Select Committee on Education and Skills Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 1-19)

WEDNESDAY 20 NOVEMBER 2002

PROFESSOR STEPHEN GORARD, PROFESSOR JAMES TOOLEY AND PROFESSOR RICHARD PRING

Chairman

  1. May I welcome three eminent professors who are going to help the Committee with their wisdom and research this morning, Professor Tooley, Professor Gorard and Professor Pring. Professor Pring and I have known each other a very long time, so welcome Richard and Stephen and James and thank you very much for spending some of your valuable time in helping the Committee. You will know that the Committee has set this whole Parliament to look at secondary education. We have done a great deal of work on higher education in the last couple of years, on pre-school and individual learning accounts and other things, but in terms of inquiries we have been away from what some people would describe as mainstream education for some time, certainly secondary education. Therefore we are looking at the diversity agenda, the Government's commitment to have a whole range of different kinds of schools, what we believe is their linking of that with attainment of schools. We are then going to be looking at retention and recruitment of teachers, we are going to be moving onto admissions policies and we are going to be looking at performance of particular groups of pupils. Four parts to our inquiry and we shall be reporting them out individually. This morning's evidence is really around the diversity agenda. Thank you very much for the memoranda you have presented to us prior to this meeting; they have been most useful to the Committee and most illuminating. May I ask whether you in turn would like to say a few words to open up the discussion from your side?

  (Professor Tooley) Having been expressly informed that we were not going to be asked to do that—

  2. It would seem discourteous not to give you a chance to.
  (Professor Tooley) You received my paper on Choice in Education: Global Examples and Evidence. What I am particularly interested in is the range of market approaches to education which are used around the world. I have given examples here of approaches in America and Europe, but I must be clear that there are also examples in Africa, in Asia, in every country imaginable. Some of the examples are particularly interesting when you see surprising places using some sort of private provision to enhance diversity; those in this report are the private grammar schools Germany and other examples which are equally surprising, as in the Swedish universal voucher system, one of only two anywhere in the world. There is a lot here to be going on with and I look forward to your comments on them.

  3. Surprising in what way?
  (Professor Tooley) Surprising as far as vouchers are concerned. We are often told in debates that these are right-wing ideas, that they find favour only in America and the Anglo-Saxon world. To see the most Social Democrat Government in Europe introducing vouchers surprises many. The fact that Germany has a higher proportion of children and young people in private grammar schools, secondary schools, than England also surprises many and the fact that these schools can charge top-up fees and still receive state subsidy surprises many because we assume our Social Democrat partners in Europe will not be embracing these privatisation ideas. Surprising to many: encouraging to me.
  (Professor Gorard) May I first of all apologise? I sent in a summary of three strands of the research I have been doing recently. What I could not do was prepare it especially for this inquiry. I gave you what was available off the shelf. I hope that makes sense. I have brought some other material which would back that up, but I am happy to leave that here for you to take away at the end. We are talking about a large number of different projects which converge in different ways. There are two main themes: one is the one about standards, about attainment in schools. My summary of that would be that I have yet to see any convincing evidence that any sector or type of school is differentially effective with equivalent pupils. Obviously there are differences between schools but we are talking about differences between school types. We cannot say that one particular type or sector of schools is particularly better or worse than another. The second strand which you may want to talk about is the potential cost of diversification which is to do with the extent to which social groups are or are not clustered within particular schools or types of schools, that is what I call social segregation, and the extent to which recent policies and possibly future policies might affect the composition of schools.
  (Professor Pring) Very simply, if you are going to differentiate between different groups or different individuals, where that differentiation means an unequal distribution of resources then the onus of proof lies on those who want to make the differences, a very simple principle of justice. In focusing upon today, I came to realise the enormous number of ways in which differentiation is taking place and there is different funding and there are different resources. Yet all this arises from many different initiatives over a period of about 10 or 15 years. There does not seem to be any overall set of principles which justifies that sort of differentiation. In other words, it has grown bit by bit ad hoc and there does not seem to be any overall vision or any overall principle by which that differentiation is justified. The onus of proof does lie on those who want to maintain this unbelievably diverse system of funding and admissions policies that we have. Secondly, particular problems are now emerging over the differentiation which takes place through admissions policies and funding of faith schools. I have to say that until very recently I have certainly been a strong supporter of faith schools, but there are some very real difficulties now. They are not easy ones to be solved and they are not ones with any simple solution because of the history. It does seem to me—and I should like to develop this afterwards if people wish—an issue which our society has to address very seriously and very urgently.

  4. Thank you for that. May I open the questioning? This Committee was particularly attracted to looking at the experience of New Zealand which we visited fairly recently, partly because it seemed to have, in terms of the OECD scores, the PISA study scores, something in common with our own country, that was that a pretty high percentage of people were doing rather well in terms of the scores. When we went to New Zealand, we found a society very similar to ours: a band, 60 to 65%, of the population who seemed to be getting a fairly good education but this tail, for very different reasons this tail of significant underachievement which very much concerned the New Zealand politicians and educators. We have the same problem here, do we not? We have a large number of people getting a pretty good education in this country but a significant tail of underachievement. If diversity is not the answer, what is the answer to tackling this tail of underachievement in our country which to this Committee seems reasonably obvious? Are we wrong to believe this?
  (Professor Tooley) You are asking what other things as well as diversity are required.

  5. Yes.
  (Professor Tooley) You might like to look at compulsion as another aspect in your agenda and particularly, as the White Paper indicates, post-14 when most of the problems of alienation, underachievement and so on occur in this country and in New Zealand and looking at the issue of whether school is the right place for all young people post-14 should be a very important part of that exploration. Certainly the diversity we shall be touching on and the diversity which occurs to a limited extent in New Zealand does not really touch on the types of diversity which are indicated in the White Paper which might be required post-14. Rather than, to put it crudely, giving everyone perhaps a combination of some watered down academic curriculum and some quasi pseudo vocational curriculum post-14, you might want to reconsider whether everyone needs the same type of schooling.

  6. We might want to push you on that in a moment. Professor Gorard, is this idea of two thirds/one third and a big tail of underachievement an accurate picture?
  (Professor Gorard) No, I do not think so.

  7. Good. Tell us why.

   (Professor Gorard) First of all I would have considerable doubts about the genuine effectiveness of international comparisons based on PISA. I am doing some work on PISA at the moment and I have some material here which I should be happy to leave for you to look at. The danger is that because of the different contexts and the different natures of the education systems, even the age banding and the promotion system within different national contexts, the variability that that causes is likely to be much larger than the variation between countries. Even what appear to be relatively large scores, even ignoring the rhetorical ranking you get in these international comparisons, even when the scores appear to show quite large differences, it would be difficult to say these are actually due to differentially effective education systems. That is a general blanket point. In terms of the notion of underachievement, it is one I have had difficulty with because I always wondered what the "under" is in relation to. Terms like "differential attainment" between particular social groups, "lower achievement", are all bound up in this notion of underachievement. We have to consider, if we have what we have been calling this underachieving group, what the assessment system, the qualification system, sets out for them. We have a GCSE system which was the merger of CSE and O levels which were designed for 40% of the relevant age cohort and because of the criterion referencing in the marking we have this year on year move towards higher scores, higher grades. Let us not get into a debate about why that is, that is a red herring. The point is that the assessment system is there to discriminate. I am not advocating it should be, I am just saying that is what it does, it is there to discriminate. You always get some people who do better than others. The other extreme would be simply to allocate everybody some kind of certificate.

  8. A lot of my constituents would say that is all very well and it is very academic, but if 20% of the population of New Zealand leave school with no qualification, whatever the academic niceties of it, many people would think that the education system had failed those children; if 20% of people go out of the school with no qualification, whatever the qualification is.
  (Professor Gorard) I was not advocating the system, I was just saying the system as it is, is set up to discriminate between people. If we had a system where nobody failed any assessment, then questions would also be asked about the reality and nature of the assessment. You could change the form of assessment.

Ms Munn

  9. Are we not talking about underachievement in relation to what we might expect people to be able to achieve?
  (Professor Gorard) Yes.

  10. The issue in areas like Sheffield which I represent is that you see proportionately fewer people getting the qualifications and not based on the fact that they are less intelligent. Surely that is what we are talking about? Not whether anybody should ever fail an exam but whether people are being given the kind of teaching and behaviour to learn in order to fulfil their individual potential.
  (Professor Gorard) I am sorry if it sounds very academic, but you then have the perennial problem. If you take a psychological prediction of how well you would expect an individual to do in any future assessment, then you have a discrepancy between how they do and how you predicted, you have now way of knowing whether it was the final assessment or your original judgement which is wrong.

  Chairman: We do not mind you sounding like an academic because you are one.

Ms Munn

  11. That is in relation to an individual. What we are actually talking about is large parts of the country and usually we are talking about poor estates, we are talking about people overall. My colleague here is from Barnsley where classically people do not achieve, yet they have done intelligence testing of kids going into school and the kids going into school there are no less intelligent than kids going into school in Oxford overall. So why are they not doing as well in Barnsley or Sheffield as they are in Oxford?
  (Professor Gorard) May I talk about South Wales which is an area of quite high deprivation where I have done considerable work? People have been suggesting that there was considerable underachievement there. It was said that the worst schools were schooling children to fail because standards had been lower than they had been in England. Where we have done comparisons between Wales and other regions of either England or Scotland which had similar economic and social profiles then the scores were pretty much as you would expect. If you did a contextualised value added analysis of what you expected pupils to achieve, then they were achieving pretty much what you would expect. The point is if you try to compare in some sort of league table system children from Kensington and Chelsea with children from Blaenau Gwent and then say because the children from Blaenau Gwent are not getting such high scores, even though they may do well on cognitive attainment tests, they must be underachieving.

  12. That sounds like you are saying it is okay for poor kids to do badly.
  (Professor Gorard) No, I am not. It is an odd thing for an educationist to suggest, but I resent the logic which says that we know there is a strong link between poverty and educational attainment, so let us do what we can for the poor children to improve their educational attainment. To some extent that is putting too much emphasis on education. Why do we start from the supposition that we should continue to have poor children? Why not deal with that issue first and then see what pans out in education?

Chairman

  13. In reality we want to do both at the same time, do we not?
  (Professor Gorard) Yes.

  14. There is a rather pessimistic note in the material you sent us in the sense that you say many times that the real link is between poverty and underachievement, do you not? Are there not examples where children from poor backgrounds achieve significantly better than children from poor backgrounds in other parts and other schools?
  (Professor Gorard) Those are the kinds of issues which the school improvement agenda is trying to tap into to see what we can learn. I do not think we can have a blanket policy of borrowing or practice of borrowing from sectors or countries or even regions. That is the point I was trying to make at the beginning. It is not a question of looking to the Pacific Rim and saying we will deal with these underachieving children in that way or looking at particular sectors of schools and saying we should be more like them or decorate our foyers in the same colours. Quite often the way in which these children are brought through depends on a charismatic teacher as much as anything else, the kind of thing for which you cannot bring in blanket legislation.
  (Professor Pring) In many respects the Government, both in this and the previous administration has put its finger on one very important thing and that is that education begins very early and one really has to put more resources into early years. Anybody who works in and is connected with the reception classes and early classes in our primary schools will realise that many youngsters come to school at the age of five already deprived in the social skills which are going to enable them to perform well, but also in a whole range of other things. In tackling the problem which you identified, the focus upon early years in terms of resources and making sure there is good teaching has been a very good point in this present Government. Secondly, quite frankly you are going to continue to achieve badly if you do not learn to read and write. The stress upon literacy and numeracy which the Government has pursued, often against certain opposition, has been right. One can criticise aspects of it and the rigidity of it in some cases. Nonetheless I think these were two policies which were quite correct in redressing these problems. We are now beginning to see the consequences of that. There is no doubt there are more people achieving well in secondary schools than was ever the case before. It is a bit like turning around a battleship, is it not? I do feel that there have been significant changes. One further point which I should like to make is that there is certainly no doubt that there was a need to tighten up the curriculum framework in the 1980s and 1990s. There were lots of stories going back, I do not need to spell them out, where we feel many young people were deprived, often because of certain attitudes. A lot of work in the 1960s in America more or less said that schools do not make much difference. I think that permeated the consciousness of many people. There has been a changeover now and people do know that schools make a difference and we are benefiting a great deal from that. At the same time, having got to that stage, I do believe that there is a need for loosening up, often the things which constrain imaginative and good teachers in responding to the kind of needs as they perceive them in particular areas. There is a frustration with many teachers having to pursue a curriculum with some young people where they feel this may not be altogether appropriate. We have to be careful here. Nonetheless I think that is the case. Whenever I go to New York, where I was a fortnight ago, I always work in a particular school, which is within the state system. In New York there is a collection of what is called the consortium of essential schools, which are all within the state school system but which have been really freed to enable them to develop quite imaginative approaches to learning and to curriculum for people in Manhattan, in Brooklyn and so on. One sees some quite remarkable changes there. It is often due to a different sort of relationship, a different school, often with young people, as in the school that I was in, from every conceivable ethnic background and often people who have been ejected from their own schools. I should like to see now, in addressing some of the problems you have talked about, the possibility of experimenting with smaller schools, where personal relationships are very, very important in order to motivate those young people. There is room now for enabling teachers to have much greater professional freedom in tackling some of the sorts of problems you have been talking about.

Mr Turner

  15. Who is the guardian of the child's interest in your picture of how education should work?
  (Professor Pring) Essentially the parent in partnership with the school. I say in partnership because you cannot just hand it over. The idea that parents know best was part of Choice and Diversity, John Patten wrote it. Quite clearly in many cases parents do not know best. Teachers very often know best for those particular children. So it has to be a very close partnership between the school and the parents in developing the education agenda of those children.

  16. What do they see as the objective of the diversity agenda? Unless we are more or less agreed on what the objective is we cannot tell—
  (Professor Pring) My view which I put in my paper was that there is no one overall objective. If you look at the very different kinds of diversity, the very different sets of funding, the very different admissions policies, which have grown without any kind of rational basis over a period of about 20 years, you cannot talk about any overall objective.

  17. Indeed. That is why I was going to ask your colleagues the same question.
  (Professor Tooley) What is the objective of this Government?

  18. No, the longer-term diversity.
  (Professor Tooley) I must say that the word "diversity" is probably a red herring. The words to stress are "choice" and "competition", perhaps "entrepreneurship". Diversity may or may not be an outcome of that. In many areas of our lives diversity does not occur when you have choice and competition. For example, all the men here are wearing suits and ties and we go to supermarkets which are roughly similar, even though they are the result of competition. The diversity aspect is not something which is to be pushed initially. It is something which could be an outcome of choice and competition: it may not be.
  (Professor Gorard) As my comments earlier were suggesting, I am not clear what the problem is that diversification could be a solution to. I am not saying there is no problem, but I am not absolutely clear what that problem is. In the data I read there is not the crisis that I certainly see reported daily through the media in any of the educational components we are looking at here. I am guessing that I was not brought along here to express my opinion on current policies or anything else, but to talk about where the data we have, which is largely based on official statistics, leads me to. I certainly was not intending to be depressing; certainly not intentionally. My intention was to look at what the data say. What I am guarding against is having initiatives which are there without clear evidence to solve problems which have been unclearly formulated. The first thing to work out is exactly what the problem is that we are trying to sort out. One of the papers I sent you was looking at what we call the determinant of school compositions and there seem to be three major chunks. Geography was a clear one. We have already mentioned geography and it has to be the main thing. Where you live largely determines where you go to school. One of the indications about the major determinant of where people go to school and therefore the outcomes of those schools by whatever mechanism would be, rather than thinking about specialisation or diversification, some form of extra money, if there is extra money to be had, to be given to those areas which actually need it and making the grants or awards geographical. The second major determinant is the type of school organisation. What is absolutely clear is that currently areas which have more diversification, different types of schools, have more socially segregated intakes to their schools. As we know from the school effectiveness and school improvement literature that can have an effect on outcomes. Outcomes are very sensitive to the compositions of schools, so my view would be that we look at the composition of schools first and that would not necessarily mean you would want to rush straight into diversification. You would want to think about the admission policies. If you take as an example the recent policy of specialism, specialist schools, what appears to happen is that in areas where specialist schools are prevalent, there is more segregation than in areas where they are not. The majority of the long-standing specialist schools have also tended to be either voluntary aided, voluntary controlled or foundation schools. What they have in common, and some of the other schools I have put in my study, is that they have different admission arrangements and different over-subscription criteria to the LEA schools with which they are competing in their local markets. In the LEAs where that is not the case, such as one LEA in our study in the south-east of England, specialist schools have to use the same criteria as the local comprehensives and the results from that school are indistinguishable from the other schools in the LEA and the composition of the schools is indistinguishable. It seems to me that what is driving this is not the nature of the schools or even the funding, but the ability to use different admission arrangements to the local area. My last point is to agree with what James Tooley said, which was that in areas where there has been a considerable choice of schools and there has been freedom of movement as there has been in some parts of New Zealand recently, then social segregation actually declines in the period of free choice and diversification was not an outcome. It was not a market-driven/market-led thing. Most of the diversification which Richard Pring was talking about in the system has been imposed by people saying they want these kinds of schools. That is not bottom-up demand. Generally if you have a choice system in schools, what appears to happen is that parents are trying to choose between ranked uniform schools.

Jonathan Shaw

  19. I should like to ask Professor Pring to expand on his idea of piloting smaller schools. You mentioned this briefly. Could you tell the Committee what you think smaller schools might provide?
  (Professor Pring) I am not suggesting that smaller schools are ideal for everybody. Where you get areas where there are particular difficulties because of the social background, the economic context and so on, the personal relationships between teachers and pupils, this personal knowledge, this understanding people very, very well, is extremely important. There may be many young people who do not find it easy to be in schools of 1,200, 1,300, 1,400, with all the implications that has for personal knowledge. Many schools do do a very good job at breaking down these large numbers into units in which there is a great deal of excellent pastoral care. The small school is what really needs to be explored for certain young people at certain ages. It may be defective in certain things, it will not have that range of expertise in the school, but that close personal relationship, establishing good social skills, motivating young people may be much more important in the long run than ensuring they have first-class teachers of history, geography, mathematics, etcetera. I think that is something which is certainly worth exploring. There is quite an interesting movement in this country called The Small School Movement and it is one which ought to be taken seriously. When I have seen this in the United States what happens is that they shape schooling very, very differently. They use the community much more. If they have excellent mathematicians in this school of only 120 pupils aged between 14 and 19 then there is a link to Hunter College just down the road. Where they have particular talents in certain things, they bring in the community and this school is something exciting, one of the few schools in New York now which has managed to get rid of the metal screens whereby they check whether people have knives and guns and so on. They have absolutely transformed relationships in that particular area because of the close intensity of the relationships which take place between excellent teachers and the pupils. I am not saying it would necessarily work but I think there has to be room, in addressing some of the problems which the representative of my home town of Sheffield came across, to start looking at other ways. I do believe that in education, certainly in my education and that of many people here, being in an institution where you really feel you belong, rather like an extended family, can be crucial for certain people.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 22 May 2003