Select Committee on Public Administration Appendices to the Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum by Professor Iain McLean, Professor of Politics, Oxford University (LR 58)

CM 5291: THE HOUSE OF LORDS — COMPLETING THE REFORM

SUMMARY

  The Government has a manifesto commitment "to reconstitute the House [of Lords] on a modern representative basis". The most obvious, and easiest, way to honour that commitment is by choosing most of its members by direct popular election.

  The elections should be by proportional representation (open-list or STV) in the 12 territorial districts of the UK, viz, the three non-English territories and the nine standard regions of England.

  Elected members should be elected by halves, and serve for one non-renewable term of 10 years (or two parliaments). Retaining the Parliament Acts unaltered will continue to guarantee the primacy of the House of Commons.

  There are arguments for combining Upper House elections with a fixed-term cycle (European or local) and with the General Election cycle. I lean towards the latter, because it helps to guarantee the primacy of the House of Commons.

  —  The Government wishes to meet its manifesto commitment to a representative House by laying a duty on the Appointments Commission to make the House representative of the UK by gender, ethnicity, and faith community.

  However, the Government's rejection of Wakeham's Recommendation 98 makes this mathematically impossible. The Appointments Commission would have to shape a House of 600 while able to choose only 120 of its members.

  It is wrong to ask the Appointments Commission to rebalance the House to any particular share of the popular vote in elections to another place. That smacks of Zimbabwean democracy.

  Neither Church of England bishops nor Law Lords should be ex-officio members.

  The transition problems are more tractable than the White Paper maintains.

INTRODUCTION

    Mr. Bryant: I thank my right hon. Friend for giving way. Does what he is saying about the consultation process mean that if the consultation showed that people wanted a wholly or substantially elected second Chamber, the Government would then bring forward such a set of proposals?

    Mr. Cook: ...[O]f course we will listen to what is said during the consultation period. In the period of reflection that will follow, we will see where we can find the centre of gravity in order to move forward with reform... Of course, I recognise that not all Members who support reform and those principles of the White Paper will necessarily support all the solutions by which it achieves those principles. What is now urgent is to find the package that would establish the greatest consensus among those Members of Parliament and the public. (Hansard, Commons, 10.01.02, cols 702-4).

    "That this House supports the democratic principle that any revised Second Chamber of Parliament should be wholly or substantially elected." (EDM in the name of Fiona Mactaggart MP, with 177 signatures by 10.01.02).

    "So what do we do next? The only sensible way to resolve the issue is by a free vote on the various options, starting with the most radical—all Members elected—and then working down." (Sir George Young MP, Hansard, Commons, 10.01.02, col. 730).

  All available evidence suggests that the centre of gravity, both of UK public opinion and of the opinion of Members of Parliament, lies in favour of an upper house at least half of whose members are elected and fewer than half, if any, nominated by or via political parties. Part A of this evidence therefore sets out how the Government might adapt the Royal Commission's proposals if it wishes to produce a predominantly elected upper house. Sir George Young's proposal would be a good way to implement the Leader of the House's reply to Mr Bryant.

  Part B sets out how the Government might design a house whose elected component is no larger than the Royal Commission's proposals. Comments on religious representatives and on the Lords of Appeal in Ordinary, which apply whether or not the upper house is predominantly elected, are in Part C; and on transitional issues in Part D.

  To distinguish the reformed upper house from the House of Lords, and its members from peers, in this evidence the former is called the senate and its members senators. This is simply a labelling device.

A.  FINDING THE CENTRE OF GRAVITY

  A1  The Government is pledged in its Manifesto to complete reform of the Lords to remove the hereditary element entirely and to reconstitute the House on a modern representative basis Cm 5291 § 3. The obvious interpretation of this manifesto commitment is that the upper house must become a predominantly elected house. For an alternative interpretation, based on a rival conception of "representative", see part B of this evidence. Part B will show that the White Paper proposals cannot achieve "representativeness" in that sense.

  A2  The Government has made it clear that any upper house must respect the primacy of the House of Commons over legislation. It included this constraint in the instructions to the Royal Commission. All of the following evidence respects that constraint. So, if the senate is to be predominantly an elected house, its powers and election timetables must be designed so that the primacy of the House of Commons over legislation remains.

  A3  This is achieved by retaining the Parliament Act 1949: "it [the Government] accepts that the so-called "suspensory veto" is the best way, in the UK context, of recognising both the House of Lords'; right to have its concerns taken seriously and the House of Commons' right to prevail at the end of the day" (Supporting Documents 4:10). I agree.

  A4  The Government's case against direct election of all or most of the Upper House is that direct election would, in and of itself, undermine the primacy of the House of Commons over legislation. Neither the Royal Commission Report nor the White Paper succeeds in showing this.

  A5  The Royal Commission's logic was faulty. In arguing against a directly elected Upper House, it said:

    11.5... There would be a risk that the second chamber would have a different political complexion from the House of Commons. Such a divergence would, whatever the formal distinctions between the chambers in terms of their powers and pre-eminence, be bound to give rise to constitutional conflicts. A different risk would arise if the second chamber had the same political complexion as the House of Commons because that could cause it to act as a compliant rubber stamp for whatever any future Government might want to do.

    11.6 Regardless of its political complexion, the central objection to a directly elected second chamber is that it would, by its very nature, represent a challenge to the pre-eminence of the House of Commons and make it difficult to strike the balance between the powers of the two Houses that our terms of reference require and that we have recommended. (A House for the Future Cm 4534, chapter 11, my emphases).

  But paragraph 11.5 proves too much. The second chamber must have either a different political complexion from the House of Commons or the same political complexion as the House of Commons. These possibilities are mutually exclusive and jointly exhaustive. And that is true whatever proportion of the second chamber is elected. Therefore paragraph 11.6 does not validly follow from 11.5. A way must be found to ensure that the senate neither gives rise to constitutional conflicts nor acts as a compliant rubber stamp, whatever proportion of its members is elected. These opposite dangers must be addressed via the powers of the senate and the manner of appointment to it, not its composition.

  A6  The senate will not give rise to constitutional conflicts if the Parliament Act 1949 is retained. That preserves the situation in which the senate has a veto only in the last year of a Parliament. No constitutional crisis has arisen since 1911 from the House of Lords, with no democratic legitimacy, using this power. If a democratically elected senate exercises the same veto, it will have more legitimacy than the House of Lords. Therefore, a fortiori, there will be no constitutional crisis if the senate blocks legislation in the final year of a parliament.

  A7  The House's power to reject Statutory Instruments did not give rise to a constitutional conflict on the one occasion it was used recently (in 2000). Therefore that power should be retained. The White Paper's proposals to restrict this power could restrict the senate to acting as a compliant rubber stamp.

  A8  The Government has not accepted Wakeham's Recommendations 74 (elected members not to be re-eligible to stand for election) nor 98 (Appointments Commission, not political parties, to select political nominees). By rejecting these two key recommendations, I cannot accept that the White Paper "build[s] on that essential groundwork" (Cm 5291 §5). Rather, it undermines it.

  A9  One weapon that parties have over their parliamentarians is the threat to deny them reselection. Recommendation 74 of the Royal Commission would ensure that the parties would not have the weapon; and that the senate would not attract those who wished to make a lifetime career of party politics.

  A10  The Government rejects Wakeham Recommendation 98 on the grounds that "It is quite wrong that a political party should not be able to determine who represents it in Parliament" (Supplementary documents 7:32). But if the leaders of political parties control the nomination and renomination of their appointed senators, those senators will have such a powerful incentive to obey the Whips that, as in the Commons, government politicians will tend to support Government proposals regardless of merit and opposition politicians to oppose them regardless of merit. The requirement on the Appointments Commission to rebalance the senate after each General Election to reflect the balance of party strength in the Commons (Cm 5291 §66) must require any party that has lost ground in the election to give up some of its nominees. If the party chooses which those are to be, that is an even more direct threat to their independence than anything Whips or extra-parliamentary parties have yet devised for MPs. It would be an impossibly invidious task for a non-partisan public body to ask the Appointments Commission to choose. It also suggests a ZANU-PF conception of democracy. If the senate has a different complexion to the House of Commons, that will be, in part, because the people have voted for it to have a different complexion. The Appointments Commission is not going to wish to play the role of the Zimbabwean army. §66 of the White Paper is unworkable, and must be rethought even if nothing else is.

  A11  The electoral system for directly elected senators must not be the closed list system currently in force for elections to the European Parliament. If a party has unfettered control of its list, it can punish its own members by placing them low on the list. Therefore, again, party senators would be at least as beholden to Whips or extra-parliamentary party organisations as MPs are. Either an open list system or Single Transferable Vote would avoid this danger, and achieve the Government's objective for the elected component of the senate.

  A12  I agree with both the Royal Commission and the White Paper that there should be a group of cross-bench senators chosen for their expertise by the Appointments Commission. These could include religious leaders and lawyers. Assuming that somewhere around 100 cross-benchers would both cover the range of expertise required and ensure that no party had an overall majority in the senate, there would be scope for about 500 elected members if the Government persists in its desire for a target house size of 600. If the Government comes to agree with the general view (which I share) that that number is much too big, then both members could be halved, say to 50 cross-bench experts and 250 elected numbers.

  A13  It will be easy for the Government to legislate for a larger elected component in the senate than the Royal Commission proposed. All the essential matters are in place, notably election by proportional representation in 12 multi-member districts, viz, the three non-English nations and the nine standard regions of England; elections to coincide with some other election; elections to be supervised by the Electoral Commission. On all of these matters I believe the White Paper is correct, providing that the PR system used is not closed party list (see A10).

  A14  The Government invites views on which out of (a) European Parliament elections; (b) Westminster elections; (c) local and regional elections should coincide with senate elections. Options (a) and (c) have similar advantages and drawbacks and I therefore discuss them together—if one is chosen, I do not mind which.

  A15  They both offer fixed terms (five years and four years respectively). This confers a double advantage. For the senate and its members, it gives certainty as to the length of the current term. And it removes election timing from the scope for political manipulation. Finally, the would tend to bolster turnout at those "second-order" elections. The Government argues that the disadvantages of using the European electoral cycles are "the historically very low turnout... [and] the danger that decisions on membership of the second chamber will be coloured wholly by voters' attitudes to the parties' policies on Europe" (Supporting Documents 6:29). However, political scientists have shown (i) that low turnout at Euro and local elections derives from voters' perception of them as "second-order"; (ii) that voters reward and punish the parties in those elections overwhelmingly because of what is happening in national politics, not in European or local politics. The first two bullet points in Supporting Documents 6:29 therefore speak for, not against, combining senate elections with one of those.

  A16  However, the Government's third argument against tying the senate to either of those fixed-term cycles is stronger. It is a firm sociological law that the Government of the day always does badly in mid term. Therefore at almost every fixed-term senate election the Opposition of the day would do better than at the previous General Election. This might generate the constitutional conflicts that the Government seeks to avoid. Therefore, (rather reluctantly) I support White Paper Option (b), namely having senate elections coincide with General Elections. However, unless considerably more guarantees of senate independence are built in than the White Paper proposes, the senate risks acting as a compliant rubber stamp. Many of the guarantees have already been mentioned. Another would be the proposal by the Conservative Party's Mackay Commission to deal with the problem of short Parliaments. If a Parliament lasted less than a certain minimum time, the terms of those elected senators due to retire would be extended for one further parliament if (and only if) a joint resolution of both Houses so resolved.

  A17  Having senate elections coincide with Westminster elections would almost always deliver two of the Government's desiderata at once. The party which won a majority in the Commons would have the largest single number of senators; but no party would have a majority of even the political senators, and therefore a fortiori of the senate as a whole. These results flow from the simple fact that the Commons election would be by plurality, while the senate election would be by PR. No party has won more than half of the votes cast in a UK nationwide election since 1935. Even in the landslides of 1886, 1900, 1906, 1918, 1935, 1945, 1983, 1997, and 2001, the governing party would have won fewer than half the seats in a simultaneous half-election by PR to the upper house. Only in 1931 (when the winning coalition won 67.0 per cent of the votes cast) would a simultaneous senate election have produced a majority of seats for the governing coalition.

  A18  The term of each elected senator should be two parliaments, non-renewable (see RC Recommendation 74 and A7-A8 above). Half of the senate would come up for election at each General Election. This plan would ensure that enough senate seats would be up for election even in the smallest district to ensure representativeness of diverse opinion. The smallest election district would be Northern Ireland, with about 2.7 per cent of the UK electorate. In a half-senate election where there were 250 seats to fill, Northern Ireland would therefore have seven seats By the standard formulae for electoral systems, then, any group that can command at least 1/8 of the votes in Northern Ireland would get a seat, thus ensuring that all main traditions would be represented. Similar calculations apply to Wales and Scotland. Across the UK, a half—senate election with 250 seats to fill and every district having at least seven seats (most of them considerably more) should ensure that important bodies of opinion (such as, to use examples from 2001, those represented by the Green Party and the UK Independence Party) would be represented—see Table 1. There would be no need to impose a minimum threshold of representation. The electoral system does this automatically by setting a quota of 1/(n+1) as the minimum fraction of the vote a party must get per seat that it wins in an n-member district.

  A19  These calculations show that this arrangement would satisfy the Government's manifesto commitment to complete reform of the Lords to remove the hereditary element entirely and to reconstitute the House on a modern representative basis Cm 5291 §3.

  A20  As much of the debate turns on just how large the elected portion of the senate should be, I commend Sir George Young's proposal (see epigraph). As opinion on the issue is (what is technically called) single-peaked, a series of resolutions starting with "100 per cent elected" and, if that does not pass, continuing downwards in (say) 5 per cent decrements will ensure that the percentage which wins a majority can beat any other. I can supply the department with a technical paper explaining why this is so, if required, but do not want to put any mathematics into this evidence.

B.  MAKING THE WHITE PAPER PROPOSALS WORK

  B1  The Government seeks to meet its manifesto commitment to a "representative" senate by imposing requirements on the political parties and the Appointments Commission to ensure that those nominated for election, and those appointed, together form a microcosm of the UK population, or at least come closer to that ideal than does the present House of Lords. Achieving "microcosmic representativeness" will be much more difficult than the Government believes.

  B2  It would be difficult for a number as small as the 120 elected members proposed (Cm 5291 §46) to be a political microcosm of the UK. If elected by halves (at a General or Euro election to serve two terms), only 60 places would be open at a time. Even if appointed for only a single parliament, which I think is a bad idea, only 120 places would be open at a time. If 120 places are vacant this implies (see A17) only three seats for Northern Ireland (where there are currently four main political traditions of roughly equal size), and if 60 places are vacant it implies that all the smaller regions (Northern Ireland, Wales, North-East, East Midlands) have too few seats to allow for political representativeness. To achieve this within the (self-imposed) constraint of the range of Royal Commission recommendations, therefore, the Government must accept the Royal Commission's Option C and have 195 elected places in the senate. If elected by halves, the number must be even, so I propose 194 elected members, with 97 places vacant at each filling. Table 1 shows the number of elected places that would be available in each district at each election under various assumptions about the size of the elected component of the senate.

  B3.  As to demographic and social representativeness, the Government proposals throw a very arduous burden on the Appointments Commission. The following calculations assume that, once transition is complete, there are 194 elected members, 120 appointed crossbench members and 286 appointed political members. There would be no ex officio bishops or law lords (see section C).

  B3.  To require gender balance, ethnic minority representation, and diversity among the elected members would require very intrusive primary legislation to control parties' nominating procedures; be impossible to impose on individual independent candidates (Dr Richard Taylor MP (Ind. Wyre Forest) has only one gender, one ethnicity, and at most one religion); and constitute a contempt of the electorate. Therefore, the Appointments Committee could achieve its proposed target for gender, ethnic and faith—community representation (Supporting Documents 7:24-28) only by choosing the gender (etc.) of at most 406 members, and for some purposes at most 120 members, of a 600-member house.

  B4.  The Government's decision to reject Recommendation 98 of the Royal Commission makes the Appointment Commission's task impossible. If a party's list of nominees does not help to achieve the number required gender, ethnic and faith-community representation, what is the Appointments Commission to do about it? If a gender, ethnicity or faith is under-represented among the political senators (elected or appointed) and if the political parties (or some of them) do not voluntarily produce "balanced tickets", the Appointment Commission will have no powers to make them do so.

  B5.  In such an event, the Commission would have to produce diversity in a house of 600 while being able to control the relevant features in only 120 members. This gearing could make the gender requirement (at least 30 per cent of each) impossible to achieve, and the ethnic and faith requirements extremely difficult. Table 2 shows the relative size of the UK's faith communities. If the Church of England is assigned 16 representatives (whether by ex officio bishops or otherwise), then a total of 77 senators will be needed to represent all faith communities. Many of them will have to be female, whatever the wishes of the faith community in question, to satisfy the gender requirement. At worst, this could leave the Appointments Commission with only 53 crossbench places to fill with representatives of anything other than faith communities.

  B6.  The only solution I can see is that the Appointments Commission must ask each party voluntarily to produce a ticket of nominees that is balanced as to gender, ethnicity, and faith. Table 3 shows how difficult that would be in respect of ethnicity. Because one ethnic group is so overwhelmingly large, it would be difficult for any one party to nominate from each of the other groups in the appropriate proportions.

  B7.  If the Government does not remove the bishops (all of one gender, and all from one minority faith) and the Lords of Appeal in Ordinary (historically almost all of one gender (from the senate, then the above becomes even more problematic.

C.  BISHOPS AND LAW LORDS

  C1.  There is no good argument for retaining either bishops of the Church of England or the Lords of Appeal in Ordinary in the senate.

  C2.  Contrary to the claim in the Royal Commission Report (Cm 4534, 15:9), the presence of the Church of England Bishops in the House of Lords has not always promoted "ever greater religious tolerance and inclusiveness". A dispassionate historian would have to say that until the 20th century it did just the opposite. Between 1893 and 1914, the Bishops votes en masse against Irish Home Rule and Welsh Disestablishment. As they were disestablished in Ireland in 1869, it is hard to see how they felt entitled to vote at all on Home Rule; and in Wales, their denomination was a small minority sect. If faith communities are to be represented in proportion to size, then the Church of England should have approximately 21 per cent of those seats. Nothing in Cm 4534 nor in the White Paper explains why the ex officio representation should remain.

  C3.  The Human Rights Act is forcing the UK towards a formal separation of the judicial function from the executive and the legislature. The Pinochet and Factortame cases have shown how easily the multiple roles of the Lords in Appeal in Ordinary could be confused. Sooner or later, the Law Lords will have to leave the legislature. There is no better time than now.

D.  THE TRANSITIONAL HOUSE

  D1.  The White Paper exaggerates and misrepresents the problem of transition from the existing House to the senate. It exaggerates the problem of managing the attrition in the number of Life Peers. It misrepresents the problem of achieving political, balance during the transition.

  D2.  The present House contains 144 hereditary peers, bishops and Law Lords (only 4 of whom are women). It is agreed that the first will go and strongly urged above that the second and third should also go. Of 555 life peers (excluding those on leave of absence, bankrupt, or in jail), death can be expected to remove 18 a year for the next ten years and a somewhat smaller number thereafter. A voluntary retirement scheme, with club right preserved (as with hereditaries in 1999) will certainly produce enough retirements to keep the total house size within the cap of 750 during the transition.

  D3.  There is a serious mistake in §93 of the White Paper, where it is stated that Labour Party peers would need to be created in order to give that party a lead over the Conservatives. But the Conservative lead over Labour among existing peers is purely a function of the remaining 92 hereditaries continuing to sit. When they go (and assuming no deaths or resignations among life peers), Labour will have, as it already does, a plurality of life peers.

Table 1

SIZE OF REGIONAL CONSTITUENCIES (TO NEAREST WHOLE NUMBER)

Territory
Electorate
2001
Per cent
of UK
electorate
Seats per territory when total seats to be filled=
  
  
  
60
97
120
194
250
500
Scotland
3984306
8.99
5
9
11
17
22
45
Wales
2236143
5.04
3
5
6
10
13
25
NI
1191009
2.69
2
3
3
5
7
13
England:
East Midlands
3205094
7.23
4
7
9
14
18
36
Eastern
3954554
8.92
5
9
11
17
22
45
London
5001310
11.28
7
11
14
22
28
56
North East
1904342
4.30
3
4
5
8
11
21
North West
5243848
11.83
7
11
14
23
30
59
South East
6054822
13.66
8
13
16
27
34
68
South West
3784807
8.54
5
8
10
17
21
43
West Midlands
4000694
9.03
5
9
11
18
23
45
Yorks & Hum
3763642
8.49
5
8
10
16
21
42
Sources: Electoral Commission, Election 2001: the official results, Tables 4 and 5;
Butler and Kavanagh, British General Election of 2001, Table A1.2


Table 2

FAITH COMMUNITIES IN THE UK

    
N (000)
Percent of
total
Entitlement to
seats
Christian:  
  
  
  
  Anglican
1,654
20.89
16
  Catholic
1,768
22.33
17
  Free Churches
1,278
16.14
12
  Presbyterian
989
12.49
10
  Orthodox
235
2.97
2
  Non-Trinitarian
533
6.73
5
Buddhist  
50
0.63
0
Hindu  
165
2.08
2
Jewish  
95
1.20
1
Muslim  
665
8.40
6
Sikh  
400
5.05
4
Others  
85
1.07
1
Total  
7,917
  
77
Source of column 1: Office of National Statistics, UK 2002, Table 15.1
Column 3 is derived by comparing the relative size of each faith community to that of the Church of England, for which the White Paper proposes 16 reserved seats.


Table 3

ETHNICITY IN GB

Group
Per cent of
population
Target number in House of 600
White
92.9
557
Black Caribbean
0.9
5
Black African
0.8
5
Black Other (non-mixed)
0.2
1
Black Mixed
0.3
2
Indian
1.7
10
Pakistani
1.2
7
Bangladeshi
0.5
3
Chinese
0.3
2
Other groups
1.2
7
  
  
600
Source of column 1: ONS, UK 2002, Table 9.5
NB, Excludes Northern Ireland, and those in GB who did not state their ethnic group.
January 2002





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2002
Prepared 25 February 2002