Memorandum submitted by the Institute
for Fiscal Studies (PC 23)
A. BACKGROUND:
WHAT IS
THE PENSION
CREDIT, AND
WHY IS
IT BEING
INTRODUCED?
The pension credit will restructure means-tested
support for pensioners to address perceived shortcomings in the
current system. So to understand its intended purpose, it is necessary
to grasp the existing structure of benefits for pensioners. Most
pensioners receive the flat-rate basic state pension, which in
April 2003 is expected to stand at £77 per week for single
people (£124 for couples).[1]
Since the early 1980s, it has been indexed only with prices (which
rise slower than earnings) and so it provides a living standard
that is increasingly meagre in relative terms. Therefore, when
recent governments have had money to spend on pensioners, they
have tended to target it on those who would otherwise have only
the basic pension to survive on.
Figure 1
Illustrative Budget Constraint under the
MIG, for a Single Pensioner

Note:
2003 benefit rates assumed.
Income disregards, taxation and other means-tested
benefits ignored.
To do this, benefits that provide pensioners
with an income "safety net"the minimum income
guarantee (MIG) and its predecessor, income supporthave
been increased.[2]
These benefits "top up" the poorest pensioners' incomes.
Crucially, topping-up is to a fixed level, regardless of whether
the claimant has private income or not. So, for the poorest pensioners,
any private income possessed is worthlessbecause, pound
for pound, it reduces the amount of "top-up" received.
Figure 1 illustrates how the system works for a single 65-year-old,
with benefit rates in April 2003, when the MIG is expected to
be £100. If his/her only income is the basic pension, the
figure shows he/she will receive a £23 top-up (£100
MIG minus £77 original income). If, instead, the pensioner
has the basic pension plus £10 of private income (total pre-means-tested-benefit
income of £87) then we can see he/she receives only £13
top-up (£100 MIG minus £87 original income). So, final
income is the same (£100) in the two cases. Indeed, the figure
shows that a pensioner's original income has to exceed the MIG
before it affects final income.
This situation could be deemed problematic on
two counts. First, it distorts the incentive to save: in particular,
making saving unappealing for low-wage workers who expect to retire
on a low income. The specific concern is that people in this situation
would decide not to save at all, which would reduce their private
incomes and so increase the means-tested benefit bill. Secondly,
on grounds of fairness, it might be felt that it is unacceptable
that those low-income pensioners who have saved to achieve some
private income should go entirely unrewarded for their thrift.
The situation has become more pressing recently
as the Labour government has increased the value of the MIG far
more rapidly than that of the pension. In the first year of the
current government, 1997-98, income support for a 65-year-old
stood at £68.80 (in current cash terms) while the retirement
pension was £62.45, a gap of just £6.35, compared with
the £23 we have seen is expected for 2003-04. This means
that, in real terms, the private income that such a 65-year-old
must possess before it has any effect on his/her final income
will have roughly tripled in six years.[3]
In the absence of reform, these tendencies would
have been exacerbated in the more distant future, because the
government "aspires" to increase the MIG every year
in line with earnings, whereas the expectation is that the basic
pension will continue to rise roughly in line with prices.[4]
This means that the gap between the MIG and the pension should
rise faster than earnings. In turn, this suggests that a growing
number of pensioners will find that their basic pension entitlement
together with their private income is below the MIG, and so their
private incomes will have no effect on their final income.[5]
The concern was, therefore, that the government's strategy of
targeting help for pensioners "where it is needed most"
implied ever more pensioners failing to be rewarded for their
thrift.
All this pointed to reform, and proposals for
the pension credit followed. Figure 2 shows how it should work
for an example single pensioner. Before the reform, each £1
of private income immediately above the basic pension left final
income unchanged; afterwards, each £1 increases final income
by 60p; ie abstractingfor nowfrom taxes and other
income-tested benefits, this means the effective marginal tax
rate implied by the pension credit will be 40 per cent, compared
with the 100 per cent rate that the MIG currently imposes.[6]
This 40 per cent withdrawal continues until all pension credit
entitlement is exhausted, at around £135 per week. The chart
shows that the lower withdrawal rate means single pensioners with
non-means-tested-benefit income of anywhere between £77 and
£135 will gain.[7]
All this has been known for over a year, since
the government unveiled its plans for a pension credit, as part
of its substantial package for pensioners in the 2000 Pre-Budget
Report.[8]
But important additional details were not settled until the 2001
Pre-Budget Report.[9]
Figure 2
Effect of the Pension Credit on a Single
Pensioner

Note:
All incomes in projected 2003 prices.
Income disregards, taxation and other means-tested
benefits ignored.
B. WHAT DID
WE LEARN
IN NOVEMBER
2001?
The basic shape of the pension credit proposal,
as outlined in Section A, did not change between the government's
Autumn 2000 consultation paper and the firmer proposals outlined
at the time of the 2001 Pre-Budget Report. But there was some
new important informationboth changes made in the light
of the consultation process and provision of details that had
not previously been givenin the later document.
In particular, we found out:
that the main ("savings credit")
reform will be restricted to men and women aged 65 and over;
that the capital rules in the MIG
system would be maintained but modified;
how the reform will affect housing
benefit and council tax benefit; and
how the new means test will work.
We will discuss each of these in turn. Before
we do so, it is useful to expand on the government's terminology,
which was also clarified in November.
From 2003, the MIGthe guaranteed minimum
incomewill become a feature of "pension credit".
This basic element will be known as "pension credit guarantee",
effectively a re-labelling of the MIG, and will be available to
exactly the same individuals. The main reformthe extra
benefit available as a result of the reduction in the benefit
withdrawal rate from 100 per cent to 40 per centwill be
known as the "savings credit" element of the pension
credit. It will be available to a more restricted group. (See
footnote 7 for more detail on how the government describes the
benefit calculation.)
B1. COST
The reform had previously not been costed in
the public finances. In February 2001, an IFS Briefing Note estimated
that it would cost at least £1 billion a year (in 2000 prices),
but it was stressed that this was extremely dependent on the generosity
of the changes made to other means-tested benefits at the time
the pension credit is introduced.[10]
As we discuss in Section B4, the government has decided to make
housing benefit and council tax benefit significantly more generous
for pensioners when it introduces the reform, making the reform
more expensive.
Another announcement concerned timing. The reform
will not be introduced in April 2003, but October 2003, reducing
by roughly 50 per cent its cost in the first year. The government
projects (in current prices) that the reform will cost:
£975 million in fiscal 2003-04;
£2.025 billion in fiscal 2004-05,
when it will be effective over the whole year for the first time.
These numbers are very similar to the estimated
additional benefit expenditure that our own tax-benefit modelling
suggests will be needed.[11]
In 2001 prices, we estimate a total of £1.9 billion extra
benefit expenditure annually from the reform, of which £1.5
billion is being paid in pension credit itself, while £200
million is housing benefit and £200 million is council tax
benefit. By contrast, when we modelled the introduction of the
pension credit initially, we assumed that council tax benefit
and housing benefit would continue to operate as now. The result
was that expenditure on these benefits would actually have declined,
by some £400 million, helping to offset the new pension credit
expenditure.
If we assume inflation at 2.5 per cent, then
we estimate that the total extra expenditure will be £2.1
billion in projected 2004-05 prices, slightly higher than the
government's estimate. But our modelling assumes 100 per cent
take-up of benefit entitlement. The government's own most recent
estimates suggest that only between 74 per cent and 86 per cent
(by expenditure) of pensioner entitlement to income support is
actually claimed.[12]
Allowing for some degree of non-take-up could reduce our cost
estimate significantly. There might also be additional differences
between our estimation methodology and that used by the government.[13]
We have not yet attempted to estimate the likely
cost of the reform in the longer term. In practice, this will
depend hugely on future government policy regarding indexation.
The government's own estimates suggest that, by 2040, the cost
of the reform could vary between 0.1 per cent of GDP and 1.1 per
cent of GDP, depending on whether the MIG is uprated with prices
or earnings beyond 2006.[14]
Further analysis of these issues, which will crucially determine
the impact of the reform on the rest of the pensions system, would
be extremely valuable.
B2. RESTRICTION
TO PENSIONERS
OF 65 AND
OVER
The MIG is available to all low-income individuals
(and their partners) of 60 or over. The savings credit element
of the pension credit, by contrast, will only be available to
those aged 65 or over (and their partners). The same is true of
the main changes to housing benefit and council tax benefit. When
the new system comes in, however, those in the 60 to 64 age bracket
will benefit from the changes to the capital rules.
Although there are large numbers of individuals
in the 60 to 64 age bracket, their exclusion from the reform does
not affect the cost very dramatically. The main reason is that
60 to 64 year-olds tend to be better off than older people, and
so a lower proportion of them stand to benefit from this means-tested
benefit increase. As a result, the immediate effect of applying
an age limit of 65 is to save just £200 million compared
with the alternative of using an age limit of 60. But this ignores
behavioural responses, which could increase the cost of setting
the age limit younger. Given that the savings credit makes the
benefit system more generous, it could encourage potential recipients
to decide that they could retire comfortably, when they would
not otherwise have done so. As many of those aged 60 to 64 (unlike
their older counterparts) are still working, if such behavioural
effects were important, the cost of including under-65s could
have increased considerably.
B3. CAPITAL RULES
The government's original plans for the pension
credit seemed to suggest that the capital element of the MIG means
test would be completely abolished when it was replaced by pension
credit. Instead, only income generated by capital held would be
subject to a means test.[15]
The government's November 2001 proposals, by contrast, envisage
keeping some capital rules, although they will be made significantly
more generous than the existing rules, which penalise possession
of financial capital very heavily. In particular, under the new
rules:
the upper capital limit above which
no MIG can be received (currently £12,000) will be abolished;
the amount of capital deemed equivalent
to £1 of weekly income will double from £250 to £500.
The government puts the changes down to arguments
it received from pensioners' organisations and others during consultation.[16]
Certainly, the changes are consistent with our submission at that
time. We argued that there were significant problems with moving
completely away from a capital test.[17]
It would have:
involved a loss of precision in the
targeting of resources on the basis of need;
discouraged the annuitisation of
wealth, which might be a concern, given that other elements of
government policy, such as stakeholder pensions, are aimed at
encouraging this;
made it far harder to avoid creating
losers when the reform was introduced;
quite possibly increased, rather
than reduced, the informational demands on claimants.
The measures the government is now proposing
instead have none of these disadvantages, and yet they still address
the concern that motivated the proposal to scrap the capital rules
in the first placethey will allow saving amongst low-income
people to be better rewarded.
The abolition of upper capital limits in the
pension credit, above which all benefit entitlement is forgone,
is especially welcome. It should avoid the "cliff edge"
situation where an individual with (say) £12,001 can find
him/herself significantly worse off than if he/she had got exactly
£12,000, as the extra £1 left him/her totally ineligible
for benefits. Given this progress, however, it seems surprising
that the government has chosen to maintain the £16,000 upper
capital limits in housing benefit and council tax benefit for
those pensioners who are entitled only to the savings credit.
Although these will affect relatively few individuals, the reform
package would surely look more coherent if these, too, were abolished.
B4. HOUSING BENEFIT
AND COUNCIL
TAX BENEFIT
The government's original plans said nothing
specific about how the introduction of the pension credit would
affect housing benefit and council tax benefit (hereafter referred
to as "rebates"). Rather, the government acknowledged
that issues were raised, and appealed for views on these.[18]
Interactions with the rebates are an issue because
of two consequences of the way the benefits are withdrawn. Rent
and council tax rebates are withdrawn respectively at 65 per cent
and 20 per cent for those pensioners with an income of just above
the MIG; where both benefits are received, the combined withdrawal
rate is the sum of these two85p in the £1. This withdrawal
means two things. First, gains to pensioners from policies such
as the pension credit that lifted them just above the MIG would
be much reduced, as up to 85 per cent of any gain would be lost
in forgone housing and council tax benefit entitlement. Secondly,
this withdrawal could dominate the increased reward for saving
an extra pound of income that the pension credit reform introduces.
The pension credit substantially reduces the MIG withdrawal rate
from 100 per cent to 40 per cent; but if both rebates are simultaneously
being withdrawn, then the combined benefit withdrawal rate of
a pension credit recipient would again rise, to 91 per cent.[19]
With these problems in mind, the government
has decided that when pension credit is introduced, both housing
benefit and council tax benefit will be made more generous. In
particular, the income that pensioners are allowed to possess
before the rebates are reduced (their "needs") will
be increased above the level of the MIG. For pensioners eligible
for the savings credit, needs will be increased by the maximum
gain from reform. This completely succeeds in eliminating the
first problem that we have considereda typical pension
credit recipient, even one who gains by the possible maximum amount,
will receive the same rebate entitlement as before, and so gain
from the reform in full. There are some special cases, however,
where particular care will be needed if the full gain is really
to be guaranteed.[20]
So, the government's decision to make the rebate
systems more generous should be able to prevent benefit "claw-back"
consuming any of the pensioners' gains from the reform in 2003.
Indeed, pensioners whose income puts them just above the MIG will
actually see an increase in their incomes that is bigger if they
are on housing benefit and/or council tax benefit than if they
are notas the increase in needs will mean that they become
entitled to full support from these rebates for the first time.
The proposal for the rebates will not, however,
completely avoid the problem of high marginal rates that we have
discussed. For some, the problem is solved. Consider a pensioner
on £105 of pre-means-tested-benefit income a week: the increase
in "needs" would mean that an extra pound of private
income will no longer give rise to reduced rebate entitlement.
Even though such a person would be exposed to the pension credit
taper, at 40 per cent, this would be less than the combined rebate
taper (85 per cent) that he/she had previously faced. But for
others, things are different. For example, a 65-year-old with
pre-means-tested-benefit income of £120 a week who received
partial rent and council tax rebates currently faces a taper on
these of 85 per cent; post-reform, he/she would continue to face
a taper on these benefits but would also become entitled to pension
credit, taking his/her total marginal deduction rate to 91 per
cent. Others, whose incomes were previously just too high to qualify
for partial rebatesand the high deduction rates that this
entitlement produceswill become entitled to them for the
first time as a result of the increase in needs.
For some pensioners, then, marginal deduction
rates will increase, while for others, they will decline. We will
consider the relative quantitative significance of these different
types of cases when we look at effective marginal tax rates in
Section C.
B5. THE NEW
MEANS TEST
In its November 2000 consultation paper, the
government stressed its desire to reduce the degree to which applying
for benefits was intrusive and troublesome for pensioners. In
particular, it suggested that it wanted to examine the ways in
which the existing weekly means test for MIG could be made more
like the annual process of tax assessment that better-off pensioners
(and others) currently undergo.[21]
The government now seems to have gone further and decided on a
five-year period of assessment, with reassessment necessary only
where one's income drops (in which case it is voluntary) or where
one's circumstances change dramatically. It has also come up with
some welcome practical proposals about how the Pension Service
can try to improve take-up.[22]
When we first looked at the pension credit proposals,
we welcomed the aim of simplifying the means test as something
that should improve take-up.[23]
Indeed, the actualas opposed to the notionalresults
of the reform could depend just as much on its success in improving
take-up as they will on the precise parameters of the new system.
While applauding the aim, however, we expressed a number of concerns.
In particular, we were concerned, first, that there was nothing
in the move to an annual system that, per se, would necessarily
significantly simplify the experience of applicants. The new practical
proposals for telephone application etc. do, however, look as
if they will help in this regard.
Our second concern was the potential abuse of
a system that fixed payments for a yearsome groups of workers
might be able to report a low income, achieved by reducing their
hours of work, and be awarded high pension credit entitlement,
only to go on and boost their income once this was fixed. The
move to a five-year period of fixed payments potentially worsens
this risk. The fact that pension credit will now be restricted
to those aged over 64 should help considerably: fewer in this
older age bracket will be the type of semi-retired people able
to manipulate their earnings strategically. Only 3 per cent of
those in our data aged 65 or over report themselves as currently
working as employees, and only a fraction of these will be able
to choose their hours at will. Still, for this small group, and
for those who are self-employed, the potential gain from a strategic
reduction in hours for the purposes of a means test could be significant
now that the government has decided on a five-year period of fixed
awards. The government may want to think about how to minimise
the potential for this abuse.
C. ESTIMATED
EFFECT ON
THE PENSIONER
POPULATION
When we first modelled the pension credit, we
had no idea about a whole range of details concerning how the
new system would work. In particular, we knew nothing about how
the interaction with the rebates system would be handled. We assumed
the least expensive possible option compatible with the maintenance
of the MIG as the net income safety net (ie that "needs"
in the rebates would be increased in line with the MIG but no
further), while noting that other options were possible that would
have quite different effects.[24]
But we now know that the government is going to be considerably
more generous than this, meaning new estimates are needed. Our
new modelling must also incorporate the effect of the changes
to the capital rules and the new age restriction, amongst other
things.
In what follows, we model the reform by assuming
the parameters used illustratively in the government's proposals.[25]
Included in our "reform" is the increase in the pensioner
tax allowance that the government will introduce to ensure that
no single pension credit recipient (without special benefit premiums)
need pay tax. Excluded is the real-terms increase in the rate
of the MIG scheduled for April 2003.
C1. DISTRIBUTIONAL
RESULTS
Looked at across the whole income distribution,
the pension credit is a progressive measure, although it is worth
less to the bottom 10 per cent than it is to the second poorest
income decile, as Figure 3 shows. This turns out to be becausegiven
the greater generosity of the benefit system to pensioners, even
before the reformfew pensioners are in the bottom 10 per
cent. Those pensioners who are in the bottom 10 per cent of the
income distribution actually gain rather more in proportional
terms than those in the second decile. This suggests that it might
be more interesting to look at the impact across the distribution
of pensioner incomes. But it is also worth considering one implication
of Figure 3if the concern is alleviation of the most acute
poverty in general, then it is not obvious that directing more
money to pensioners should be the top priority. Rather, those
groups whom the benefit system treats less generously and who
therefore dominate the bottom decile should, perhaps, be the immediate
target.
Figure 4 recalculates the figures using deciles
constructed on the basis of family income for adults aged 65 or
older only.[26]
There are two immediate differences from Figure 3. First, the
scale of the redistribution that the reform represents is far
largergains for the bottom two deciles now represent an
increase in income of significantly more than 5 per cent. This
is because here we are only considering the effect on those people
whose age means that they are potentially affected. Secondly,
the poorest 10 per cent now gains the most: 8.1 per cent of income.
This is because many households that gain that are not in the
bottom 10 per cent of the overall income distribution are amongst
the poorest 10 per cent of those over 65. Even in cash terms,
it turns out that the poorest 10 per cent of pensioners gain mostsome
£11 a week on average, compared with gains of between £5
and £8 for each of the other deciles apart from the top three,
which gain less.
Figure 3
Gains from the Pension Credit across the
whole income distribution

Note:
Income deciles are derived by dividing the total
population into 10 equally sized groups according to household
income adjusted for family size. Decile 1 contains the poorest
tenth of the population, decile 2 the next poorest tenth and so
on, up to the richest tenth in decile 10.
Source:
IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, run using
data from the Family Resources Survey, 1998-99.
Figure 4
Gains From the Pension Credit across the
over-65s Income Distribution

Note:
Income deciles are derived by dividing the population
of adults living in families containing someone over 65 into 10
equally sized groups according to household income adjusted for
family size. Decile 1 contains the poorest tenth of the population,
decile 2 the next poorest tenth and so on, up to the richest tenth
in decile 10.
Source:
IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, run using
data from the Family Resources Survey, 1998-99.
Given that the pension credit is a reform aimed
at helping those with incomes just above the MIG, it may seem
surprising that it is the "really poor" rather than
the "nearly poor" pensioners who seem to be gaining
most. One reason is that there are a small but significant number
of high-capital, low-income pensioners at the very bottom of the
income distribution who can gain very substantially from the reform
of the capital rules, as they can become entitled to means-tested
benefits for the first time. Indeed, according to our data, average
family savings in the bottom pensioner decile are actually higher
than those in the second poorest decile (£5,000 rather than
£4,000).
Looking at the difference between couple and
single pensioner families, we find that couples gain slightly
more on average: £6.60 as opposed to £5.26. But given
that pensioner couples have higher incomes on average, the proportional
effect on single pensioners will actually be greater.[27]
Like the estimates of cost we discussed in Section
B1, these figures assume full take-up of benefit entitlement.
If, in reality, take-up by expenditure is similar to that for
existing entitlement, the average effects will be reduced by about
20 per cent.[28]
C2. POVERTY RATES
The government is aiming to reduce pensioner
poverty. One way in which it measures this is by the number of
pensioners living below various thresholds of median income. The
pension credit is one policy that might help in this regard. Table
1 shows its effect on poverty rates using two particular thresholds60
per cent and 70 per cent of median income.
Table 1
Proportion of Adults Aged 65 or Over Living
Below Different Poverty Lines, Before and After the Reform
Poverty line |
Pre-reform | Post-reform
|
60 per cent median income | 10.6 per cent
| 5.7 per cent |
70 per cent median income | 18.5 per cent
| 15.9 per cent |
Notes:
The poverty line is measured relative to the whole population
median income (where households are weighted by the number of
people in them). Income is measured net of taxes and benefits,
but before deducting housing costs. Percentages are fractions
of the 8.54 million people aged 65 or over who live in private
households in Great Britain.
Source:
IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, run using data from the
Family Resources Survey, 1998-99.
Our estimates of poverty rates before the reform are considerably
lower than those published in Households Below Average Income
(HBAI), even though both sets of estimates ultimately derive from
the Family Resources Survey.[29]
The divergence is principally because the numbers here are based
on a tax and benefit model, whereas the HBAI is simply recorded
data. The figures in Table 1, therefore, show the notional working
of the 2003 tax-benefit systemthey can capture the pre-announced
increases in benefits for pensioners that the HBAI numbers cannot,
and they assume that all benefit is taken up, which the HBAI does
not.[30] But the effect
of a particular policy on poverty in a tax-benefit model should
at least relate reasonably closely to the eventual effect that
the policy will have on the HBAI figures when compared with the
option of not introducing the reform.
We can see that the effect of the reform might be to reduce
by almost five percentage points the number of pensioners living
below the 60 per cent median income poverty line; for the 70 per
cent median income poverty line, the effect is more modesta
decline of 2.6 percentage points. One very important reason why
the actual effect on the poverty rate might be rather smaller
than this is that take-up of the entitlement created will be less
than 100 per cent.
C3. MARGINAL DEDUCTION
RATES AND
THE INCENTIVE
TO SAVE
Changes to the tax and benefit system can have two types
of effect on the incentive of working individuals to save for
retirement. The first are "income effects": these occur
when people's understanding that the reform has increased (decreased)
their income in the future will decrease (increase) the urgency
with which they need to save. Because the pension credit reform
represents a means-tested benefit increase, it increases low-income
individuals' expected future income and thereby blunts their incentive
to save through the income effect. The second channel through
which the tax-benefit system affects saving incentives is the
"substitution effect", ie it affects the rate at which
an extra pound of saving now cashes in in terms of increasing
the ability to spend in retirement. In what follows, we will focus
on substitution effects as the reform is largely focused on these.
But it is important to appreciate that these are not the only
consideration that will determine the effect of the reform on
saving behaviour.[31]
The existing MIG system exerts negative substitution effects
by clawing back the savings income of low-income pensioners in
forgone benefit entitlement. As we saw in Section A, benefit withdrawal
can mean that saving to provide for an extra pound of income ends
up having no effect on the incomes of the poorest pensioners.
Another way of expressing this is to say that the "effective
marginal tax rate" (EMTR) is 100 per cent.
We can use EMTRs more generally to look at the extent to
which benefit withdrawal and taxes together reduce the incentive
to save. Table 2 shows how the reform will alter these rates for
adults of 65 or over. In general, the reform has reduced them.
It has very substantially reduced the number of pensioners who
face a marginal withdrawal rate of 100 per cent or more, from
32.1 per cent to 5.6 per cent. This is principally because most
pensioners who are currently entitled to the MIG (and so face
pound-for-pound withdrawal) will in the future face lower withdrawal
ratesindeed, their EMTR will be just 40 per cent if they
are on no other means-tested benefits.[32]
There is also a decline in the number of people in the 80 per
cent to 90 per cent bracket, because the increase in the generosity
of housing benefit and council tax benefit needs has decreased
the number of families whose marginal tax rate is made up of a
20 per cent withdrawal rate from council tax benefit and a 65
per cent withdrawal rate from housing benefit. A further effect
reducing the number of people on high marginal tax rates is the
government's decision to increase the tax allowances of pensioners
so as to ensure that no single pensioner (without special income
support premiums) can both receive pension credit and pay income
tax.
Table 2
Proportion of Adults Aged 65 or Over Facing Various Marginal
Tax Rates, Before and After the Reform
Effective marginal tax rate | Pre-reform
| Post-reform | Change
(per cent points)
|
0 per cent | 18.2 per cent
| 13.5 per cent | -4.7
|
<50 per cent | 42.2 per cent
| 56.7 per cent | 14.5
|
50 per cent-69.9 per cent | 0.6 per cent
| 14.9 per cent | 14.3
|
70 per cent-79.9 per cent | 0.5 per cent
| 0.4 per cent | -0.1
|
80 per cent-89.9 per cent | 5.5 per cent
| 1.3 per cent | -4.2
|
90 per cent-99.9 per cent | 1.0 per cent
| 7.7 per cent | 6.7
|
100 per cent + | 32.1 per cent
| 5.6 per cent | -26.5
|
Notes:
The percentages represent fractions of the total population
of adults aged 65 or over in private households in Great Britain.
Their total number is 8.54 million. An effective marginal tax
rate is the proportion of a small increase in income consumed
through forgone benefits and taxation combined. Tax rates are
estimated by considering the effect of an increase in private
pension income.
Source:
IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, run using data from the
Family Resources Survey, 1998-99.
There are some effects working in the other direction. The
number of individuals with a zero EMTR has declined, because the
increased generosity of the means-tested benefit system necessarily
means that more individuals are eligible for help, and so the
number of people facing the effects of the withdrawal of benefits
has also increased. Also, there is a very large rise in the number
of people facing EMTRs of between 90 per cent and 100 per cent.
The most important single reason is that the reform produces a
group of individuals who will see their council tax benefit, housing
benefit and pension credit simultaneously withdrawn: their marginal
tax rate will be 91 per cent. These are mostly individuals who,
before the reform, were already having both rent and council tax
rebates tapered (giving rise to an EMTR of 85 per cent), so the
increase in their EMTR is modest.
A more general sense of the reduction in EMTRs is achieved
by looking at the change in the mean EMTR for people aged 65 or
over. Before the reform, it was 47.8 per cent; post-reform, it
declines to 39.2 per cent. A final measure is the number of people
experiencing increases or decreases: 25.3 per cent of adults aged
65 or over will see their marginal rate increase; 30.9 per cent
will see it decline.
So, it seems that EMTRs will generally fall, and they will
fall most where they were previously highest. Although, as we
discussed in Section B4, the increase in needs in the rebate system
means some pensioners see their EMTRs increase sharply because
they will become entitled to partial housing benefit for the first
time, in practice their number seems to be small. A possible explanation
is that there are relatively few pensioners living in rented accommodation
whose incomes are sufficient to exhaust housing benefit entitlement,
even before the increase in "needs". The immediate practical
effect on EMTRs therefore seems strongly positive.
This is a much more emphatic conclusion than we were able
to reach when we last analysed the pension credit.[33]
In part, this is because we were concerned with government pension
policy more broadly last time (in particular, we considered the
increase in the MIG as a reform, whereas here we take it as a
given). But, in part, it is because the increase in the 'needs'
in the rent and council tax rebate system that the government
has announced has dramatically reduced the numbers who will be
left facing very high marginal rates after the reform.
In the long term, though, there are factors that will tend
to increase the number of pensioners on high EMTRs. First, this
is because the gap between the state pension and the MIG is set
to increase very rapidly, which should increase the number of
pensioners who will have pension credit entitlement and so will
face the effects of its withdrawal (see Section A and footnote
5). Secondly, because of the rapid growth in typical MIG entitlement
that this produces, there will likely be a growing range of incomes
over which pensioners would be liable to have both rebates and
pension credit withdrawn at once.[34]
Thirdly, as the married couple's allowance for pensioners continues
to be phased out, there will be an increasing number of pensioners
who both pay tax and receive pension credit.[35]
D. CONCLUSIONS
Since we last analysed the pension credit, the government
has announced significant new details concerning the implementation
of the reform. We have learnt about how council tax benefit and
housing benefit will be made more generous for pensioners. This
development has very significantly increased the cost of the reform,
but it ensures that more pensioners will gain in full from the
reform and that their effective marginal tax rates will typically
be lower after the reform than they otherwise would have been.
In addition, the policy towards capital has changed in an advantageous
manner, and we have learnt a little more about how the new means
test will work.
The main outstanding questions concern longer-term issues.
In particular, there are questions about how much the pension
credit will cost in the future and about its effects on long-term
incentives to save, given that it seems likely that it will cover
a growing proportion of pensioners. Most particularly, it remains
unclear how the credit fits in with other parts of the government's
pensions strategy, notably stakeholder pensions for those on moderate
incomes and the state second pension. For the growing number of
middle-income pensioners who seem likely to be floated onto the
benefit, given current government policy, the gains from having
built up pension rights will be reduced.
Tom Clark
Senior Research Economist
February 2002
1
Precise figures will depend on the inflation rate. The couple
rate applies where one partner is without a full National Insurance
contribution record. If both have full records, they receive twice
the single rate. Where one record is partial, the couple receives
whichever is the greater of the couple rate and the sum of their
individual entitlements. Back
2
This happened under both Conservative and Labour governments.
For a 65-year-old pensioner, the real-terms increases in the maximum
means-tested benefits were 7 per cent between the introduction
of income support in 1988 and 1997 and 25 per cent between the
election of the Labour government in 1997 and 2001. Back
3
Total inflation between April 1997 and April 2003 would be 16.3
per cent if the government hits its 2.5 per cent inflation target
in 2001-02 and 2002-03. This would imply that the gap between
the MIG for a 65-year-old and the pension would have to have been
just £7.40 in 2003 to have maintained its 1997 value. Back
4
This is in spite of the Chancellor's announcement on pension
uprating in the 2001 Pre-Budget Report, which will only produce
higher pension increases when inflation falls below the target
of 2.5 per cent. Back
5
This holds even if pensioners' private incomes rise in line with
prices over time, as long as patterns of state pension entitlement
and the distribution of private pensioner incomes have fixed shapes. Back
6
This is true of unearned income. The MIG disregard means that
the first few pounds (standardly, £5 for a single person
and £10 for a couple) of earnings are exempt from the 100
per cent withdrawal rate. Back
7
The government describes the calculation for those over 65 in
two parts-a pound-for-pound income top-up (100 per cent withdrawal)
followed by payment of a "savings credit" (at 60 per
cent of private income possessed). But the process is more simply
captured by being described as a single calculation with 40 per
cent withdrawal (100 per cent minus 60 per cent). Back
8
The Pension Credit: A Consultation Paper, Cm. 4900, The
Stationery Office, London, 2000. Back
9
Department for Work and Pensions, The Pension Credit: The
Government's Proposals, London, 2001. Back
10
T Clark, Recent Pensions Policy and the Pension Credit, Briefing
Note no 17, IFS, London, 2001 (www.ifs.org.uk/pensions/bn17.pdf). Back
11
Source throughout this section: TAXBEN run on Family Resources
Survey 1998-99. TAXBEN produces output in 2001 prices. Modelling
assumptions are described at the beginning of Section C. Back
12
Department for Work and Pensions, Income-Related Benefits:
Estimates of Take-Up in 1999-2000, 2001 (p 15) (available
from DWP website: www.dwp.gov.uk). Back
13
Our modelling assumes constant demographics and that the distribution
of private pensioner incomes has a constant shape. The government
may invoke more sophisticated assumptions on these points, which
could give rise to an additional estimated expenditure. Back
14
Department for Work and Pensions, The Pension Credit: Long-Term
Projections, London, 2002 (available at www.dwp.gov.uk/publications/dwp/2002/pencred/pencred.pdf). Back
15
The Pension Credit: A Consultation Paper, Cm 4900, The
Stationery Office, London, 2000 (pp 22-3). Back
16
Department for Work and Pensions, The Pension Credit: The
Government's Proposals, London, 2001 (p 5). Back
17
For more details, see T Clark, Recent Pensions Policy and
the Pension Credit, Briefing Note no 17, IFS, London, 2001
(Section B(4)) (www.ifs.org.uk/pensions/bn17.pdf). Back
18
The Pension Credit: A Consultation Paper, Cm 4900, The
Stationery Office, London, 2000 (p 20 and p 24). Back
19
Withdrawal rate of 91 per cent calculated as follows: [pension
credit taper] plus [(rebates taper) times (income kept after pension
credit taper)], ie 0.40 + 0.85 (1-0.40) = 0.4 + (0.85 × 0.6)
= 0.4 + 0.51 = 0.91. Back
20
The savings credit is potentially worth more to people with especially
high MIG entitlement, such as those with severe disability premiums.
The reform's maximum worth is the reduction in the taper rate
(0.60) multiplied by the MIG entitlement affected. In the typical
case, the benefit affected is £23 (the difference between
a basic pension of £77 and MIG of £100), making the
maximum value of the reform £13.80. Needs for the rebates
will rise by just this amount. But where the relevant MIG is higher,
then the affected MIG entitlement is also higher, as is the maximum
gain. To ensure that none of the gain is consumed in forgone rebates
in such cases, needs would therefore have to be increased especially
sharply. Back
21
The Pension Credit: A Consultation Paper, Cm 4900, The
Stationery Office, London, 2000 (p 23). Back
22
Department for Work and Pensions, The Pension Credit: The
Government's Proposals, London, 2001 (p 10). Back
23
T Clark, Recent Pensions Policy and the Pension Credit, Briefing
Note no 17, IFS, London, 2001 (Section B(5)) (www.ifs.org.uk/pensions/bn17.pdf). Back
24
T Clark, Recent Pensions Policy and the Pension Credit, Briefing
Note no 17, IFS, London, 2001 (www.ifs.org.uk/pensions/bn17.pdf). Back
25
However, these numbers are expressed in 2003 prices, and we do
not want to have to make too many guesses about what the rest
of the 2003-04 tax-benefit system will look like. Instead, we
deflate the illustrative numbers by assumed inflation of 2.5 per
cent between 2003-04 and 2002-03, and then model the reform as
if it were being introduced in 2002-03. Back
26
Each adult aged 65 or over is given equal weight. Couples where
both partners are over 65 are therefore given twice as much weight
as single pensioners. Back
27
These averages are across all "pensioner families",
ie single people over retirement age or couples where the man
is 65 or over. This implies differences from the 65+ definition
we have used in constructing Figure 4 (see footnote 26). If the
same basis as for Figure 4 is used, then the average gains are
£5.73 for single people and £6.81 for couples. Back
28
This figure is approximately in the middle of the range of estimates
for the non-take-up of entitlement that we cited in Section B1. Back
29
See Department of Social Security, Households Below Average
Income, 1998-99, London, 2000 (p 127), which is also based
on the 1998-99 Family Resources Survey. It suggests that 21.5
per cent of pensioners lived with below 60 per cent of contemporary
median income and that 35 per cent lived with below 70 per cent
of contemporary median income. Back
30
There are other possible reasons for the divergence-for example:
the income definition is slightly different from the before-housing-costs
measure in the HBAI; the table is only for those aged 65 or over,
whereas the HBAI includes women of any age if they are married
to men aged 65 or over. Back
31
For a fuller discussion, see T Clark, Recent Pensions Policy
and the Pension Credit, Briefing Note no 17, IFS, London,
2001 (Section B(6)) (www.ifs.org.uk/pensions/bn17.pdf). Back
32
The main group of pensioners left with an EMTR of 100 per cent
are those with pre-means-tested-benefit incomes of less than the
basic state pension. Back
33
See T. Clark, Recent Pensions Policy and the Pension Credit,
Briefing Note no. 17, IFS, London, 2001 (Section B(3)) (www.ifs.org.uk/pensions/bn17.pdf). Back
34
This will happen, for example, if rents and local taxes increase
more slowly than the maximum income required to exhaust pension
credit, which will rise more rapidly than earnings. In these circumstances,
over time, some of those initially entitled to rebates but not
pension credit would become entitled to pension credit and so
face an increased EMTR. In addition, if rebate "needs"
increase more slowly than the income that exhausts pension credit
entitlement, then the proportion of the band of incomes over which
the savings credit is received before the tapering of rebates
begins will decline. Back
35
This will apply in couples where neither partner was born before
1935 and where the joint income is sufficiently low to attract
pension credit, but where income is concentrated on one partner,
which can mean that his/her individual income exceeds his/her
personal tax allowance. Back
|