individual votes. That is closer to the kind of transparency that is required to make a non-elected body of Eurocrats and technocrats acceptable, a body with a real policy role in the current monetary arrangement in Euroland. These arrangements are evolving. As we meet a year from now to comment on the first 30 months of the ECB, the European Parliament, if no other body, will have insisted on more effective accountability of the ECB.

  43. When you talk about the legal framework and institutional arrangements, these have not changed at all. If you think that the common currency's survival is still at risk, why are you recommending other countries to get involved in it? Were you overstating yourself here?
  (Professor Buiter) Political legitimacy is necessary for any institution to survive. To me, political legitimacy requires a measure of openness, accountability and transparency that is greater than the one currently in effect. That applies to many institutions, not just in Euroland, but in national economies, including the United Kingdom. No institution's viability can ever be taken for granted.

  44. What changes are required in the legal framework?
  (Professor Buiter) This is specifically in connection with the size of the deliberative body. There are 17 now. With the four coming in there would be 21. With ten accession countries it would be 31. That is two and a half football teams. It is too large. There are going to have to be serious institutional reforms, not just there but in the European Union institutions as a whole, to get away from the automatic presumption that every nation automatically has a seat on the board or the Council or whatever. We have to go towards more qualified majority decision making there as well.

  45. I thought the ECB did vote by majority.
  (Professor Buiter) They do not vote at all, de facto. These decisions are by consensus. They could vote if they wanted to but that is a practice that they have evolved among themselves, just as our practice of voting is not laid down in the Treaty.

Mrs Blackman

  46. Can we attribute the trend rate of growth enjoyed by countries within Euroland to the euro by itself or would they be enjoying similar rates of growth in any event, given the retreat of the damage done by the emerging markets crisis?
  (Professor Buiter) One can conceive of a set of national monetary policies in what is now the Euroland area that would have achieved similar overall macroeconomic stimulus. Monetary policy, on balance, has been rather loose in Euroland since the start and appropriately so, but you could have mimicked that in a technical way by having 11 national monetary authorities on average loosening up. The degree of coordination achieved by having this common institution would have been very hard to mimic. The growth in Euroland is not just cyclical. The weakening of the euro has helped. The low interest rates have helped to give a conjunctural stimulus but despite those who insist on pointing out the rigidities in Euroland there has been a history of reform since the late eighties or the mid eighties that has made the supply side receptive to this more relaxed monetary policy. We are seeing the beginnings now, even in the least reformist areas of Euroland, of an awareness of the need for measures to implement supply side reforms that will ensure that an appropriate monetary policy of the kind conducted by the ECB is translated into real growth and low unemployment, rather than higher prices.
  (Mr Barty) What entry into the monetary union does for a number of these countries is to get them to focus on the microeconomics. They no longer have real control over the macroeconomic tools. They clearly do not have control over monetary policy. Their ability to move on fiscal policy is limited by Maastricht criteria. The evidence we have—it is slow at the moment—is that countries are looking at their labour markets and saying, "What do we need to do to free up labour markets?" Clearly, it is the case in many European countries that their labour markets are not as flexible as ours or those in the United States, but I think we are going to move along that road. I think you will see tax reforms coming through as well so from that perspective monetary union has been a stimulus to force governments to look at the microeconomic policies which in the past they had ignored because they had been able to pull macroeconomic levers instead.

  47. These kinds of structural reforms will ultimately, one assumes, lead to more convergence along with the monetary climate that is set strategically. Do you see real signs of convergence at the moment amongst different economies? It is really achievable?
  (Mr Barty) Over time you can see convergence between the European economies. One of the pieces from one of my colleagues at Deutsche Bank which went into this document shows that, if you look at the correlation between French and German growth rates through the course of the 1990s, it is almost 75 per cent. That is a very strong correlation. A lot of those countries paid the price for that. France in particular had the Franc fort policy for a long period of time. It fixed its exchange rate to that of Germany. They then mimicked the Bundesbank's monetary policy and achieved convergence in that way. It is going to be interesting to see how these countries sustain convergence over time inside monetary union, but obviously as trade links between the countries increase that should help convergence. The point on microeconomic reform is that it does not necessarily increase convergence. Liberalisation of financial markets can act in the opposite direction and make some economies more volatile. If you have microeconomic liberalisation, it increases the ability of an economy to flexibly adjust to any macroeconomic problems and that is where these micro reforms will help.

Sir Michael Spicer

  48. Professor Begg, in the interesting article which we have read entitled "Regional Adjustment Mechanisms" you conclude: "EMU is unlikely to be threatened in the short term by the inadequacy of regional adjustment mechanisms but as an aspect of the Union it will need to be addressed. Either the EMU itself will have to acquire new competencies together with budgetary and administrative means to fulfil them or Member States will have to recover some of their powers to intervene." Which of these do you prefer? Which do you think is likely to happen?
  (Professor Begg) I will give you a typical economist's answer: both. What happens under EMU is plainly you have lost an adjustment mechanism, the exchange rate or independent monetary policy, which are in practice the same thing. Therefore, you need to work on how other adjustment mechanisms can be brought into play to achieve the same ambitions. It may be that flexibility on the supply side, which is much more a Member State or even sub-national competence, is something that will have to be reinforced under EMU as we try to reconfigure the policy framework. There is also the case for some degree of top down fiscal stabilisation. That necessarily means a European level financing power of some sort. It need not be huge. Some of the work that has been done by the Commission suggests that you can achieve European level stabilisation from regional or national shocks with a relatively small budget, of the order of 0.4 of a percentage point of GDP. It is not the structural funds which are long term in their ambitions. It is something more akin to what you find in the US through the transfer of welfare benefits, which will attenuate a downturn or relative upturn in state economies. That is the sort of thing which has to be considered at least at European level. I know it is anathema to many in Britain to say, "Let us give more money to Europe to play with", but this is a macroeconomic proposition, not one about giving them more money to spend.

  49. Top down financial stability is a euphemism for a new central taxation system?
  (Professor Begg) Yes, but on a very limited scale.

  50. If you accept that there is to be immobility of labour between countries and therefore a continuation of pretty massive structural deviations and variations within Euroland, in order to compensate the countries that will be badly affected by this, these funds are going to have to be quite substantive, are they not?
  (Professor Begg) No. The stabilisation function is a macroeconomic proposition which can be done with relatively little money. You should then simultaneously be working on freeing up markets, ensuring that there is greater capacity for labour mobility.

  51. We are talking about labour markets between countries. Nobody is suggesting that any kind of freeing up is going to result in greater labour mobility between countries.
  (Professor Begg) In the paper, we itemise nine different mechanisms which come into play. I would not want to rely on any of them singly but rather put together an entire package which give you greater scope for adjustment.

  52. You have been honest and said there will need to be some new central taxation system, in your view. That is clearly on the record. Would anybody disagree with that?
  (Professor Buiter) Yes. I do not think that, for stabilisation purposes, any central, federal level fiscal policy is necessary. Anything that can be done by a federal level, by a European stabilisation authority using nation specific transfer payments or whatever, can be achieved equally well from a stabilisation point of view by national or even sub-national government entities having automatic fiscal stabilisation or discretionary fiscal instruments at their disposal. It is a very different issue if you talk about serious redistribution between regions or nations of Europe or if we talk about long term structural reform which you wish to subsidise out of centrally raised and centrally provided funds. That is a matter of political priorities, a matter of political cohesion, but there is nothing that Brussels can do for national stabilisation that nations cannot deliver equally well themselves.

  53. If that is the case and there could be, in your view, greater freedom given, from a stabilisation point of view, to national fiscal authorities, would that not run counter to the requirements that monetary and fiscal policy at central European level should be at least in coherence and in sync with each other?
  (Professor Buiter) No. It would be desirable to have a mechanism for coordinating Euroland wide fiscal and monetary policy. It is not being coordinated now. What has to be decided at the centre is the balance between the average fiscal stance in Euroland and the Euroland wide monetary policy. That still leaves individual nations or sub-national entities to divide the average stance among the nations in a way that corresponds to their possibly different cyclical positions.

  54. You have accepted that it would be desirable as part of the monetary union to have a central fiscal authority?
  (Professor Buiter) No. I think there has to be coordination to make sure that the sum of the fiscal stances of the 11 Members adds up to something that makes sense from the point of view of the balance of monetary policy and fiscal policy.

  55. The coordinating body would have to have some authority. You could not just have a coordinating body which had no authority.
  (Professor Buiter) It would have to be a coordinating body which would have the authority to set a total deficit space in Euroland, but there does not have to be an independent, central tax or transfer mechanism.

  Sir Michael Spicer: That is not accepted by the rest of your colleagues, I do not think.

Chairman

  56. Do we not have the Maastricht criteria already? Is that not a coordinating structure?
  (Professor Buiter) I would not say that is the coordinating mechanism. That is simply a response to the perceived fear by the founders of national governments left to their own devices being prone to excessive debt and deficit spirals. It is a set of ceilings. To use nationally differentiated fiscal stabilisation, nations would have to be sufficiently far below these norms that there is enough room on the upside not to hit the ceilings when times get rough. In principle, the national, fiscal stabilisers, both automatic and discretionary, can operate once a country locates itself, as Britain is now already, sufficiently far south of the Maastricht and Stability and Growth ceilings not to be bound by them in the course of cyclical fluctuations.

  57. You said that you thought that, for stabilisation purposes, it was not required to have a central, fiscal taxation gathering authority, but that you thought there might be political reasons in terms of distribution of income for having such an authority. Are they not two sides of the same coin? If you have great disparities of wealth and economic well-being between different parts of a single monetary union, can it really be the case that that monetary union can remain as a stable entity?
  (Professor Buiter) We have had very wide disparities in levels of income and wealth within the United Kingdom without the country blowing apart.

  58. The United Kingdom authorities do have and indeed use the means very extensively to distribute moneys from one part of the country that they consider to be wealthy to other parts of the country. That is exactly what happens. That is why there is some element of stability within the country.
  (Professor Buiter) I agree that there is a political argument that, if an area is going to have a certain degree of political integration and common institutions, that will be accompanied by effective political pressure for a greater redistributive element and greater common support for desirable structural projects and things like that. That is not a matter of economics but of society. I fully accept that. If integration means anything, at some point it will mean that you want to express the common identity by some sort of fiscal means. It is not a stabilisation issue.

Mr Fallon

  59. Can we move from fiscal coordination to economic policy coordination? Are you able to comment on the adoption within the broad economic policy guidelines of the power of ECOFIN now to review Member States' public expenditure programmes? Do you see that power being used increasingly?
  (Professor Begg) No. I do not think ECOFIN or any other European body is ever going to say, "Here is what you may or may not spend your money on." What they may say is, "We are concerned about your fiscal balance", which is purely the difference between the two aggregates of public expenditure and taxation. They would never get into the detail.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 17 July 2000