Select Committee on Education and Skills Memoranda


Supplementary material submitted to Education and Skills Select Committee

September 16th 2003




Professor John Coldron

Sheffield Hallam University

Contents

1. Findings concerning the choice process - schools and parents

1.1  Use of performance tables and likelihood of opting away from local school:

1.2  Do parents demote their favourite school?

1.3 Likelihood of parents being offered their favourite school:

1.4 On the characteristics of schools that parents class as their favourite school.

1.5 Characteristics of parents who appeal:

2: LEA procedures for expressing a preference

2.1  How many LEAs use equal weighting of parents' expressed preferences?

3. The management of preferences in wholly selective areas

3.1 Selective areas

3.2 Problems of admission management in selective areas:

3.3 Ways in which selective LEAs try to solve the problem:

3.4 Adjudicator rulings:

4. Management of the problem in areas that are not wholly selective but have wholly selective schools within their area

4.1 LEA practice:

5. Access to tests for places at a selective school

5.1 Opting in or opting out?

5.2 Possible problems with non-universal systems:

6. Evidence as to the educational benefits of selection

6.1 Evidence from Schagen and Schagen and PISA

7. Proposals and recommendations

7.1  The need to accommodate different solutions

7.2  Issues to be considered

7.3  Proposals and recommendations

1. Findings concerning the choice process - schools and parents

1.1 Use of performance tables and likelihood of opting away from local school: There are a number of relevant findings in the nationally representative survey conducted by the Office for national Statistics for our joint DfES study (Flatley and Williams 2001) into the experience of parents. The figures are for 1999/2000.

The findings provided further evidence that parents consider a whole range of criteria of choice and that the academic performance of the school is only one. For example a minority of parents (39%) used performance tables to find out about schools. However parents among whom the mother had a degree or above were nearly twice as likely to consult them as those among whom the mother had no educational qualifications.

We also found that parents in London, those with higher educational qualifications and those in occupational classes I and II were more likely to opt away from their nearest school (see Table 1). This shows that parents who live in London were six times more likely to apply for a place outside their own LEA area than parents who live in a Shire authority and that parents where the mother had never had paid employment were three times less likely than those in Social Class I or II to have applied outside their own LEA; and where the parent had no educational qualifications they were half as likely (two times less likely) to have applied outside their own LEA (see Table 1).

Table 1 Likelihood of parents applying for a place in a school outside their own LEA area (based on odds ratios from logistic regression)
Characteristic Odds ratios 95% confidence intervals
Lower Upper
Highest educational qualification
Degree or equivalent or higher
1.0
..
Other qualifications
0.5
0.40.9
No qualifications
0.4
0.20.7
Social class of mother
I & II
1.0
....
III non-manual
1.0
0.71.5
III, IV & V manual
0.9
0.61.4
Never worked
0.3
0.20.6
Parental LEA type
London borough
6.3
4.29.4
Metropolitan authority
1.3
0.82.0
Unitary authority
2.6
1.83.8
Shire authority
1.0
....
Nagelerke R2
0.1

1.2 Do parents demote their favourite school? Members were interested in whether there was a difference between the school that parents stated on the application form as their first preference and the school they would 'really' have preferred. The ONS analysis covered this aspect of parental choice to some extent. Parents were asked if there were any state schools they had not applied to but would have preferred their child to attend. Eight per cent of parents reported that there were. In addition the survey collected the names of all schools to which parents applied for a place. Parents were asked which of these schools they most wanted their child to attend. For the purposes of analysis this school was referred to in the report as the parent's favourite school. It is therefore possible to infer what proportion of parents demoted their favourite school to a lower preference in the ranking of their application form. The survey found that while 92% gained entry to the school they had put as their first preference 85% reported that they had gained their favourite school. This indicates that about 7% had not put their favourite school as their first preference. The results are presented in Table 2.

Table 2: Outcome measures by cohort
% offered a place in Entry cohort of selected child
Sept 1999

%

Sept 2000

%

Total

%

In a preferred school
Favourite school 8981 85
First preference school 9391 92
Any school for which preference expressed 9795 96
In a school for which no preference stated 35 4

Weighted base
1192 977 2170

1.3 Likelihood of parents being offered their favourite school: It was found that there was not a strong relationship between the background characteristics of parents and the likelihood of being offered a place in their favourite school. However parents in London were an exception and were the least likely to be offered a place in their favourite school (an odds ratio of 0.3:1.0 compared with the reference category of Shire authorities). While nationally 85% of parents were offered a place in their favourite school in London only 68% receive such an offer. Nationally, 4% of parents were offered a place in a school for which no preference had been stated. Nevertheless, among these parents around half reported they were satisfied with the school they had been offered.

1.4 On the characteristics of schools that parents class as their favourite school. Six in ten of the favourite schools (as defined earlier) had higher than average GCSE performance scores than their LEA average. When compared to national figures for the proportions of pupils eligible for free school meals, 46% of favourite schools fell within the two lowest national quintile groups (i.e. in the 40% of schools with the lowest proportions of students receiving free meals). Fifteen per cent of the favourite schools were in the 20% of schools with the highest proportions of students receiving free school meals.

When the odds of all the different factors in combination are examined, parents who had no previous experience of choosing a secondary school, were owner occupiers, lived in London boroughs, had a degree level qualification or above and were in Social Class I and II had the highest odds of choosing a favourite school with a high GCSE performance score. They were three times more likely to do so than those parents in the reference category (who differed from them in having previous experience of choosing a secondary school and in living in a Shire authority). Parents who had the lowest odds of choosing a secondary school with a high GCSE performance score had previous experience of choosing a secondary school, lived in social sector rented accommodation, lived in a Shire authority, had no qualifications and were parents among whom the parent had never worked. This group of parents were about eight times less likely than the reference group of parents to choose a favourite school with a GCSE performance score above the LEA average.

1.5 Characteristics of parents who appeal: Five percent of parents in the nationally representative survey reported that they had appealed (n=129). In general, these parents did not vary by background characteristics. In other words there was no greater likelihood of a middle class parent appealing than a working class parent. In our work for the DfES project on Appeals panels (Coldron et al 2002) panel members reported their impression that there were now greater numbers of working class appellants. We also found that there was no greater likelihood of a middle class parent winning an appeal i.e. the Social Class of an appellant bore no significant relation to whether the appeal was successful or not (n=317).

2: LEA procedures for expressing a preference

2.1   How many LEAs use equal weighting of parents' expressed preferences? The question was raised as to how many LEAs used an equal weighting procedure. The nationally representative survey (Flatley and Williams 2001) found that 66% of parents were asked by their LEA to list their preference for school, on their application form, in rank order.

In Stage One of the same project (Williams et al 2001) we analysed all eligible LEAs in England (n=141) and categorised their procedures for allowing parents to express a preference. This data relates to the procedure for September 2000 entry. Finding a means of categorising LEA modes of practice which captures the complexity that exists, whilst ensuring that a useful and usable typology was developed presented several challenges. In some areas LEA admission procedures applied to such a small proportion of schools that describing the LEA mode of practice did not provide a meaningful description of the procedures that many parents experienced there. The procedures found in the composite prospectuses were categorised into four types.

Type 1: Multiple preferences - Rank order

The parent is invited to name a number of schools as preferences in rank order and the LEA admission authority attempts to allocate them a place at their first choice school. Though the first choice takes precedence in the majority of cases it is not guaranteed that a parent's first choice will take precedence over someone else's second choice. There are circumstances where a second choice takes precedence, particularly if this means a pupil would be spared a long or difficult journey to an alternative school. Sometimes a multi-stage process is involved where parents may be asked to enter the next stage of the admission procedure and identify further preferences if they have been unsuccessful with their initial preferences.

Type 2: Invitation to accept a designated school or choose another

Parents are notified of a place allocated at a school chosen by the LEA on the basis of the general admission arrangements of the authority and invited to confirm that particular school as their expressed preference or to name one or more alternative preferred schools. The parent must confirm in writing that the allocated school is acceptable otherwise it is treated as a non-preference and no place is reserved. This procedure is most commonly used in those areas where a catchment or priority area system is in place. How the consequences of this are handled by LEAs varies considerably. Some LEAs state explicitly that not putting the designated school down as first preference may mean that a place is not available at this 'local' school should they be unsuccessful in gaining a place at a different first preference school. Other LEAs state explicitly that parents who put their 'catchment 'school down as a second preference who do not get their first preference will not be treated any less favourably than a parent who chose the catchment school as their first preference.

Type 3: Multiple preference equal weighting

Parents are asked to express multiple preferences and each preference is given equal weighting. LEAs then allocate to one of those preferred schools on the basis of their general admission arrangements. This is often in context where the admission system is complex involving a number of admission authorities. In such circumstances the procedures can seem to be complex unless there is a common admission timetable and a common application form as is now required by the new Code (DfES 2003).

Type 4: Single preference system

Parents are invited to express a single preference and if this proves unsuccessful they may apply to alternative school(s) in a second stage of dealing with preferences.

Table 3: Frequency of procedures for expressing a preference (Sept 2000 entry)
Type of system
No. of LEAs
% of LEAs
Multiple preference rank order
105
74
Invitation to accept designated school or express a preference for other school(s)
18
13
Multiple preference equal weighting
7
5
Single preference
11
8
Total
141
100.0

3. The management of preferences in wholly selective areas

3.1   Selective areas: Although only a minority, selective admissions present very different issues of management for both school admission officers and parents. The official definition of a selective LEA is one where over 25% of the pupils attend selective grammar schools. There are other areas such as Chelmsford and Colchester in Essex, or Ripon and Skipton in North Yorkshire where all of the schools reasonably available to parents are organised as either selective grammars or secondary moderns. But because these are sub-areas within larger LEA districts the LEAs are not classified as wholly selective. All wholly selective areas use some version of a standardised test of general ability administered at 11+. In practice this was either one produced by an independent research organisation such as the NFER or one developed within the LEA itself. We deal in turn with two aspects of admissions in these areas -the first being the allowance of two first choices and the second being access by pupils to selective tests.

3.2   Problems of admission management in selective areas: The advent of open enrolment highlighted a tension between the new inclusive principle that gave parents the theoretical right of attendance at any school of their choice and the older exclusive principle of selection. This, and the requirement to take account of parents' expressed preference creates a difficult issue for parents who wish to apply for a selective place if, at the time of stating their preference, they do not know if their child is eligible for a selective school place. If they express a first preference for a place at a selective school and their child does not reach the required standard (or too many do) it is possible that they would not get their preferred non-selective school because that school may already have reached its admission limit through the allocation of first preferences.

3.3   Ways in which selective LEAs try to solve the problem: In the event of a child not gaining admission to a first choice selective school some wholly selective areas manage this difficulty for parents by allowing the next non-selective school preference to be deemed a first choice equal with those other parents who had expressed this as their actual first choice. Thus, parents who apply to selective schools are advantaged over other parents who for whatever reason do not apply. We found two variations of this default process. One is to maintain separate selective and non-selective school preference lists deciding which to use when the child's 11-plus result is known. The second way is to require parents to express preferences for selective and non-selective schools on a common form. If it turns out that the child is deemed ineligible for a place at a selective secondary school the highest preference non-selective school becomes, by default, the first preference. These systems have either been accepted by parents and schools, or at least have operated without any effective objection, over a number of years.

3.4   Adjudicator rulings: While the 1998 Education Act reaffirmed both open enrolment and then existing systems of selection the legislation also created the Office of the Schools Adjudicator thereby creating a process for challenging the admissions practices of schools as admission authorities and of LEAs. The Schools Adjudicator has ruled against the default procedures described above in two important determinations one concerning Wirral and the other Torbay. In Wirral the adjudicator decided that tests for selecting to secondary schools should, under the Authority's admission arrangements, take place after rather than before all parents had expressed a preference for the school they wanted their child to attend. The implications of the Torbay Determination are that tests for selection to secondary schools should follow and not precede the invitation to all parents to express a preference.

4. Management of the problem in areas that are not wholly selective but have wholly selective schools within their area

4.1   LEA practice: A system adopted by a number of areas which are not wholly selective but have one or two selective schools in their area is to ask parents to express preferences for both selective and non-selective schools on a common form without first knowing if their child is eligible (i.e. has reached a high enough score in the test) for a place at a selective school. The tension mentioned above between the inclusive and exclusive principles is addressed directly by some LEAs. For example one LEA states clearly in its composite prospectus:

'If you enter your child for the 11plus you should bear in mind that a place at your local comprehensive school or community college cannot be reserved in the event that he or she does not gain a grammar school place.'

In this case advice was then given about the previous year's entry (what marks children had and what marks those who were given a place had). This would have had the effect of reassuring those parents whose children's measured attainment to date was well above average but would put pressure on those considered borderline. It represented a risk for these parents but it allowed most parents to make a reasonably informed choice. Of course the 'pass' mark may change each year as the number of students achieving those marks increases or decreases. The local authority acknowledged the fact that,

' … A place is not guaranteed for a candidate who qualifies for a place under the 11plus selection arrangements…The guarantee of a grammar school place was necessary in the past when the only alternative was a secondary modern school, which did not cater for pupils of grammar school ability. Nowadays suitable alternatives are available at comprehensive schools and community colleges that cater for the whole academic ability range.'

This robust position is replicated in a number of other areas and would tend to facilitate comprehensive (all-ability) intakes at the non-selective schools in the area.

5. Access to tests for places at a selective school

5.1   Opting in or opting out? A significant aspect of the admission process to selective schools is how children are entered for the test. We found that there were different ways in which this happened. In some areas all children in the last year of primary school were entered for the test (with parents able to withdraw them by request). This method of entry was common for wholly selective areas. It provides universal access and raises no obvious equity issues beyond those generally associated with selective systems. In other areas children were entered on the primary school's recommendation (with parents able to include them by request). This involves, as a formal part of the process, a discussion with primary school staff about the child's secondary education and raises questions about the status of primary schools' judgements and recommendations. Because there is an element of judgement at this early stage in the child's school career it is possible that some primary schools may inappropriately close off an opportunity for some children.

5.2   Possible problems with non-universal systems: There is also the possibility that parents will differ in how they act on the primary school's recommendation. In addition we know from the extensive work on how parents choose a school that there are significant differences in the way that parents from different social groups respond to information and to the task of choosing. In other LEAs, and for all wholly selective Voluntary Aided and Foundation schools, parents must request that their child take the test as part of the application to the school. Skilled and semi-skilled choosers, who tend to be from more advantaged families, will do this more readily than those who are less engaged with the process of choice.

6. Evidence as to the educational benefits of selection

6.1   Evidence from Schagen and Schagen and PISA: Members asked about the evidence as to the educational benefits of selection. I explained that as I read the evidence the differences between the two systems in terms of exam performance was very small. I quoted two pieces of recent evidence and present them here with more precision than was possible in the hearing. Ian and Sandie Schagen of the NFER have produced authoritative work (Schagen and Schagen 2002) concerning the effects of selection in 149 LEAs in England. They considered the effects at the level of the school (i.e. for the pupils attending grammar or comprehensive schools) and at the LEA level (the effects for the whole cohort of children in the LEA). At the level of the school there were significant differences but at the level of the LEA there was no significant difference between selective and non-selective. Specifically they concluded that at the level of the school 'there is a large 'grammar school effect' which shows that borderline pupils - those who narrowly obtain a grammar school place - obtain much better GCSE results five years later than pupils of equal prior attainment in comprehensive schools' and on the other hand that 'pupils of higher prior attainment (key stage 2 average level greater than 5)' fared better in comprehensive schools. They hypothesise that these two gains at school level balance out so that there is no difference between the systems in the performance of children at GCSE at the LEA level.

The PISA study looked at the different performance of national systems (OECD/UNESCO-UIS (2003). We should be very cautious about cross national comparisons but the findings are of interest. This study was concerned to investigate any relationship between school and student characteristics and student performance. They found that 'the impact [on educational performance] of school's socio-economic background is much stronger than the effect of any other variable (including school climate, homework, reading engagement etc…..) Ch. 7 p219. They also investigated the factors that were associated with social selection and found that academic selection is correlated with socio-economic segregation, 'Among the ten countries with the most pronounced socio-economic segregation observed in PISA, all carry out selection procedures that channel students into different streams of secondary education before or at the age of assessment.' Ch 7 p220.

7. Proposals and recommendations

7.1  The need to accommodate different solutions: Any set of recommendations needs to be sensitive to the fact that different areas experience different levels of problems. Policies designed to solve chronic problems in London should not make things worse in Cumbria.

7.2  Issues to be considered: We know that the majority of parents want their children to go to good local schools, defined not just in terms of exam performance but also in terms of moral and physical security. They also want predictability and speediness in the admission procedures. The evidence suggests that balanced intakes will reduce the problems of polarisation and are either educationally neutral or beneficial. Further, local contexts must be taken into account. It will therefore take a combination of measures to affect these connected issues. Some proposals are given below.

7.3  Proposals and recommendations

Proposal One: The aim of amendments to admissions policies should be to:

·  encourage balanced school intakes;

·  maximise parental satisfaction with the process, but more importantly, the outcome;

·  increase social justice and maximise overall choice (i.e. not give choice to some by taking it away from others);

·  facilitate cooperation between schools;

·  maximise efficiency and cost-effectiveness as far as possible consistent with other principles;

·  have concern for wider environmental implications such as traffic congestion.

Proposal Two: Responsibilities for admissions to schools should rest with one admission authority for a given area (i.e. VA and Foundation schools should no longer act as the admission authority for their school). One of the things that increases segregation of intakes and increases the difficulty of managing the process of admissions for both parents and admission authorities is the existence of a number (sometimes a majority) of autonomous admission authorities in an area. The new Code (DfES 2003) has made significant moves to increase collaboration and cooperation but it stops short of taking away the ability of schools to act as their own admission authority. There should be consideration of combining the admission responsibilities into one authority for a relevant area. This seems particularly important in London. Clearly there would need to be extensive discussion with interested parties but the relevant area for London would most effectively be drawn to include the whole area where presently there is a great deal of cross border admission. Unifying admission authorities would greatly improve the appeals procedures of Voluntary Aided and Foundation schools which are at the moment poor (Coldron et al 2002).

Proposal Three: Admission criteria should be common within the area covered by an admission authority. A single authority for an area implies that admission criteria should also be common for community, Foundation, Academies and CTCs. For religious schools there would need to be an additional criterion as to religious commitment common to all religious schools in the admission authority but in combination with ability banding to prevent covert selection.

Proposal Four: Admission authorities should seek to maximise parental preference overall rather than giving absolute priority to the first in a ranked list of schools. This is already a recommended model in the new Code of Practice. It allows admission authorities to balance other criteria such as proximity with parental preference to gain optimal satisfaction.

Proposal Five: Schools should be encouraged to join into collaborative federations and there should be active exploration of the possibility of making federations the unit for admission rather than the individual school. This could contribute significantly to reducing polarisation of perception especially if Proposal Eight underpins it and banding by attainment is used to balance intake.

Proposal Six: The major oversubscription criterion for community and Foundation schools should be proximity (or catchment areas based on proximity) and, for Voluntary Aided schools, catchment areas. This is the least worst option and would have the undesirable effect of reinforcing selection by mortgage. Therefore this Proposal needs to work in conjunction with Proposal Eight on resourcing harder to educate children and, in urban areas, the use of banding (perhaps within groups of schools) to mitigate segregation of intake. Admission authorities need to ensure that all schools are able to accept casual admissions of harder to educate children.

Proposal Seven: Selection by general ability should be phased out. This includes partially and wholly selective systems. They are not radically more or less effective educationally but they create greater segregation, generate a lot of appeals and are incompatible with parental preference systems.

Proposal Eight: Resources to schools should follow the child and be based on a calculation of risk factors indicating how easy or hard each child is to educate. A school with a greater proportion of harder to educate children will receive proportionately more resources than a school with fewer children who are harder to educate. We know certain characteristics of children (such as the socio-economic status of their family, their prior attainment, their mobility between schools, and their first language) are highly correlated with their educational attainment at 16. Some are easier to educate than others. We also know that some schools attempt to select the easier to educate and to exclude the harder. The extra resources would encourage schools to better balance their intakes and this would in turn reduce one of the pressures toward segregation and polarisation of perception. It may also have other advantages; for example it would go some way to complement the advantages already experienced by pupils in schools with high socio-economic status intake; it encourages an inclusive rather than an exclusive response from schools; it acknowledges the additional difficulties that schools as institutions have when they have educationally disadvantaged intakes; it would help to reduce some of the competition between schools and therefore provide a sound foundation for the operation of the Admission Forums or the unitary admission authorities and the development of Federations of schools; it addresses one of the main problems of English education which is the low achievement of the middle and lower attainers; it would improve the morale and the retention of teachers in the schools most in need of stability.

Proposal Nine: Greater travel subsidies should only be considered as one among a number of ingredients. Greater real choice may have a role in reducing segregation of intakes in some areas but should not be considered as either adequate in itself or as problem free e.g. an increase in the school run traffic would be an undesirable result. It should be considered as an option in specific contexts.

References

Coldron, J., Stephenson, K., Williams, J., Shipton, L., Demack, S. (2002) Admission Appeal Panels: Research Study into the Operation of Appeal Panels, Use of the Code of Practice and Training for Panel Members School of Education, Sheffield Hallam University for the DfES, Research report RR344

DfES (2003) School Admissions Code of Practice London: Department for Education and Employment

Flatley, J., Williams J., Coldron J., Connolly H., Higgins V., Logie A., Smith N, Stephenson K. (2001). "Parents' Experience of the Process of Choosing a Secondary School." Office for National Statistics and Sheffield Hallam University. DfES Research Report RR278

OECD/UNESCO-UIS (2003) Literacy Skills for the World of tomorrow - Further results from PISA 2000 OECD

Schagen, I. and Schagen S. (2002) Using national value-added datasets to explore the effects of school diversity presented at BERA, Exeter, 12 September 2002

Williams, J., Coldron J., Stephenson K., Logie A., Smith N. (2001). "An analysis of policies and practices of LEA admission authorities in England." in Parent's Experience of the Process of Choosing a Secondary School, edited by J. Williams and J. Flatley: Department for Education and Skills


 
previous page contents

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 16 September 2003