Select Committee on Public Administration Appendices to the Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum by the Democratic Audit, Human Rights Centre, University of Essex (LR 52)

RESPONSE TO THE WHITE PAPER, "THE HOUSE OF LORDS: COMPLETING THE REFORM", CM 5291

INTRODUCTION

  1.  In 1999, a Task Force, chaired by Lord Plant of Highfield, gave evidence to the Royal Commission on the Reform of the House of Lords on behalf of the Democratic Audit. The Task Force report argued that only an elected second chamber would possess sufficient legitimacy in the eyes of the public to fulfil the role of legislative scrutiny and, wherever necessary, to employ the delaying powers that the House of Lords generally fears to use. The Task Force argued for a full-time salaried House with the capacity to undertake systematic scruting of the Government's legislative proposals.

  2.  The Task Force stated that the House of Commons should remain pre-eminent. But its members echoed long-standing complaints about the poor quality of legislation emerging from the House of Commons; and argued that since the Commons has largely become the instrument of the executive, the need for a stronger second chamber with the capacity to thoroughly examine government Bills and the legitimacy and powers to require the executive and first chamber to reflect for a limited period was all the more desirable.

  3.  We enclose a copy of this evidence with this submission.1

  4.  Our first aim in this supplementary evidence is to set the debate over reform in the context of a public mood of disillusion and withdrawal from the formal political process and to consider how reform of the second chamber could contribute to combating that disillusion. To assist the Government, Democratic Audit commissioned a public opinion poll from ICM Research, which was designed to follow up previous polls on the future of the House of Lords in the "State of the Nation" series of polls commissioned by the Joseph Rowntree Reform Trust. These previous polls confirm other results which show that the public greatly prefer an elected, or largely elected, second chamber to one which is solely or largely appointed (see pages 77-81 of Voices of the People, which summarises the "State of the Nation" polls).

  5.  We then go on to discuss the issues raised in the White Paper.

PART 1: THE PUBLIC'S VIEWS

  6.  The Rowntree polls over the period 1991-2001 indicate that the public is in general committed to the principles of accountable Government; to the adoption of strong legal and formal scrutiny and rules of conduct for government and Parliament; to more popular participation in government decision-making; and to the proportional principle in elections. Few people profess to have a wide knowledge of constitutional and political affairs, but the public as a whole has consistently revealed a basic grasp of democratic principle and the underlying issues in polls over the ten-year period of the Rowntree polls.

  7.  The public has consistently expressed a principled preference for an elected, or largely elected, second chamber and hostility towards party political patronage in appointments to that chamber. Our advice to the Government and Department is that reform of the House of Lords should as far as possible conform with the views of the public. These views are reasonable, principled and consistent. If the Government is willing to give them the consideration they deserve, then it will do much to restore public confidence in the country's political system and to give the future second chamber popular legitimacy. We will enlarge on these points as we respond to the White Paper.

Election or Appointment?

  8.  In the ICM poll for Democratic Audit2, respondents were first asked what was the best course for the future of a new second chamber; and then, which would give a reformed House most right to block government legislation. There was a simple majority for an elected, or largely elected, second chamber; and 54 per cent of the public would choose such a chamber against 14 per cent who are in favour of the government option of a largely appointed House (see Table below). Most respondents also believe that election would give the reformed House more legitimacy to block government legislation. Nearly half those interviewed (49 per cent) believe that election would give the House "most right" to block legislation, whereas only one in 10 (11 per cent) believe a largely appointed chambers would have similar legitimacy.

  9.  The public's views in full were as follows:

In your view, which of these proposals, if any, is the best course for a future second chamber?
For
%
Which would give a reformed
House most right to block
government legislation? (%)
A mixed House, with a majority of elected members
27
22
A wholly elected House
27
27
A mixed House, with a majority of appointed members
14
11
A wholly appointed House
9
18
Don't knows
24
23


  10.  The poll further tested people's attachment to the principle of election, as against the White Paper's insistence on special knowledge and expertise, by asking respondents whose views should be considered more important when it came to making new laws in the second chamber.

Whose views should be considered more important when it comes to making new laws in the second chamber?
  
Much more important (%)
A little more
important (%)
The views of eminent people with special knowledge or expertise
23
20
The views of elected representatives of ordinary people
35
14
Neither of them—1 per cent; don't knows—5 per cent


  Thus, a third of people think that the view of elected members are "much more important" than those of eminent specialists, against nearly a quarter who take the opposite view, and in aggregate, virtually half the public (49 per cent) think the views of elected representatives carry more weight, but in a close vote (43 per cent prefer to rely on eminent specialists).

Powers

  11.  The public clearly want the second chamber to be a real bulwark against poor legislation. Respondents were given four options and asked, "What powers should the second chamber have to make the government think again when it objects to a new law?"

What powers should the second chamber have to make government think again?
For
%
Power of delay for a few months
21
Power of delay for one year
14
Power of delay for two years
5
Power to hold up a new law "indefinitely" until the two Houses of Parliament can reach agreement
52
Don't know
9


  The strength of the public desire for an effective check upon the executive is apparent in the large vote—52 per cent—for giving the second chamber the power to hold up legislation until both Houses can reach agreement. In all, 71 per cent of respondents want a power of delay of one year or more. Further, two thirds of respondents (63 per cent) agreed that the second chamber should have "extra powers of delay" where peers felt that a proposed law would endanger human rights (27 per cent disagreed; don't knows numbered 10 per cent).

The Appointment Process

  12.  On party patronage, ICM's pollsters first asked respondents whether they agreed or disagreed that the Prime Minister of the day and other party leaders should have any say at all over those who are appointed to the second chamber; and then, "If there are to be appointed members, who should have the final say on who is appointed or not?" Public opinion greatly values the idea of an Appointments Commission,

Should the Prime Minister and other party leaders have any say at all on who is appointed to the second chamber?
For %
If there are to be appointed members, who should have the final say on who is appointed
For %
Yes
37
The Prime Minister of the day
12
No
56
An Appointments Commission independent of the government and parties
83
Don't know
6
Don't know
5


independent of both government and the political parties, having the last say on who is appointed to the House (if there are to be appointed members). An 83 per cent vote for a wholly independent commission indicates a popular consensus around this view. There is also a simple majority against the Prime Minister or party leaders having "any say at all" in appointments.

  13.  ICM also asked respondents whether they agreed with the proposal that the Prime Minister should decide on the great majority of appointments to a reformed second chamber, with an independent commission appointing a minority. The public were strongly against such a proposal, with 59 per cent "against" to 26 per cent "in favour"—more than a two-to-one vote against.

PART 2: COMMENTS ON THE GOVERNMENT'S PROPOSALS

Royal Commission Recommendations

  14.  Democratic Audit shares the Royal Commission's key views that the reformed second chamber should be "broadly representative of society" and that it should work with the House of Commons to provide "an effective check upon the Government" (see page 5 of the White Paper). The importance of creating a new House with sufficient authority and capacity to check and, if necessary, amend government legislation is vital to good government in the UK. By comparison with most democracies, the select committees in the House of Commons are relatively good at making government accountable for its policies and actions, and they do so largely in public; but the UK falls far behind other democracies when it comes to legislative scrutiny. The ad-hoc standing committees that are supposed to examine Bills in the Commons are weak, ill-informed and divided on partisan lines. A survey of parliamentary committees around the world, submitted to the Modernisation Committee in January 2002, stresses the need greatly to improve legislative scrutiny in the UK Parliament.3 Reports urging reform go back to the 19th century. In more modern times, several official reports in the 1970s made the case for reform, which was finally given magisterial authority by Making the Law, the report of the Hansard Society Commission on the Legislative Process in 1992.4

  15.  We do not believe that the Commission's proposals would have given the second chamber sufficient legitimacy to provide an effective check. The government's proposals will give the second chamber even less legitimacy, as the public is strongly against government and party patronage in appointing members to the second chamber. The decision to downgrade the role of the Appointments Committee may very well bring the chamber into disrepute as a haven for "place" men and women over time.

The Pre—Eminence of the House of Commons

  16.  Democratic Audit is disturbed by the executive bias in the Government's description of the "UK's political system", as set out in the White Paper (page 9, paragraph 15). Elections in the UK do not only, as the White Paper suggests, seek a "clear and unequivocal answer" to the question, "Whom do you choose to govern you?" Elections in the UK have a dual purpose—they also ask the electorate to choose their representatives to stand in for them in Parliament. This is a significant difference in that the White Paper is built around the interests and wishes of the political executive rather than the principle of democratic representation; nor can it be said that the disproportionate results of the majoritarian electoral system give a "clear and unequivocal answer" even to the choice of the UK's political governors.

The Powers of the House of Lords

  17.  Democratic Audit agrees that the House of Lords should continue to be able to delay legislation for a year, but we wish to see a second chamber that has the legitimacy and the capacity to use this power when it is appropriate. We agree with the public's view that the second chamber should possess additional powers to block legislation that it considers would endanger human rights in the UK. But we believe it is necessary to go further. As we are about to witness once again, the Government can generally change the country's constitutional arrangements by ordinary legislation passed (or accepted) by a simple majority in both Houses. We believe that it is incumbent on the Government to put major constitutional changes of this kind to the people in a referendum; and we urge the Government to do so in this case. There is also a strong case for giving the second chamber powers either to insist on a referendum where legislation has a major constitutional effect; or to give it extra powers of delay.

Composition

  18.  We begin by re-stating the case for election which rests upon principle and connected practical considerations. We then go on to examine issues of composition, the electoral system and timing, and pay.

(a)  The Principled and Practical Case for Election

  Legitimacy can only come from popular election. A modern legislature acts in a representative capacity: it stands in for the people as a whole. No appointed body can act in this capacity.5 Election is the primary mechanism of representative democracy. It is the only means by which everyone can be given an equal choice of candidates for public office and in which everyone has at least a formal opportunity to stand for public office. It is true, as the Lord Chancellor argues, that not all public offices are or need to be filled by way of election, but most such offices are normally specialist, not legislative, positions. In the UK, the appointed state is already growing fast and vast. There are no compelling reasons for filling most of the second chamber with appointees. But there is a compelling practical reason for giving it the legitimacy of election, simply because a largely appointed House is unlikely to command sufficient public respect and political authority to fulfil its central duties.

(b)  Second Chambers Overseas

  The White Paper is deliberately misleading in its discussion of the composition of the second chamber. To say, as the White Paper does, that, "Only a minority of democracies worldwide have wholly directly elected second chamber" is a half-truth. To go on to argue that the US Senate is not the norm against which other second chamber should be judged when 15 other nations, including Australia and Japan, also have wholly directly elected second chamber is no more than a red herring. Table 1 (over) sets out the position internationally to the best of our ability within the short time-scale for consultation. (We are aware that it is not comprehensive.)

  It is true that wholly directly elected second chambers are in a minority worldwide; but they form the largest minority. Further, most democracies choose one or another form of election as the principal means for recruiting members for their second chambers; 41 (or 71 per cent) of the 58 democracies in this survey have opted for chambers that are wholly or largely elected, directly or indirectly. Only 17 have wholly or largely appointed memberships. The Government's preferred option — largely appointed with an elected minority—is in a very small minority of two democracies, Malaysia and Swaziland, at the moment.

  The trend among established democracies is for elected chambers, and the main variation from direct election in this trend is towards indirectly elected chambers in federal states. At the same time, mixed systems with a variety of variations are common. Overall, a largely elected House of Lords with up to 20 per cent appointed or ex-officio members, on the model that we suggest in "Summary" below, would conform with the major democratic trend around the world. Such a solution need not mean that "the independent members would virtually disappear" (page 18, paragraph 40), especially if the Appointments Commission assumes the full role over the appointment process that the Wakeham Commission envisaged.

Table 1

COMPOSITION OF SECOND CHAMBERS AROUND THE WORLD

Composition
No.
Examples
Fully and directly elected
16
Inc. Argentina, Australia, Bolivia, Brazil, Colombia, Japan, Mexico, Poland, Switzerland, USA
Indirectly elected
14
Inc. Austria, France, Germany, Netherlands, Pakistan, Russia, South Africa, Switzerland
Mixed, largely elected (directly or indirectly) with appointed members
9
Inc. Chile, Croatia, Ireland, India, Italy
Mixed largely directly elected/co-opted/hereditary
1
Belgium
Mixed directly/indirectly elected
1
Spain
Wholly appointed
13
Antigua, Bahamas, Barbados, Belize, Burkino Faso, Canada, Fiji, Grenada, Jamaica, Jordan, St Lucia, Thailand, Trinidad and Tobago
Mixed, largely appointed with an elected minority
2
Malaysia, Swaziland
Mixed hereditary/appointed
2
Lesotho, United Kingdom
Total
58
  


  Sources:  derived from the Inter-Parliamentary Union database: www.ipu.org; secondary sources, Coakley, J, and Laver, M, in The All-Party Oireachtas Committee on the Constitution: Second Progress Report, Seanad Eireann, Government of Ireland, 1997; Russell, M, Second Chambers Overseas, Constitution Unit, 1999; Hazell, R, Commentary on the White Paper, Constitution Unit, 2001

(c)  The Party Presence in the Future Second Chamber

  Two other loose arguments in this section of the White Paper should be addressed. First, the White Paper states: "The majority of members should continue to represent the political parties ... it would be unrealistic to try and keep party politics out of the second chamber" (page 17, paragraph 35). If this is the case, what is the argument against election? The Royal Commission's principal argument against a fully or largely elected second chamber was that elections would entrench party politics and squeeze out members of "expertise and experience". The government has rejected the Royal Commission's recommendation that the independent Appointments Commission should have the final say over the identity of party nominations. Thus the government intends to give the party managers of the main parties the decisive say over who will fill up to 332 places in the new House, or 55 per cent of the total membership. In other words, the government is determined that leaders of the established parties should retain the conveniences of patronage (some of them highly undesirable) and directly select their party members in the House rather than trust the people to choose them for their qualities and political affiliation after a more diffuse selection process has taken place within the parties (but see "Electoral issues" below).

(d)  Gridlock

  Second, it is argued that two wholly elected chambers within the Westminster system would be a "recipe for gridlock" (page 18, paragraph 39). As the Democratic Audit Task Force argued, the spectre of gridlock could readily be disposed of by giving the second chamber clear functions and limits on its powers to ensure the continuing pre-eminence of the House of Commons (page 13, paragraph 21). Moreover, given the rushed and inadequate nature of the legislative process in the UK, an element of "gridlock"—that is, proper time for reflection—should be warmly welcomed; and the ICM polls suggest that the great majority of the British people would welcome it.

(e)  New Labour's Life Peerage

  Democratic Audit examined the make-up of the Life Peerage in 1999 for the Task Force report and found that former ministers, MPs and MEPs made up a third of the total (Table 1 of the report). There was a huge imbalance between life peers drawn from private business and those from the public service. In terms of "primary occupation", we found that business people outnumbered public servants by a ratio of three to one—22 per cent against 7 per cent. Moreover, when the secondary occupations of former MPs and other peers were examined, 214 of the then 513 life peers had identifiable business backgrounds or interests—42 per cent of the total. In all, 250 life peers were also identified as "party activists" (including councillors) — 49 per cent of the total. About one in ten life peers had the specialist knowledge or expertise that is used to justify the appointment process.

  For this evidence, we examined the full list of life peers created under Tony Blair. In the House of Lords, the Lord Chancellor said 247 life peers had been created under the Labour government (HL Debates, 9 January 2002, col 563). Of these, five were law lords. Thus we analysed the backgrounds, interests and political activity of 242 life peers, we also separated out the 15 creations made on the recommendations of the Appointments Commission. Table 2 (over) shows the basic analysis of the New Labour (or political) Life Peerage (column 1), as well of the full list (column 2). We believe the composition of this list to be a significant pointer for the future, since most creations have been made by the Prime Minister and party leaders, though it is intended that the Appointments Commission will supply a large minority in the future.

  As before, we have given priority to elected public office or public service in defining the "primary occupations" of life peers, even though for example former MPs and ministers have often had successful business careers as well, or may previously have worked in the public services. The political contingent from "the other place" remains broadly steady at a third of the total. The gap between life peers from business and the public service has narrowed slightly, down to 17.5 per cent against 13 per cent after the intervention of the Appointments Commission. However, it is likely that the gap would swell were we to measure secondary occupations.

Table 2

LIFE PEERS CREATED (UNDER 1958 AND 1876 ACTS) SINCE MAY 1997*

Category
All Government and party appointees
All life peers, including Appointments Commission creations
  
No
%
No
%
Former ministers, MPs and MEPs
80
35
80
33
Corporate and private business
41
18
43
17.5
Academics, specialists etc
17
7
21
8.5
Lawyers (other than Law Lords)
12
5
12
5
Public service work, paid and voluntary (including social work, the NHS, police and military service, etc)
24
10.5
32
13
Senior civil servants
5
2
6
2.5
Councillors
13
6
13
5.5
Trade union officials
11
5
11
5
Political party officials (including high-ranking volunteers and Parliamentary candidates)
6
2.5
6
2
Political advisers
4
2
4
1.5
Culture and media
10
5
10
4.5
Religious office (other than ex officio Anglicans)
2
1
2
1
Royal Household
2
1
2
1
Total
227
100*
242
100*
*Percentages rounded.
Sources: Dod's Parliamentary Companion 2002; Who's Who 2002; The Guardian Guide to Parliament; Journal Office, House of Lords; Parliamentary Profiles.


(f)  Party Politics

  We have researched the political backgrounds of life peers as thoroughly as we could in the short time available. We counted as "political activists" elected politicians at all levels; failed parliamentary candidates; known party donors; party workers, paid and voluntary; and close allies of party leaders ("cronies" in the vernacular). Many life peers had played many political roles. The records at our disposal were incomplete. Nevertheless, we found that 163 life peers were political activists in this sense. Thus nearly three out of four of the appointments made through the Prime Minister and party leaders are party political activists. The composition of the House of Lords is being saturated by the very party politics that the Royal Commission warned against.

  These figures throw into relief the White Paper's expressed belief in the value of "non—politically aligned members of the Lords" (page 23, paragraph 62). Nomination rather than being a safeguard against excessive party political influence in the second chamber actually creates a well-trodden, and half-concealed, alternative path of party political preferment into Parliament.

(g)  Specialism

  Much is made of the specialist contribution, which the House of Lords makes to parliamentary debate and scrutiny. Yet the scepticism about the breadth of specialism that appointments bring to the House expressed in the Task Force report (page 38) is confirmed by the low level of academic and specialist peers created under the current regime (at 8.5 per cent of the intake, even after the Appointments Commission's contribution). On the other hand, there is likely to be a tendency to be sympathetic to the needs of the executive, with 80 more former ministers, MPs and MEPs, and six more senior civil servants, added to the already considerable number of recruits from Westminster, Whitehall and Strasbourg on the House's benches.

(h)  The Role of the Appointments Commission

  If the government's view that there should be a majority of appointed peers in the reformed chamber prevails, it will be vital to public confidence in the new House and its political authority for the Appointments Commission to assume the full role envisaged by the Royal Commission. This would be the case even if appointees were to be in a minority. The government does propose two significant reforms: the relinquishing by the Prime Minister of his current powers of appointment to the House; and the fact that nominations by other party leaders will no longer need to pass through the government's hands (page 26, paragraph 67).

  But the judgment in paragraph 66 above that the "parties of whatever persuasion must be able to decide who will serve on their behalf" [our emphasis] is mistaken. No explanation is given for this arbitrary decision. But it holes the legitimacy of the whole structure of the government's reform. A process of party political appointment of over half the members of the new House will be widely seen as a recipe for party political patronage and cronyism; and there will be some truth in such a perception.

  It is axiomatic that not all such political appointments are made on merit. Party leaders must reward party or personal loyalty or services; donors are often given a short-cut to public office, as many of the New Labour Life Peerage have; MPs in safe seats are given peerages to smooth the path of the Prime Minster's aides and allies into the House of Commons (as happened in at least two cases at the last election). Patronage of this kind should be a remnant of the old politics, not preserved in the very fabric of a modernised new chamber. The damage that such practices will do the reputation of the House and politics in general is incalculable. The government must be persuaded to put democratic principle first, and the convenience of party leaders second. The proper route for party control of recruits to the second chamber is via the ballot box.

(i)  Religious Representation

  In a modern and pluralist nation of many faiths and none, it is an anachronism for the Church of England to be the only church or faith represented as of right in the chamber. The "practical obstacles" to a wider representation of faith do not justify the anomalous position that the White Paper adopts with the retention of 16 places for the Church of England in the House. In our view, the specific representation of "faith" in the House is wrong in principle; the various faiths that exist within the UK should be represented in the legislature alongside all beliefs and political and social affiliations through the votes of the people at the ballot box. Representation of "faith" in the second chamber would breach the democratic principle of political equality and give certain values systems and interests preference over others. However, if "faith" is to be privileged, no one institution should monopolise that privilege. There should be no places reserved for the Church of England in the House; and the Appointments Commission should be given the responsibility for deciding on the representation of faith in the new chamber.

(j)  The Electoral Process

  The government recommends that elections for elected members of the House should be by a proportional list system and should primarily seek to introduce representation on a regional basis into the House. We welcome the decision to adopt a proportional system, but there should be debate now about the most appropriate system. The electoral system chosen should be as open and flexible as possible, enhancing the degree of accountability that is available to voters. At the same time, the degree of control exerted by party managers over the choices open to voters should be restricted. If the government opts for a "closed list" system alongside party control of most appointed places, the undesirable political saturation of the House, under the control of the party managers, would increase yet further. The parties in effect control the composition of some three quarters of the whole House.

  There are three types of list system:

    —  fully open systems under which voters must choose the individuals they wish to vote for from party lists

    —  flexible systems which give voters a choice between accepting the party list or voting for individual candidates; and

    —  closed systems which give voters only a basic choice between rival party lists.6

  It is this third system that the government introduced for the Euro-elections amidst a great deal of controversy. The system goes against the grain of electoral traditions in the UK, since most voters value the idea that they are choosing a representative as well as a party when they go to the polls. The system diminishes any real sense of democratic accountability since any candidate elected as part of a list will naturally seek to satisfy the party managers and members who gave her or him their place on the list rather than the voters. We recommend that the government at least opt for a fully open list system and change the system for Euro-elections to conform. We also recommend that the government consider the advantages of the Single Transferable Vote (STV), a broadly proportional system which encourages voters to discriminate between candidates. We are aware that there is considerable hostility towards STV within the Labour party's (and presumably the government's) ranks, but it does enhance personal accountability and its use would more fully realise the government's professed aim of a more diverse and independent second chamber. It also becomes more nearly proportional in large constituencies.

(k)  Timing of Elections

  Democratic Audit agrees with the Royal Commission that elections to the second chamber should be held alongside elections to the European Parliament. Turnout would probably be lower, as the White Paper argues, than if they were held at the same time as general elections. But holding the elections both to the European Parliament and new House together would raise turnout for the Euro-elections, the more so the more substantial the elected element in the new House is to be. There is a real danger that a minority of 120 elected members will be regarded only as a token. Linking elections to the second chamber to general elections would also have the profound disadvantage that the terms of elected members would be variable. They may even have to stand for election twice in one or two years, as has happened in general elections.

  The case that the Royal Commission made for longer terms of office in the second chamber in terms of greater independence and continuity is very persuasive and should not be cast aside. We also regard it as a disadvantage that the dominant national issues on which general elections are fought would almost certainly determine the results of the elections to the second chamber and heavily influence the party and personal choices that were made by voters. The composition of the elected element in the second chamber could become a pale reflection of the composition of the popular chamber. The degree of accountability to voters would diminish. Regular elections on a different time-scale would reduce this danger; and would bring stability to the second chamber. The regional nature of both elections could be emphasised rather than the purely European influence that the government fears (page 21, paragraph 21).

(l)  Terms of Office

  Democratic Audit does not believe that the terms of office for elected or appointed members need be of 15 years; nor that the two categories must necessarily serve terms of equivalent length (page 22, paragraph 57). Nevertheless, the Royal Commission's argument for long and regular terms of office is compelling and we recommend that terms of 10 years are appropriate for both categories; and 10-year terms would fit well into the European Parliament's electoral cycle.

(m)  An Electoral Threshold

  Finally, a 5 per cent threshold for party election to the House seems high, at least in relation to the government's current proposals for the size of the elected element. The dangers of a too homogenous House are far greater than any distant danger of "unacceptable fragmentation" (page 25, paragraph 67). The second chamber must not become yet another preserve largely for the three main parties, a prospect that seems likely under the White Paper's schema. We also recommend that any threshold set be on a regional, not national, basis.

9.  PAYMENT

  Implicit in both the Royal Commission's report and the White Paper is the assumption that the second chamber will continue to be a public home for an elite. We are not in a position to judge how far the House benefits from its part-time and expenses-based system. But the government's preference for such a system sits neither in principle nor practice with opening up membership to election. Every citizen should, as we have already stated, have at least a formal opportunity to stand for public office in the new second chamber. This formal right must be given substance so that, for example, all members of society should be able to put their names forward knowing that they will not suffer financially. If we assume that the expenses are broadly genuine attempts to meet the actual costs of attendance and membership, then the current arrangements will be inadequate to recompense those who cannot supplement their service in the House from the rewards of their existing professional or work lives.

  Table 3 (below) sets out the sitting days of the House over the last four years for which information is available. If we assume that the daily subsistence payment of £60 for attendance at sittings would be the equivalent to a salary, then in the last three years the full annual "salary" for a member would be varied between £9,420 and £10,140; and in an election year might fall as low as £7,500. The average gross full-time wage in 2001 was £23,607 a year. The Audit's Task Force report in 1999 argued that the Lord was "woefully under-resourced" for its current duties and recommended that a reformed House should be a full-time body and that all members should be paid salaries and fees, and given resources, commensurate with their responsibilities. In the interests both of democratic equity and effectiveness we repeat that recommendation again. Membership of the House should be a full-time paid post. If members wished to serve on a part-time basis, they should if possible be able to do so. But full-time and fully-paid peers should become the norm.

Table 3

HOUSE OF LORDS DAILY SITTINGS, 1997-2000

By calendar year
2000
1999
1998
1997*
1
No of sittings days (excluding days when the House sat for judicial business only and swearing in days)
169
157
163
125
2
No of weeks during which the House sat
40
37
39
31
3
No of hours for which the House sat
1,261:37
1,190:28
1,211:21
816:39
* General election year
Source: House of Lords Annual Report, 2000-01


SUMMARY — A MODEL NEW CHAMBER

  We will not summarise this brief paper. But we accept that we should present a model for a new chamber for discussion. Our preference—both for reasons of principle and practice—is for a fully directly elected chamber. But we believe that a compromise is acceptable. This compromise model should above all be simple. Hence we suggest:

    —  the chamber should have a considerable majority of elected members over appointed members;

    —  the upper limit for appointed members in a 600-member House should be set at 200 members, or a third of the House;

    —  the Appointments Commission should be wholly responsible for appointing all appointed members and should be statutorily responsible for holding a proper balance in terms of party allegiance, gender, ethnicity and faith;

    —  the Prime Minister should be able to create a limited number of peers to serve as ministers in the House;

    —  party leaders should be allowed to submit lists of possible appointees to the Appointments Commission, alongside public rights of nomination and self-nomination;

    —  the electoral system should either be a fully-open list system or STV;

    —  elections should be on a regional basis and should be held at the same time as Euro-elections under the same more open system.

February 2002

REFERENCES

  1  The Plant Report, Making a Modern Senate: a new and democratic second chamber for Britain. Democratic Audit Paper No. 17, Human Rights Centre, University of Essex, 1999.

  2  ICM interviewed a random sample of 1,000 adults aged 18+ by telephone between 14-16 December 2001. Interviews were conducted across the country and the results were weighted to the profile of all adults. The full tables giving demographic information are available from ICM and were posted on their website.

  3  Weir, S, and Kearton, I, Object Lessons: Parliamentary committees abroad, their functions and powers, Democratic Audit, Human Rights Centre, University of Essex, January 2002.

  4  Hansard Society, November 1992. See page 2 for the long history of informed dissatisfaction with the legislative process, dating back to 1835!

  5  See Beetham, D, "Democratic criteria for electoral systems", in his Democracy and Human rights, Polity, 1999 (esp. pages 174-79).

  6  See further, Dunleavy, P. and Margetts, H, "Electing Members of the Lords (or Senate)", LSE Public Policy Group, in the Report of the Royal Commission on Reform of the House of Lords, vol. 2 (CD), Cm 4534.



 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2002
Prepared 25 February 2002