Select Committee on Treasury Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 60 - 79)

TUESDAY 13 JUNE 2000

MR JAMES BARTY, PROFESSOR IAIN BEGG, MR ROGER BOOTLE, PROFESSOR WILLEM BUITER AND DR DANIEL GROS

  60. You are aware that in their February conclusions they did give themselves the power to review Member States' public expenditure programmes?
  (Professor Begg) Yes, but not in the sense of saying, "Here is what you may spend money on".

  61. What does reviewing Member States' public expenditure programmes mean?
  (Professor Buiter) In relation to the tax programmes, it is just an elaboration of the stability of growth criteria. It is a stabilisation story, not national priorities about the size of the public sector issue.

  62. Do you think peer pressure within ECOFIN or within the Euro 11 or 12 is sufficient to bring about the degree of economic policy coordination that might be required?
  (Professor Buiter) That is a good question. I do not know the answer to that. Logistically, even if everybody is willing to coordinate the fiscal stance, it is much harder to get coordination between one central authority amongst 11 or ten and a half national, fiscal authorities, than in the United Kingdom, where you have one on one interaction. Subject to the point of the logistics, it can be done and will increasingly be done. The proposals to give Euro 11 a greater voice in these stabilisation matters are the logical outcome of this kind of thinking.
  (Professor Begg) I think it is getting there very slowly. There was a vacuum in the core of the EMU policy framework when the Maastricht Treaty was drawn up which was the absence of an explicit means of coordinating fiscal policy. With the Luxembourg, Cardiff and Cologne processes, what political scientists call the soft policy approach to all this—that is to say, there is no Treaty base for it and there is no directive—but what they are doing is engaging in these forms of bench marking and coordination which are getting towards a coordinating mechanism for the major design of policy, but it is not going to get into the detail of which particular supply side policies the country uses. Nor is it going to get into the detail of what public expenditure programmes or taxation instruments are used. It is the grand, strategic design of it.

Mr Davey

  63. I would like to ask this question to all of our witnesses. Do you agree with the OECD that the United Kingdom has been converging in recent months with Euroland and that that convergence is set to continue so that by the end of next year it is likely that the Chancellor's first economic text on convergence will have been met?
  (Mr Bootle) No, I do not think I do agree, except in a very superficial sense. The phrase used in the original document which propounded the Chancellor's economic tests talked about sustainable convergence. The word "sustainable" is very important. We are not talking about certain macroeconomic variables coming into alignment, whether they are going to cross over or not. We are talking about something much deeper. However, one would expect them to converge in that narrow sense as a precondition for them to converge in a sustainable sense. To that degree, some of them were a bit closer in that growth rates are reasonably similar. There was a time when the United Kingdom was very much faster. The inflation rates are also reasonably similar. Interest rates having moved up strongly in the Eurozone recently are looking as though they may have peaked or nearly peaked in the United Kingdom. Arguably on the interest rate front too, there is something like convergence. At the long end of the yield curve there has been something like convergence for a long time. For all those types of things there is something like superficial convergence but I do not think it amounts to very much in that what one wants is evidence that structures, institutions and practices, as well as the movement of the economic cycle, make such a convergence sustainable and not just something that will last a year or two. If one focuses very narrowly on the question of interest rates, there are several features here that are interactive. Our inflation rate is very similar to the level in Euroland. In fact, it is a good deal lower. This morning on the HICP measure I saw that inflation fell even further to 0.5 per cent in Britain. Does anyone seriously suppose that, if we had 4.25 per cent interest rates in the United Kingdom, even without the fall in the exchange rate that most advocates for joining the euro would suggest was a necessary precondition, we would be at anything like this level of inflation? I certainly would not. One puts together four per cent-ish interest rates with an exchange rate at a plausible entry level, 2.70 or so, and surely the apparent convergence with regard to inflation would add up to divergence.
  (Professor Buiter) The usual measures of convergence have shown, since the start of 1999, that the gaps between the United Kingdom and the average of Euroland have diminished. These kinds of score cards are so transitory that I would not personally pay much attention to them. Nothing is ever going to be in sync, perfectly or lastingly. The only question is what is the magnitude of the likely deviations and what are the mechanisms for dealing with them once the monetary instrument is thrown away? It is true however that, since one of the most important reasons for divergent cyclical behaviour is independent, national monetary policies, the data we are going to get are always going to give an overblown view of the underlying degree of divergence that can be expected following monetary union. Once you throw the monetary key away, that particular impulse towards divergence is dead. There will be sector specific shocks that impact on different nations differentially. Yes, the OECD is right but it is also not very interesting. The real issue is not are we at the same point or even: are we likely to be ships passing in the night, but rather: even though we know we are ships passing in the night how far away are we going to be before the gaps close up again. I think it is basically a non-issue.

Chairman

  64. It is the Chancellor's major economic test actually.
  (Professor Buiter) The kind of convergence we will have following monetary union will be sufficient to operate the Common Monetary Policy efficiently without adverse impacts to the British economy. Clearly, if we had joined earlier, we would not have had the current level of interest rates. I think this is something that will be judged appropriately when the political will is there and not until then.

Mr Davey

  65. It is a question of political will rather than some economic test?
  (Professor Buiter) Yes.
  (Professor Begg) I think it is interesting that in an OECD report of 160-odd pages there are two paragraphs on convergence which have grabbed all the headlines. It is based essentially on their examination of what are called output gaps. Output gaps are a particularly tricky concept because there are two different ways of measuring them. Some of you might think it is peculiar that you can have a positive output gap. In other words, your economy is operating above potential, which is what projections for 2001 that I have in front of me show from the OECD. The United Kingdom is projected next year, 2001, to have an output gap of 0.9 of a percentage point and the Euro area 0.8. In the narrow terms in which this debate has been couched, that is plainly convergence. They are at the same points in the economic cycle. However, I do question whether the notion of an economic cycle is quite so useful as it used to be in the past when it coincided quite closely with parliamentary cycles. What we now find is that the United Kingdom economy has been through two cycles in the last 20 years, the first starting in 1981 going to 1990, the second starting roughly in 1992 and continuing. We do not have the deterministic four or five year cycles we used to have. Whether this means that the Chancellor has succeeded in achieving his abolition of boom and bust or not is a question I leave to the Committee. There is an interesting paradox that a government which tells us it has abolished boom and bust is relying on boom or bust as an argument for not entering the euro. In other words, the cyclical test is being used for something which no longer seems to be relevant. I would also commend to your attention a notion, using another of the Chancellor's favourites words, "endogenous", of endogenous convergence. What tends to happen once countries join the currency area is that other aspects of their economy other than their monetary policy tend to change. Would any of you have believed that Ireland or Spain today would have the combination of growth rate and inflation rate that they have? I doubt it. What has happened is that the labour market institutions in those countries have adapted quite considerably as a result of membership of the single currency. That is putting a downward pressure on the inflation rate. It seems to me that convergence is something that happens not just before you join a monetary union but also afterwards and as a direct result of joining.
  (Mr Barty) I would slightly disagree with some of what Professor Begg has said, in particular the idea that you can rely on some endogenous convergence after you have entered. You would have to be quite closely converged before you would consider entering. One of the things I would definitely agree with that Mr Bootle said is that, if you had put the United Kingdom and the Euro area on the same monetary stance since the start of monetary union, there is no way that we would have converged. I thought the OECD report was particularly badly worded. They said there would still be a gap in terms of interest rates but that could quickly be eliminated if the United Kingdom entered monetary union, without referring to what the implications of that reduction of gap in interest rates would mean. They also mentioned the exchange rate and the exchange rate, to my mind, is a major problem for the United Kingdom going into monetary union in the near future. The currency is still significantly overvalued, despite the recent decline. The monetary policy stance run by the Bank of England over the last year has been much, much tighter than that run by the ECB. Whilst on a superficial level, if you look at rates of inflation, rates of growth, output gaps, however you define them, bond yields, you can say the United Kingdom is much more converged with the Euro area, to ignore the fact that the monetary policy settings have been completely different misses the point altogether.

  66. I think it is interesting that our four witnesses have not agreed with the OECD report and I would tend to agree with our witnesses, that the United Kingdom is not terribly well converged, not sustainably, but given that it is the Chancellor of the Exchequer's first test—and presumably if the current government wins the next election it will be one of the tests that is applied for the United Kingdom membership—what would each of you again think that the Chancellor needs to do to try to promote greater convergence? What policies should he be pursuing?
  (Mr Barty) There are two very clear areas that you need to address. One is the short term interest rate sensitivity of the United Kingdom economy. I fundamentally disagree with those who say that the main reason the United Kingdom's cycle is out of line with the rest of Europe is differences in our trade patterns. Frankly, the differences in our trade patterns are not that significantly different from those in the rest of Europe to make that much difference to our economic cycle. We are just much more sensitive to short term interest rates. That is partly a historical phenomenon. Our mortgage debt has been primarily funded at short term interest rates and our corporate debt also, so when there is an adjustment in interest rates in the United Kingdom the transmission mechanism is much more aggressive than it is elsewhere. To this day, the Bank of England is still worried about the housing market, where house price inflation is 15 per cent and we have short rates of six.

  67. We need more standard banks, do we?
  (Mr Barty) That is one route. Certainly in the mortgage market, you have to extend the duration of the interest rate agreements which govern mortgage interest rates. Although there has been a move towards more fixing of mortgage payments, in the United Kingdom you need to be quite careful of that because a lot of those fixed agreements are for one, two or three years; whereas in continental Europe they are for 15 years or plus. If the United Kingdom wants to make a success of entry into the monetary union, you would have to move much further down that route. The government could address that probably several fold. It could certainly make it, from a regulatory angle, much more advantageous for mortgage lenders to offer fixed rate mortgages, which is not the case at the moment. There is still a bias from their perspective to offer floating rate mortgages. On the currency side, the government's line that we need to ensure economic stability and then economic stability will bring currency stability does not wash. If you look at what is happening in the US, the US has a great record on having macroeconomic stability. The Fed, over the last decade, has delivered very sensible growth rates, very low inflation, the fiscal side has been a lot better and the dollar continues to oscillate substantially against the euro. If we are going to offer sensible, sustainable convergence, you have to either change the Bank of England's mandate in order to ensure that you shadow the euro more effectively, or even consider joining ERM2. I find it bizarre that a government that says it is prepared to take the United Kingdom into a single currency is not prepared to enter an exchange rate mechanism where you have fluctuation bands of plus or minus 15 per cent against the central rate. If you cannot be prepared to tolerate the economic requirements of shadowing even such a loose environment, to fix the exchange rate in perpetuity is very odd indeed.
  (Professor Begg) When you opened this question, you asserted that we all agreed the OECD is wrong. I do not think the OECD is that far wrong. The British economy is much more convergent with the Euro area now than it was three years ago. If the projections have any validity to them in saying that the Euro area output gap will become positive over the next year, the implication is that the ECB will have to be tightening monetary policy at the time when it has perhaps reached a plateau in the United Kingdom. Monetary policies will therefore converge much more than they have up to now over the next year or two. As for the exchange rate, the pound/euro exchange rate has already fallen nearly ten per cent since its peak. I think another five or so points, taking it to somewhere in the region between 1.45 and 1.50, would be tolerable for joining a single currency. It is much less of a gap to be overcome than it was in the past on both these counts. You also asked what the United Kingdom government needs to do. I think pretty much steady as she goes. There is not much that has to be adjusted macroeconomically in the United Kingdom to continue the pace of convergence that we have seen over the last couple of years. The United Kingdom is projected to grow slightly more slowly than the Euro area. As it does, they will both catch up towards full capacity utilisation and that will be a form of convergence.
  (Professor Buiter) I do not believe there is much that can be done or necessarily needs to be done to promote convergence. What convergence we are going to get is already substantively there and it is enough. The structural similarities between the United Kingdom and the continental European economies are much more important than the differences. Specifically, I deny the relevance or even the existence of significant difference in short term interest sensitivities of Euroland vis a vis the United Kingdom. There are always references to stories about the housing market especially, but it is not in the data. The IMF has exhaustively studied this. There is no evidence that economic activity responds more sensitively to short term interest rates in Euroland, or indeed in the US, then in the United Kingdom. Note that the US has had a very sensitive response of economic activity to short term interest rates for many years, even during the years when the only mortgage you could get there was a 25 year mortgage. There are many ways in which monetary policy gets transmitted. It is different in Euroland but there is no evidence that the United Kingdom is uniquely interest sensitive. You have to expect that, after some of the sensible reforms of discrimination against certain financial instruments take hold, the structure of housing markets and housing finance will converge more but that is not a precondition. What would help convergence is the creation of a confident expectation of membership in the not too distant future. If that is accompanied by clear hints that that membership, when it is negotiated between Britain and its European partners, will not be at anything like the current rate but south of it, that would take care of the serious problem of how to get there from here. Whether this requires formally entering into an ERM2 arrangement, which will require negotiation of the central rate in the first place—and the central rate will inevitably become, as it did for the first 11 entrants, the actual entry rate—may be a bridge too far. It is clear that once membership looms very directly, once the political commitment has been made, the mandate of the Monetary Policy Committee will have to be changed because you cannot have an independent, national inflation target and a floating exchange rate when you are steering towards membership in a common currency. In the short run, I think, steady as she goes. Our policies are not structurally divergent from the objectives of monetary and fiscal policy in Euroland and the best thing to do is to create confident expectation in the market as a whole that membership will come and in the not too distant future.

  68. You disagree with Mr Barty in respect of interest rate sensitivity in the housing market but you did agree with him on the exchange rate being a very important test of economic convergence. Would you say that is the key test of economic convergence even though the Chancellor does not actually put it in those terms?
  (Professor Buiter) I do not think it makes a lot of sense to join a currency union at an exchange rate that is way out of line and that you will spend ten years working off as a result. That is so clear both here and in Euroland that I do not think it will be an insurmountable issue. The details will be argued over ferociously but, just as everybody here agrees that sterling is overvalued, everyone in Euroland, including the ECB and the Council of Ministers, talks about the chronic undervaluation of the euro.

  69. Is that the key test of economic convergence?
  (Professor Buiter) No. It is an important test that has to be met for it to be a politically acceptable package. You only will get there if you have made a commitment, if you want to get there. The horse has to be in front of the cart rather than behind it.
  (Mr Bootle) What can the Chancellor do? Since the government was elected, I have argued that if it was serious about preparing Britain for the euro the major macro policy it could pursue is to have run a much tighter fiscal policy than it has. This is by no means dependable but it seems to me in direction at least the way in which you could aim to have a lower level of interest rates closer to the level operated in Euroland and also, on the balance of arguments, it would have helped to restrain pressure on the pound. For all sorts of understandable reasons, that was not to be. I think one should treat it now as effectively a closed door. The thing that remains is taking a more active line on the question of getting Britain to the right exchange rate and discovering what that exchange rate is, an issue on which I would very much disagree with Professor Begg, who stressed the possibility of converging after membership. He held out the example of some countries like Ireland which had delivered a remarkably good performance in the circumstances. It is true that there is something of that which can occur. However, I am very struck by the fact that it is not the way that France went about it. What France did was actually to prepare for the euro for ten years. A number of other European countries, including the Netherlands, were quite closely converged with the leading Euroland economy, namely Germany. One can think of all sorts of reasons why one might want to do that. In the French case I think this is particularly important because although no one can know what exactly the right exchange rate is, if indeed there is such a thing, in the French case they could be sure—and so could the Germans be sure—given the ten years that at least the rate at which the two currencies were fixed could not be grossly wrong because of the experience. We are not in that situation. I think it is simply incredible that the Chancellor should take the current stance under which the exchange rate has been down at 2.16 against the Mark, up to 3.45, all over the shop, with people arguing for a vast range of different possible entry rates and then to suppose that some time after the election there will be a referendum without a discovery process, without an experience of Britain being linked closely within a reasonable range to the euro—suddenly the thing is foisted upon us. That is the critical issue: discovering what the appropriate exchange rate is, within reasonable bounds, and seeing if you can live with it.

Mr Plaskitt

  70. How do we do that? We have had this quite dramatic oscillation in sterling against the DM and the euro. Clearly you have to get some degree of sustainable stability in the exchange rate in the run up to joining membership. Can we do it with the Bank of England's present remit as to how it controls monetary policy, or do we have to give them a new remit? Do you think, Mr Barty, we have to add perhaps a second pillar and say it has now got an exchange rate job as well? Otherwise, how is it done?
  (Mr Barty) I tend to agree with Roger Bootle in that you have to try and find the appropriate level of exchange rate, fix it and see if you can live with it. At some point, that will mean changing the Bank of England's mandate, I think.

  71. In what way?
  (Mr Barty) Because you would join ERM2, but you would not know what the right central rate is. By the way, there have been cases where people have adjusted their central rates prior to entry. Greece is one; Ireland is another. You do not have to stick with the central rate once you go in. One way or another, you would have to say the Bank of England would have to take more notice of the exchange rate than it currently has. Since we left the ERM, we have fluctuated enormously against either the Deutschmark or subsequently the euro. I do not know where Professor Begg gets his idea that five per cent more would be enough. I do not think anyone has a clue. The range of sensible equilibrium exchange rate estimates that I have seen for sterling in Deutschmark terms is from about 2.50 to 3 Deutschemarks. That is a huge range. The only way you can basically try and discover that is to say to the Bank of England at some point, once we are convinced that we have inflation down to a sustainable level, "Now you have to try and target the exchange rate as well". That could be in a wide enough range to not massively limit the Bank of England but you do have to go down that route. If we do not have stability of the exchange rate, I do not understand how we can be confident that we can go in at a certain level of sterling against the euro and make it work.

  72. Are they compatible objectives? If we achieve price stability at round about the current exchange rate and then say to the bank, "Now you have to get down to that exchange rate but you are not to compromise price stability", is it possible?
  (Mr Barty) You have to be very careful. One of the two targets would have to have precedence over the other. You cannot have two targets and one instrument. You could ask the Bank of England to take more weight from the exchange rate than it has done up to now. To have a situation where the currency fluctuated as much as it has, and it is only very recently that the Bank of England has got so concerned about the level of sterling, when we did get up to 3.40-ish against the Deutschmark, that it forced them to stop raising interest rates. That shows that their primary focus, quite sensibly, has been totally on the inflation target. My contention would be that at the moment, if we had a very different level of exchange rate, we would have much different levels of interest rates. Some of the OECD stuff published last week is an inappropriate gauge. It is not easy to do this, but if you want to go down the route into monetary union you do have to think about the exchange rate as well as inflation.

  73. Given all the years of volatility, how long do you think it will take, following the point at which you change the rules, before you could demonstrate relative stability in the exchange rate sufficient for you to be ready to join the euro?
  (Mr Barty) It is very difficult to put an exact time frame on it but certainly years rather than months. I would personally say at least a couple of years to see what the effect of a certain exchange rate would be. Here we are, 18 months into monetary union, and none of the economists at this table can honestly say whether we think there has been divergence or convergence amongst the Euro zone economies since we started.
  (Professor Buiter) I do not want anybody to go into a demonstration that we can manage the exchange rate outside the euro. What is required is a transition, if Britain is to join the euro, from the current level of exchange rate to a more sensible level. It does not require you to demonstrate that you can manage the exchange rate in ERM2 for some years' time. We have to get out of that box. These interim regimes are bad news. Our current monetary arrangements in this country are the best arrangements for managing independent monetary policy with no expectation of joining. It is the wrong arrangement for managing monetary policy with an expectation of joining. It should not have two nominal targets ever. If the Chancellor and the government decide that joining is going to be a serious objective, then the exchange rate has to become the overriding nominal target. You cannot be a little bit pregnant in these things. You have to do it seriously and have a formal change in the mandate.

Mr Fallon

  74. Given Mr Barty's assumption of, say, a two year transition—you are the experts—what rate would you joint at, Roger Bootle?
  (Mr Bootle) The 64,000 euro question. I would have to give a range. Something probably between 2.60 and 2.90.

  75. Professor Buiter?
  (Professor Buiter) I do not want to venture a guess at this stage.
  (Professor Begg) Ideally, somewhere between 1.40 euros and 1.45.

  76. Could we have that in Deutschmarks?
  (Professor Begg) Not off the cuff.
  (Mr Barty) It is 2.80-2.90.

Chairman

  77. Professor Buiter, I presume the reason why you have not give us an answer is that you have recently been a member of the MPC?
  (Professor Buiter) Yes.
  (Mr Barty) In the document I submitted, I said a broad range guess is somewhere between 2.60 and 2.80. I would probably be towards the top end of that range but I think it is impossible to put an exact number on it.

Mr Fallon

  78. Can we move on now to the inclusion of Greece and the drachma into the system from next January? The ECB I think slightly qualified that inclusion in their report by questioning whether the drachma would have the capacity to meet the conditions on a sustained basis. Do you share that concern?
  (Professor Begg) The Greek government has been working very hard since 1996 to join the EMU. It has gradually brought the aspects of the economy that were out of line into what seems to be in line. The exchange rate stability has been one of the advantages of that policy because it has not been all over the place the way it used to be in the eighties. It is not a big difficulty for the drachma joining because there is strong political commitment behind it. Anyone who looks at the accession of Greece to the single currency and says, "This is a destabilising feature" is simply ignoring the arithmetic, which is that the Greek economy is around one percentage point of the EU total. That does not alter monetary policy. You are adding the equivalent of a couple of Isle of Wights to the United Kingdom economy and that will never change things.
  (Mr Barty) It has been a fairly rapid convergence for Greece and the jury is going to be out on exactly how they cope once they are inside the monetary union, but they have made tremendous progress on convergence. I would agree with Professor Begg that Greece is, what, 1.5 per cent of the EU GDP. That is relatively small. It is not going to make a major difference to the Euro area. The United Kingdom is a very different situation. We are somewhere between 15 and 17 per cent of the EU GDP so if we went into the euro and we were inappropriately positioned it would be much more significant.

  79. Is it suggested that just because an economy is very small it should somehow be exempted from complying with the rules under a sustained basis?
  (Professor Buiter) No. The argument that they have not exhibited durable, sustainable exchange rate stability is again getting it backwards. You join the monetary union because that is the best way, the only sure way, of getting currency stability. To ask for a capability to demonstrate it on a durable basis before you join is quite silly. The fundamentals are right. The budgetary situation, the underlying inflationary pressures, the adherence to the general rules and norms of the Common Market game are ready. They will get their exchange rate stability, extremely sustainably, once they are part of the euro.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2000
Prepared 17 July 2000