Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Appendices to the Minutes of Evidence


APPENDIX 19

 Memorandum submitted by the Country Land and Business Association (H21)

INTRODUCTION

  1.  The majority of the 45,000 members of the Country Land and Business Association (CLA) derive a significant proportion of their income from agriculture. Thus the CAP Mid-Term Review is of considerable importance to them, and their views, and their potential response, are of direct relevance to this inquiry.

  2.  CLA has publicly recognised that change in the CAP will not be avoidable, in the light of the pressures on the EU Budget, the implications of EU enlargement, the likely outcome of the next WTO round and demographic developments within the EU. Not all UK farming businesses relish the prospect of further CAP change, given the low levels of farming incomes in the UK, and an international background in which the EU's greatest competitor, the United States, has announced plans to increase the support it gives to its farming industry, very significantly.

  3.  Nevertheless, CLA and the European organisation to which it belongs, the European Landowners' Organisation (ELO), are submitting detailed views to the European Commission on how such changes might best be made—in the interests of European consumers, agriculture and the environment. The points made in that submission are in line with this.

  4.  This submission follows the same order of questions as that in the Select Committee's statement, announcing its inquiry.

Will the MTR liberalise EU agriculture? What impact would the reforms have on the negotiations on the enlargement of the EU?

  5.  The European Commission's MTR proposals are a noteworthy initiative to redirect CAP support, particularly against the background of the US Farm Bill. At a time when the US appears to be turning its back on its own bold initiative in the 1996 "FAIR Act" to decouple support from production, the Commission has proposed that the EU should pursue the course of decoupling—at least in the main commodity regimes in which the EU has already moved towards direct payments.

  6.  It is proposed that the direct payments in Pillar one should be decoupled from their current bases of crop areas and animal numbers and paid as "a single decoupled income payment per farm". We refer to them hereafter as Decoupled Direct Payments (DDPs). These payments would be conditional on "statutory environmental, food safety and animal health and welfare standards (cross compliance)" and, for arable farms, enrolment in long-term, 10-year, non-rotational environmental set-aside.

  7.  It is proposed to decouple payments for cereals, oilseeds, proteins, beef, sheep, grain legumes, starch potatoes and dried fodder. The dairy sector, sugar, olive oil and some fruit and vegetables "could follow later". Certain premia for durum wheat and proteins are to be expected from the decoupling. The Commission is silent on wine, tobacco and textile crops.

  8.  Although the exemptions listed above mean that significant areas or agricultural support will not be subject to change under the MTR proposals, nevertheless, the decoupling that is proposed does represent a move towards liberalisation of EU agriculture. If implemented, the proposals would mean that individual farmers would be able to take decisions based on market circumstances rather than considerations of the support they would receive.

  9.  The extent of this liberalisation is qualified by a proposed rule in the proposals to prevent farmers from moving to pastoral to arable farming within the new support system. In the view of the CLA this is illogical and unjustified.

  10.  The relative areas of arable and pastureland should reflect the relative market demands for arable and livestock crops, plus any publicly supported pastureland managed specifically for environmental outputs. Whatever mix of arable and pasture emerges from these processes, there must be due attention paid to good environmental land management. There are already controls on the conversion of permanent grassland to other land uses.

  11.  Other direct payments, such as those in Less Favoured Areas and under Agri-Environmental Schemes, for Organic Farming and stimulating Farm Woodland are, rightly, not to be decoupled. This is because they are already, in effect, payments for non-market environmental services.

  12.  The Commission is at pains to avoid describing "decoupled farm income payments" as attached to the land. However, it recognises that if the land is transferred in whole or in part, then the whole or part of the payment must go with it. The CLA believes both for reasons of principle and practicality the decoupled payments should be attached to land.

  13.  Liberalisation of agriculture in the EU 15 is, overall, necessary to facilitate the enlargement of the Union to absorb 10 new applicant countries, let alone any further accessions in the future. The current CAP could not be applied to the applicant countries, even over a transitional period, without serious burdens on the EU Budget on the one hand—which would not be accepted by many EU member states—and serious distortions to the economies of some, if not all, the applicant countries on the other. That must mean that further change in CAP is needed if enlargement is to become a reality, and also that CAP support, taking account of such changes, cannot be applied to the applicant countries except over a transitional period. The Commission has made proposals for the speed of this transition, and until the MTR negotiations have been completed, CLA is not in a position to comment on whether the Commission's proposals in this regard are sensible and realistic.

  14.  That said, it would be wrong, in CLA (and ELO's) view, for the burdens of enlargement to be placed disproportionately heavily on the agricultural sector of the EU 15. Enlargement is more than an exercise in trade liberalisation—it is a huge political commitment. For that commitment to work across an EU of 25, all sectors of the economy, and all populations of the EU, including the rural and land based populations must be able to benefit. An enlargement that concentrated on transferring support from agriculture in the EU 15 to the applicant countries would fail this test.

  15.  The MTR will not come soon enough to ease the finalisation of the negotiations with the applicant countries, given that the intention is to conclude negotiations in the next few months, and the MTR is about changes in the CAP from 2003-04 at the earliest. The conditions for application of the CAP to these countries—ie how quickly the CAP is to be applied—are more critical to the finalisations of the accession negotiations.

  16.  Whilst liberalisation of CAP support is necessary to enlargement from the EU 15's point of view, it is less welcome within the farming constituencies of those applicant countries, especially Poland, which retain a large agricultural sector and where agriculture is still of political and electoral importance. Liberalisation at too fast a pace will make it more difficult for the governments of such countries to seek a popular mandate for accession to the EU.

How will the proposals affect UK farmers? What will be the impact of capping aid to larger farms and decoupling subsidies from production levels?

  17.  The proposals go further than decoupling. They would also:

    —  Reduce decoupled direct payments by 3 per cent per year, beginning in 2004, with further cuts until a total cut of 20 per cent had been reached by 2010.

    —  Introduce a "franchise", equal to

    5,000 of CAP direct support. Payments within this franchise would not be cut.

    —  Introduce a maximum direct support amount of

    300,000 per holding, known as "capping".

CAPPING

  18.  Estimates vary as to how great would be the effect of the Commission's proposals to cap support to larger farms. In terms of numbers of farms, the figures are likely to appear relatively small, but in terms of the share of production, and thus the average level of support received per hectare in the UK as against other EU member states, the figures are considerably more concerning.

  19.  Nearly all the farms affected in the EU would be in the UK and Germany, with France possibly left unaffected. The arguments against capping are strong and numerous, and apply not only in the UK but elsewhere in the EU too:

    (i)  It is a profoundly anti-competitive measure, which contradicts the first declared objective of the exercise "a competitive agricultural sector". It will slow and may even reverse some desirable restructuring, encouraging very small part-time units not to restructure for fear of payment cuts. This will be especially damaging in the applicant states in Central and Eastern Europe.

    (ii)  The proposal is discriminatory against a few Member States, particularly the UK and Germany, which for historic reasons have some very large farming structures. This discrimination is all the more important because the Commission proposes to change the rules on modulation requiring funds cut from pillar one payments to "revert to Brussels" for redistribution. Whilst the proposed criteria for redistributing the funds to Pillar two have some objective relationship to the purpose of pillar two measures the proposed modulation has no such objective basis.

    (iii)  The use of labour units in scaling the franchise makes no economic sense. It will be difficult to administer. It will have to be able to cope with the use of contract labour, which is increasingly used on larger efficient farms. It provides a direct incentive to discover labour that does not truly exist. It will be open to fraud. It will result in gross unfairness when, for example, two farms of similar area, receiving identical direct payments for their arable crops, are very differently treated because one has a highly intensive horticultural enterprise employing 20 people and the other does not. This could result in one being subject to payment cuts and the other not, and thus one receiving lower payments.

    (iv)  The imposition of ceilings is particularly punitive and crude. The size of the penalty rises with the scale of the farming operation. The largest farming units, employ a significant portion of the employed farm labour force, and are often responsible for the management of some of the finest landscapes in the countryside. These farms are usually engaged in environmental schemes, they manage many sensitive habitats, they are vertically integrated in the food chain, and they are active in collaboration. In short this group are leaders in precisely the areas of agricultural and environmental development which society wants. Many of these advances will be imperilled by the proposed ceilings

    (v)  The imposition of ceilings will distort support on adjacent and similar land. For all farms subject to the capping there will be a dramatic drop in the payment per hectare, which increases with the size of the farm. This can bring about the anomaly that adjacent land on farms below and above the payment ceiling could have payments per hectare with a six-fold difference:

    60/ha to

    360/ha.

    (vi)  In particular, the proposed payment ceilings will penalise co-operatives which are large IACS claimants (both in the West, and prospectively in the East of Europe).

    (vii)  It makes no sense in principle to impose payment ceilings when it is policy to transform the purpose of direct payments into payment for environmental and cultural landscape services. It might be possible to argue that there are some economies of scale in the delivery of these services, and this could justify some tapering in rates of payment per hectare, there are some examples of this in existing agri-environment schemes. But it makes no sense to suggest that above a certain threshold there are zero costs of delivering these services and thus no payment is justified.

THE FRANCHISE

  20.  CLA is opposed to the concept of a franchise, because farms below the franchise threshold will be exempt from progressive cuts in Pillar one support—20 per cent over seven years, referred to in the proposals as "dynamic modulation"—and the requirement for a whole farm audit (see paragraphs 29-30 below).

  21.  The franchise means that UK agriculture will be subject to a much greater absolute extent of modulation than its competitors. Since funds saved through modulation are, unlike capped funds referred to above, to be retained by the EU and only then redistributed through Pillar two, UK agriculture is likely to suffer a very large reduction in overall support in a way that our competitors will not.

  22.  If the UK were unable to raise its share of Pillar two funds from the current 3.5 per cent level, the deficit between those funds modulated and those funds subsequently redistributed to the UK via Pillar two could be very great indeed. The amount "saved" by modulation of UK payments could amount to £600 million per year. Even if the UK were to raise its share of Pillar two to nine or 10 per cent, the amount to be redistributed in the UK through Pillar two might be £400 million, ie a deficit in the order of £200 million per year.

  23.  At current exchange rates, UK agriculture is already experiencing lower levels of support and prices than its EU counterparts. These proposals—unless the cap and the franchise could be removed, modulation ameliorated and the UK's share of Pillar two dramatically increased—would bring about a further significant weakening in the competitiveness of British agriculture.

ENERGY CROPS AND CARBON CREDIT

  24.  This particular proposal could benefit British agriculture and the environment. With the appropriate incentives and fiscal arrangements land management can play a very important role in reducing greenhouse gas emissions by supplying renewable energy (from biomass, bioethanol and wind power) and by sequestering carbon in soils and forests. Creating a scheme of carbon credits is therefore an idea the CLA strongly supports. More work is necessary in devising practical ways of measuring and monitoring the carbon balance of land management systems.

  25.  The CLA is involved in such work and looks forward to working with the Commission to develop it further. We welcome the recognition of the special role for land in managing the carbon economy in the form of the proposed inducement (

45/ha) for energy crops. However, this issue requires considerably more attention and discussion before we can agree the proposed rate. Also the distribution of any aid for energy crops amongst the Member States should relate to the potential for these renewable energy developments and the CO2 reduction.

  26.  CLA has further, more detailed points on the Commission's proposals on decoupling support. These are set out in detail in the Annex to this submission.

What will be the practical effect of the new cross-compliance conditions? Do these adequately balance environmental and commercial concerns?

  27.  If overall CAP policy is to be coherent, direct payments must be subject to environmental conditions. In fact this is already the case. In the Agenda 2000 Horizontal Regulation (2059/99) Article three states that direct payments are conditional on respecting "general mandatory environmental requirements" and most member states have interpreted this as referring to respect for existing environmental law and codes of good agricultural practice. The MTR proposal is therefore essentially to implement the existing regulation in a common EU framework. Whilst agri-environment schemes under Pillar two are the right way to enhance the environment, conditions under Pillar one are the right way to maintain the environmental quality of the landscape. Thus these conditions should remain as they are, at the legal reference level.

  28.  The MTR tries to take cross-compliance further. First, it is suggested that the conditions should be applied to the "whole farm". The environmental rationale for this is plain, but it follows that if the environmental conditions and obligations apply to the whole farm then the payments must also be deemed to apply to the whole farm. In CLA's view it is right in principle to attach the decoupled payments to the whole agricultural area. However, this invites more discussions about the definitions of the land included within cross-compliance obligations—especially where so-called "un-used" land is concerned. This question is pursued in more detail in the attached Annex.

  29.  The Commission proposes to establish a community-wide system of farm audit including "material flows, on-farm processes and equipment relating to environment animal welfare and occupational safety standards". The audit, if it is to be useful, will ultimately have to include all the most important elements of sustainable land management. However, it will take time to get to this position. It must therefore be based on a modular and flexible structure and allow self-assessment. It should embrace economic as well as environmental and social aspects. To provide a basis for area-based payments and to incorporate satisfactorily the various environmental elements the aim should be, ultimately, to link it to digital mapping.

  30.  Considerably more detailed discussion is required to agree the components embraced and how the new audit fits into other comparable systems (eg for NVZs, Crop Protection management plans and Assurance schemes). Clumsily done, this has the capacity to duplicate other efforts, to be extremely confusing, and therefore to be highly counter-productive. There will be a great temptation—which must be resisted—to include too many and too detailed aspects in these audits at the outset. The CLA does not accept that these audits are only necessary for full-time "commercial" farms. Many environmentally important areas are farmed by small, part-time operations and it is vital that they are not excluded from the consciousness-raising benefits of whole farm audits—this underlines the necessity for simplicity at the first stage.

  31.  The proposal to retain the existing (10 per cent) set-aside as an EU-determined, long-term environmental measure is unacceptable. The logic of separating Pillar one and Pillar two is to arrange for delivery of environmental services in the second Pillar agri-environment schemes. As the Commission proposes to switch funds from Pillar one to Pillar two one of the principal ways of using such funds in most Member States will be to enrol more land into broad-application, entry-level, agri-environment schemes. One of the core requirements in such schemes will be to provide improved management of biodiversity, landscape and resource protection (especially of water) through measures including: certain proportions of non-cropped habitat, wide field margins and more secure margins alongside water. It is for Member States and regions to decide the place of environmental set-aside amongst such schemes. This is the correct way to provide the environmental land management, not through arbitrarily imposed, crude, EU-wide, set-aside targets.

Will the proposed re-allocation of funds from direct payments to farmers (Pillar one) to rural development (Pillar two) provide sufficient resources to achieve environmental goals and support rural areas?

  32.  The Commission proposes to redistribute the "amounts saved by modulation" on the basis of three criteria: agricultural area, employment and a prosperity criterion. The idea to distribute Pillar two funds on a more objective basis is welcome. The logical basis is the demand for agri-environment services and investment in rural development. The suggested criteria are, of course, proxies for the demand for environmental services and for rural development actions. It would be easy to criticise the crudity of these indicators, but it is hard to suggest alternative, consistently measured, variables which could apply on a comparative basis for all Member States. CLA therefore accepts the principles for making this redistribution.

  33.  However, the points in paragraphs 20-23 above are as apposite in relation to the availability of funds for agri-environment and rural development as they are in terms of the effect on the competitive position of UK agriculture.

  34.  Detailed, legislative proposals, expected later this Autumn, will give a better indication of the possible effect of the Commission's plans on the UK although it is very unclear whether the negotiated outcome of the MTR will resemble the Commission's proposals. Until the EU as a whole determines;

    —  The balance between cross-compliance in Pillar one and agri-environment in Pillar two.

    —  The rate of "dynamic modulation" from Pillar one payments.

    —  The levels at which any "franchise" on modulation and any capping of support to larger farms will be set.

    —  The criteria for the redistribution of funds to member states under Pillar two.

    —  Whether a "Safety Net" of support should be maintained under Pillar one to protect EU agriculture from the more extreme effects of fluctuations in world commodity prices, weather events, currency movements and shifts in support policy among the EU's major competitors.

It is not possible to make a reasonable assessment of whether the UK will receive an amount from Pillar



 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 21 January 2003