Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Appendices to the Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Eunomia

INTRODUCTION

  1.  This submission focuses primarily on the management of municipal waste. It also adopts a view of the waste management hierarchy consistent with the interpretation of the Waste Framework Directive implied by a Commission Communication arising from a waste management strategy review, endorsed by the European Parliament in a resolution of 1997. This stated:

    "Within the recovery principle, where environmentally sound, preference should be given to the recovery of material over energy recovery operations. This reflects the greater effect on the prevention of waste produced by material recovery rather than by energy recovery" (my emphasis).

  2.  The UK interpretation of the hierarchy is slowly aligning itself with this view, as illustrated in the strategy for England and Wales, A Way With Waste, and most recently, in the Strategy Unit Report, Waste Not Want Not. Indeed, we follow the SU report, and commend it, in making the distinction between "high-in-hierarchy" options (materials recovery, re-use and minimisation) and those generally related to residual waste (energy recovery and disposal).

  3.  Much will probably be made in this inquiry, as usual, of the lack of harmonisation of data across countries being compared with the UK. Yet UK waste management remains, to borrow the term used by an Italian professor recently, "prehistoric". Whatever recycling rates may or may not be, or may or may not include, it is sobering indeed to consider that whilst the average inhabitant in the UK generates residual waste (ie waste remaining after materials recovery) of around 400kg per capita. In leading European situations, this figure is of the order 150kg (with individual households, of course, producing much less). In other words, every man, woman and child in the UK is "throwing away", on average, almost three times as much material as people in, for example Flanders and parts of Austria and Germany.

THE HIERARCHY AND THE BEST PRACTICABLE ENVIRONMENTAL OPTION

  4.  Clarification of this point is intended to orient subsequent thinking in this submission, but it is also important to understand the eclectic role played by "the waste management hierarchy" in orienting thinking about waste management in the UK. It remains the case today that although the hierarchy is intended to orient thinking about waste management, it has an awkward relationship with the concept of "Best Practicable Environmental Option" (BPEO).

  5.  In its twelfth report of 1988, the Royal Commission on Environmental Pollution (RCEP) addressed the issue of establishing the Best Practical Environmental Option (BPEO) to deal with pollution and other environmental problems, and defined it as:

    "the outcome of a systematic consultative and decision making procedure which emphasises the protection and conservation of the environment across land, air and water. The BPEO procedure establishes, for a given set of objectives, the option that provides the most benefit or least damage to the environment as a whole, at an acceptable cost, in the long term as well as the short term".

  This "definition" does not take us very far as regards operationalising the concept. The fine words mask all sorts of problems, including the weight given to serious consultation as opposed to more technocractically based decision making, the degree to which one can establish, on an objective basis, the superiority of one or other approach, the issue of what is "an acceptable cost", and the degree to which any technocractic attempt to rank options is open to public scrutiny and debate.

  6.  Considerable time and effort continues to be devoted to technocractic efforts aimed at illustrating why more or less anything and everything can be promoted as "the best practicable environmental option", as long as one chooses one's assumptions carefully. Indeed, we believe we could present a case, with the assumptions suitably made, to support just about anything as the "BPEO". This catch-all can frequently, therefore, constitute a barrier to the movement of waste up the hierarchy.

  7.  Hence our first recommendation is that, in the absence of clear proof that the waste management hierarchy does not give a guide as to what is the best option (and the burden of proof should clearly rest with those who seek to "buck the hierarchy"), the hierarchy, and not the concept of BPEO, should guide waste management strategies in the UK. This is necessary because of the frequent attempts made by waste management companies and local authorities alike to posit anything and everything as the BPEO in what amounts to "excuses" to engaging seriously with materials reduction, re-use and recovery.

WASTE MINIMISATION/REDUCTION/AVOIDANCE

  8.  At the household level, the number of actions which can be taken by individuals to reduce their generation of waste is considerable. However, this requires sensitisation of consumers to the issues concerned. There are good reasons to believe that for this reason, minimisation will follow recycling, much as it may desirable for the opposite to be the case.

  9.  For this reason, the influence on waste generation of government-led initiatives, either in terms of taxation, other market-based instruments such as deposit-refund schemes, negotiated agreements, or (perhaps less desirably) regulation should not be overlooked. A clear problem here has been that in the domain of "producer responsibility", the fact that the lead is being ceded by DEFRA to DTI implies that in the very area where some action is required to "make measures stick", the responsible government department is the one which seeks to minimise any new burdens, regulatory and otherwise, on industry. This has tended to weaken producer responsibility initiatives, and in the case of Packaging, has tended to deflect the burden of compliance on to local authorities. The net effect is that instead of the burden being shouldered by producers and consumers of specified products, part of the burden has fallen upon the collective of tax payers. The chance of implementing the Polluter Pays Principle is thereby lost, and the opportunity for "making producers responsible" is foregone.

  10.  Our second recommendation is that deposit-refund schemes should be introduced for beverage packaging.

  11.  Our third recommendation is that lead responsibility for Producer Responsibility legislation should be removed from DTI.

  12.  Our fourth recommendation is that a wide ranging investigation of the feasibility of new producer responsibility initiatives should be undertaken (including batteries, tyres, waste electrical and electronic equipment, pharmaceuticals, household hazardous wastes, etc). In each case, these should be designed in such a way that where local authorities undertake activities which support the initiatives, they should be remunerated for this activity in line with an estimate, for example, of the (incremental) costs to them of providing infrastructure for the separate collection of the relevant materials. Only when such considerations are made part of the design of such mechanisms will producer responsibility begin to resemble a polluter/consumer pays mechanism.

  13.  Furthermore, in public sector activities, and other areas of communal activity, there is considerable potential for waste minimisation through, for example:

    —  Use of re-usable equipment, such as crockery and cutlery, in public places/at public events. This can be achieved through lease/hire mechanisms. Some schemes in market places benefit from support for use of dishwashers.

    —  Promotion (in public owned healthcare facilities) of the use of re-usable nappies.

    —  Promotion (in schools, as part of the curriculum—waste from schools is "municipal waste") of waste minimization and recycling activities. This could include establishment of on-site composting facilities, schemes to ensure the use of paper on both sides, etc.

    —  At Christmas and other festival periods, initiatives should be undertaken to encourage giving "experiences not stuff". This type of approach, used in Washington State, aims at both reducing waste and boosting the local economy through encouraging citizens to buy presents in the form of vouchers usable at arts and leisure events.

  14.  Our fifth recommendation is that central government should consider establishing a mechanism to support, financially, local efforts to minimise waste in schools, hospitals, and other areas under local authority jurisdiction in appreciation of the fact that these are likely to be investments which deliver net benefits, environmental and financial, over the medium to long term.

  15.  The other key influence on waste generation is the nature of service provision for waste collection. In recent work, we suggested that the impact of local authorities issuing wheelie bins for the collection of garden waste was to increase the overall quantity of waste collected by something of the order 100kg per household per annum, or around 7-8% of the municipal waste collected per household per annum[48]. This tends to discourage home composting in favour of collection in large bins. This imposes unnecessary costs upon the collection system.

  16.  Our sixth recommendation is that the services provided for the collection of waste have to take into account their potential for "drawing out" of the household more waste than is necessary (with implications for the cost of service provision). Ideally, this implies that schemes for biowaste collection should focus on the denser kitchen waste fractions rather than the garden waste fraction, or the combination of kitchen and garden waste. The inclusion of garden waste acts as a disincentive to deal with garden waste in the garden (through "grass-cycling" and/or home composting). It also constitutes (under current arrangements for paying for waste—see below) a regressive element in cost terms since the wealthiest people tend to be among those with large gardens.

HOME COMPOSTING

  17.  Some local authorities underestimate the role that home composting can play in dealing with garden and some kitchen wastes, and the role that it may already be playing in reducing the amount of waste set out for collection. In parts of Europe, such as Austria, home composting accounts for half of all biowaste management.

  18.  A seventh recommendation is that home composting should be encouraged through demonstration activities (at recycling centres), and the training of volunteers in areas with gardens. Another way to ensure that home composting is not discouraged is through the design of charging mechanisms for waste collection (see next section).

DIFFERENTIAL AND VARIABLE RATE (DVR) CHARGING

  19.  DVR charging schemes, sometimes referred to simply as "variable charging", or "direct charging", or "unit pricing" or "pay-as-you-throw", are schemes which charge householders on the basis of a defined measure (weight, volume, frequency of emptying of bin, number of bags etc) of use of one or more elements of the collection service. In all schemes designed with an incentive effect in mind, the scheme involves levying a higher charge for the use of the residual waste collection service than for those elements of the collection service designed to collect materials separately (for recycling and composting/digestion).

  20.  The United Kingdom is one of few countries where such activities are effectively outlawed in primary legislation, though one scheme—in Blaby in Leicestershire—effectively operates on this principle. The UK appears to be the only country which has a landfill tax in place, but does not allow (not to mention, encourage) the introduction of DVR charging schemes.

  21.  Where these schemes are in place, they have been found to have two effects:

    —  a reduction in total waste generated/set out (the output effect); and

    —  an increase in the use of separate collection systems favoured by the price differential (the substitution effect).

  Both tend to lead to a reduction in residual waste.

  22.  Skumatz, in the US, examined the impact of DVR charging schemes on recycling and reduction. The results are summarised below in Table 1 and indicate that variable charging reduces waste generation by around 6% and produces further recycling of around 11%.

Table 1

SEPARATE EFFECTS OF VARIABLE CHARGING ON REDUCTION AND RECYCLING
Community Comparison Time-Series Comparison
Source Reduction (%)5 to 7   5.8
Dry Recyclables Effect (%)5 to 6   6.9
Garden Waste Recycling (%)4 to 5   4.6
Total Effect of PAYT/VR16 17.3

Source: Skumatz Economic Research Associates (SERA) in Resource Recycling August 2000.


  23.  We were pleased to see the Strategy Unit recommending that "the Government should secure an early legislative opportunity to grant local authorities powers to implement incentive and charging schemes for waste if they want to do so." DVR charging systems work best where convenient systems are available for citizens to reduce their liability to charges through engaging in source separation. In the absence of such convenient systems, the potential for evasive behaviour, such as fly-tipping, increases. This makes clear that one of the key measures used to support waste reduction is a measure which, when intelligently applied, pre-supposes the existence of convenient systems for source separation. DVR charging systems should be deployed, and convenient systems for source separation should be in place. Together, evidence suggests that waste reduction can occur without increases in fly-tipping occurring. The same cannot be said of systems where there is only one bin, that for residual waste.

RE -USE

  24.  As regards re-use, we have discussed above the issue of deposit-refunds for beverage containers. The distinction between what is regarded as waste minimisation, or avoidance, and materials re-use is often blurred (as some of the above examples illustrate). Deposit refunds, and producer responsibility initiatives, can encourage a reduction in waste arisings.

Recycling and Composting/Anaerobic Digestion (Materials Recovery)

  25.  Firstly, one must start this section by saying that the definitions of recycling, and more especially, composting are in urgent need of clear definition. The lamentable absence of any statutory or quasi-statutory standard distinguishing between a) those materials derived from waste which are suitable for unrestricted application, and b) those materials which, because of their physical, chemical and/or biological properties are suitable for application to land only in certain cases, has been a major failing, not to mention a significant loophole, in the existing regulatory framework in respect of waste management, and specifically, the management of biowastes. As long as "composting" remains poorly defined, the obligation "to compost" will be open to abuse by those who wish to take short cuts in respect of the law.

  26.  Linked to this, the categorisation of anaerobic digestion as "energy recovery" rather than a material recovery option is unfair where digestion is of source-separated materials in such a way that the residues from the process are suitable (possibly following a period of aerobic composting) for unrestricted application to land. The digestion of source-separated kitchen wastes ought to offer considerable potential for diversification of on-farm incomes, with the prospect also of low-cost, locally available energy through either electricity provision, or biofuels for use in transport. This type of cross-cutting thinking is exactly the type of imaginative approach which DEFRA ought to be encouraging.

  27.  The "quickest and easiest hit" in respect of separate collection of materials is to be achieved at what are still called "Civic Amenity sites". This is increasingly recognised by local authorities. Relatively basic changes including improved signage, improved layout, improved site supervision and so forth can make rapid changes to the recycling rate achieved at a given site. Allied to enhanced producer responsibility schemes (see above), such a nationwide re-organisation of these sites could deliver, on its own, a doubling of the UK's current recycling rate at very little incremental cost. Indeed, at higher levels of landfill tax, the changes will effectively become cost effective to make (because of increased savings in respect of avoided disposal costs).

  28.  We recommend that all local authorities are encouraged to re-organise their "civic amenity sites", and that the terminology is changed to reflect the new role of these facilities. Consideration should be given to making these sites the responsibility of waste collection authorities rather than waste disposal authorities, once again reflecting the changed role envisaged for these "material recovery parks".

  29.  More generally we recommend a review of the allocation of responsibility for all services related to waste management (specifically, in England, across the tiers of Government). Ideas of potential interest might include: the creation of all WCAs as "waste unitaries", with a duty to devise waste strategy in partnership with neighbours (including consideration for letting of contracts jointly); and the establishment of a financial relationship between WCAs and WDAs under which WCAs received variable tonnage based charges from WDAs related to the types of treatment/disposal services purchased (WDAs would cease to receive notional EPCSSSA allocations for waste disposal).

  30.  When taken together, kitchen waste and garden waste constitute the largest fraction of the waste stream. Separately, they are also significant fractions, but as suggested above, the quantity of garden waste in the waste stream is amenable to influence through the collection mechanism (and through appropriate charging structures in DVR charging systems). Ideally, biowaste is approached in the following manner:

    —  kitchen wastes, with high bulk density, are collected separately in low-cost, flat-bottomed trucks;

    —  garden waste, of lower bulk density, is collected separately at bring sites ("Civic Amenity sites") and/or through using low frequency doorstep collections during peak months.

  This type of system ensures that:

    (a)  waste arisings are not inflated by large, and seasonal deliveries of garden waste into the collection system;

    (b)  home composting is not discouraged;

    (c)  the most putrescible and odorous fractions can be targeted accurately, allowing for a reduction in the frequency of residual waste collections and a reduction in cost; and

    (d)  because the denser kitchen waste fraction is targeted, the lower costs of the vehicle stock can ensure that collection costs are maintained at a low level AND that the frequency of collection of kitchen wastes can (where necessary) be maintained at a weekly level.

  31.  The problem in recent times has been that despite the compelling logic of this type of approach, questions have been raised about the suitability of kitchen wastes for composting. These questions have arisen owing to a concern for the possibility that the spreading on land of the products of composting of kitchen wastes might give rise to the spread of animal pathogens such as the virus responsible for the foot and mouth disease. It is our view that these concerns have been exaggerated, and that the biological treatment techniques for managing waste appear to be being singled out for over-zealous regulation, especially when one compares this with the comparatively lax approach to regulating residual waste facilities such as incinerators (see below). The application of the existing state of knowledge associated with the respective plant types are clearly being treated from radically different epistemological perspectives. It is a sobering thought that a year's work of the Strategy Unit of the Cabinet Office stands to be, potentially, dashed by the approach of DEFRA vets to the issue of composting of kitchen wastes. The only mitigating circumstance for the approach taken is the singular lack of clear waste regulation in the area of biowaste treatment which, had it been in place at the time of the outbreaks of foot and mouth disease and swine fever, might have helped to deflect suspicion from biological treatment approaches.

  32.  We recommend that the risk assessment carried out for DEFRA be a) reviewed to display, transparently, the degree to which the results obtained are based upon i) assumption and ii) clear evidence, and b) supplemented by an empirical study on the incidence of livestock diseases arising from composting carried out through collaboration with those countries with most experience with this treatment.

ENERGY RECOVERY

  33.  The terms of reference for the inquiry ask what is "best practice" in terms of energy recovery. One can say quite unequivocally that no such practice exists in the United Kingdom at present. There are two reasons why one would remain sceptical that such "best practice" could emerge in the current context.

  34.  Firstly, the simple fact of the matter remains that the legislative framework in the United Kingdom, such as it currently exists, does not require best practice in the technologies available. Several European countries—Switzerland, Germany, Austria, Netherlands, Flanders (Belgium) among them—routinely apply standards for emissions of key emissions that are tighter a) than our own and b) than those under European Directives (even those yet to be fully implemented in the UK). Hence, the question arises as to whether the UK should not be applying similar standards under the IPPC Directive, which it would be perfectly entitled to do through specifying better abatement technologies as BAT (Best Available Technology).

  35.  At present, it seems that the argument runs that going beyond what is required in the latest revision of the Incineration Directive is unnecessary because of the cost involved. On the evidence available, we would strongly dispute this in the case of, for example, NOx since under the IPPC Directive, the test is a cost-benefit one, and it would appear that on the basis of our own analysis, the benefit-cost ratio may be as high as 5:1. [49]

  36.  On a much less thorough line of argument, one might say "if it's not too expensive for the above countries, why's it too expensive for us?" Switzerland is one of those countries which is always mentioned as one where "incineration and recycling (46%) co-exist". Most Swiss plants have installed SCR (selective catalytic reduction) as standard for abatement of NOx emissions.

  37.  The Environment Agency's own review of incinerators indicated that as far as NOx abatement is concerned, of the 11 incinerators studied, three employ selective non-catalytic reduction (SNCR), two have flue gas recirculation, one has both SNCR and recirculation, and four have "no provision" for NOx abatement (no info for Wolverhampton). No plant is equipped with SCR to control NOx emissions. This is a lamentable state of affairs.

  38.  The Best Estimate from Enviros as regards NOx emissions per tonne from UK incinerators is around 300mg/m3, about 15 times higher than the level achieved in the best performing European plants, and four times that achieved at "half decent plants" in Europe.

  39.  One reason why incineration and recycling "co-exist" in Switzerland is that the proper regulation of the facilities and their outputs (not just air emissions—the ETH in Zurich has been assessing issues of long-term effects of landfilling ash etc) makes the cost of incineration higher, and makes source separation for recycling/composting/digestion cost-effective from the perspective of local authorities. The same is true in Flanders, Austria, Germany, the Netherlands etc. In Austria, GUA Group (Vienna) carried out analyses that suggested for every tonne of waste separately collected for composting, the net financial saving was

50 per tonne.

  40.  The other reason why best practice is unlikely to be achieved is that the strategic context for deploying energy from waste facilities is frequently misunderstood. In a dynamic strategy—and in the era of Best Value, it is incumbent upon local authorities to challenge themselves rather than maintaining stasis in their approach to waste management—the imperative to "continuously improve" can be (it is not necessarily the case) constrained by resort to investments in capital intense plants which demand—for contractual or technological reasons—a more or less constant throughput of waste materials.

  41.  An emerging approach for the deployment of energy recovery techniques involves the use of energy recovery in the context of what are known as mechanical biological (MBT) treatment processes. In these processes, pre-treatment through "biological drying", followed by mechanical separation, can reduce the requirement for incineration capacity, and increase the flexibility of waste management strategies. The approach is gaining acceptance in Austria, Germany and Italy, and more recently, in the Netherlands and Flanders. Some MBT plants resort to anaerobic digestion processes for the delivery of energy from residual waste, and some make resort to both anaerobic digestion and thermal recovery techniques.

  42.  In the UK, costs for energy recovery facilities are increasing because of planning delays, protests, inappropriate BPEO statements and so forth. The difficulties experienced in "getting facilities in place" relate to poor proposals, concern at the environmental and health impacts, and a lack of transparent and open debate about the issues. These delays might be reduced if the view were taken that these facilities ought to be more tightly regulated, giving greater comfort to citizens in respect of operating performance. Once regulators are trusted in the public eye—and to be trusted, they must be seen to be doing their job—and once facilities are operated to high standards—for which, appropriate standards are required to be in place—it seems likely that the public will at least be more accepting of new facilities. At present, it would seem that the costs of trying to have waste management "on the cheap" is that nothing gets built at all!

  43.  We recommend that the proposals laid down in the Environment Agency's Interim Sector Guidance for incineration should be reviewed in the light of existing best practice in the EU. This review should consider carefully the following issues:

    —  why it should be considered inappropriate for incinerators to be equipped with current best practice abatement technologies given existing practices in other EU Member States.

    —  what form of disposal of air pollution control residues is acceptable in the context of a consideration of the potential long-term effects of disposal in landfills?

  We believe that tighter standards and regulation, with appropriate sanctions in place, are likely to assist in having facilities approved by citizens.

  This approach—proper regulation of the treatment, delivering benefits to human health and the environment—is preferable to an approach based solely on taxation, though an extension of the landfill tax to other residual waste treatments should not be ruled out.

  44.  We recommend that due attention be paid to the flexibility of waste management strategies as they are designed. By flexibility, we mean the ability of the strategy to facilitate increased rates of source separation over time without compromising investments in residual waste treatment.

SUPPORT FOR ENERGY FROM WASTE (EFW)

  45.  The incentive structure for waste management remains "upside down". There are no pecuniary incentives for recycling and composting, yet through the Renewables Obligation, residual waste treatments receive support for the energy delivered. This is despite the fact that European Directives on Landfill, Incineration and Integrated Pollution Prevention and Control will require energy recovery for the facilities' operation. What the Renewables Obligation does is reduce the costs of residual waste disposal. This is exactly the wrong message to send, it undermines the credibility of the Renewables Obligation, and it implies that as the UK renewables target comes into force, electricity suppliers will transfer revenue to landfill operators, and operators of gasification and pyrolysis plants. This money would almost certainly be better spent encouraging the development of "genuine" renewables such as wind power, solar heating, etc. rather than providing rents to the operators of facilities who will be required to generate this energy by law anyway.

  46.  The Strategy Unit report makes a mistake in, on the one hand, recommending that DEFRA and DTI take forward a programme of advice and development of new technologies, and on the other, failing to recommend the removal of the support for residual waste management options which occurs through the Renewables Obligation. In stating that conventional mass-burn incineration would not eligible to issue Renewables Obligation Certificates (ROCs), DTI made reference to the conflicts with the waste management strategy. It is completely bewildering that they should have stopped at incineration, thus allowing energy generated from landfills, gasification and pyrolysis facilities to qualify for ROCs, the sale of which may be worth up to £10 per tonne for some facilities, possibly more, depending upon the trading price of ROCs. [50]

  47.  We recommend that if it is intended that new treatments for residual waste are to be given any form of assistance, this should not be in a form such that it reduces the costs of the facility to the local authority. The emphasis should be upon demonstration facilities and trials. To offer support for the end product—energy—is not the way to encourage a rational development of these facilities, not least since local authorities my be seduced into making over-hasty investments. It should not be the goal of any policy instrument to make residual waste management cheaper (and definitely not when no such instrument exists to reduce the costs of recycling). At the moment, there are too many instruments, often conceived in the energy field, which do this.

DISPOSAL

  48.  In the general sense, we welcome the suggestion in the pre-Budget speech that Landfill Tax will continue to increase in future. However, we doubt that this measure will have a significant impact on municipal wastes in and of itself (the implications for commercial and industrial wastes are likely to be more interesting).

  49.  The increased tax will be made more effective once DVR schemes can be introduced. However, at present, most local authorities are adopting strategies which are heavily shaped by their wish to meet Landfill Directive targets (potentially making, it should be added, any emissions trading bill in waste management a sideshow, since to the extent that all local authorities will seek to meet targets in their own right, the trading of permits is likely to be a marginal activity).

  50.  A much more intelligent of the landfill tax relates to the structure of the tax. It is our view that if residual waste undergoes biological treatment such that it is stabilised prior to landfilling, a lower level of tax should apply than if the material was landfilled as untreated waste. This is a situation which already exists in Austria.

  51.  We recommend therefore that standards be established for "stabilised biowaste" (as part of the wider set of standards for biological treatment—see above) such that material fulfilling these standards qualifies for a lower rate of tax than the standard rate (which could be the lower rate, or a separately established rate). This lower rate would enable continued use of existing landfill void, but in such a way as to reduce the potential for problems associated with landfilling of waste.

CONCLUDING COMMENT

  52.  Countries which have been far more successful in moving waste up the hierarchy do two things:

    —  they ensure that residual waste treatment/disposal is not cheap through a combination of a) regulating residual waste treatments such that high technological standards need to be met, b) landfill taxes, and c) taxes on non-landfill residual waste, such as incineration; and

    —  they give very clear guidance to local authorities in terms of the desirability of source separation, using producer responsibility initiatives, voluntary agreements with local authorities, and providing advice on implementing collection systems, as well as DVR charging schemes.

  53.  This is hardly rocket science. Indeed, it is pretty obvious that such an approach—make residual waste less attractive, and source separation more so—will generate the desired outcomes.

  54.  A clear problem in England at present is the continuing process of opting for sub-optimal strategies. The terms "integrated", and "balanced" have become synonyms for the phrase "we don't know what we want". The existing equivocation, and uncertainty in the policy domain, only deepens the state of near paralysis on the part of those who might otherwise act, if only because—and no one can blame them for this—it's not clear to them what they are being asked to do.

  55.  The truth of the matter is that there are a million and one ways to do what this Inquiry is seeking to do. But whilst individual visionaries may be able to do things without government leadership, policies for which government is ultimately responsible are the ones which offer the best prospects for forging a more sustainable path for resource management in the UK. It seems an appropriate occasion for a House of Commons Committee to ask itself why, when so much could be achieved through some simple decisions and a relatively small amount of money, the decisions remain unmade? Bluntly stated, it's the Government's fault, and there is little point in denying this. It would be nice to think that another of these Inquiries as to "why we're still doing so badly" could be made unnecessary by doing what obviously needs to be done.

Eunomia

6 January 2003


48   Eunomia, Avon FoE and Network Recycling (2002) Maximising Recycling Rates, Tackling Residuals, Final Report to CRN, www.crn.org.uk. Back

49   See D. Hogg and J. Hummel (2002) The Legislative Driven Economic Framework for Recycling in the UK, Final Report to the National Resources and Waste Forum, www.nrwf.org. Back

50   See D. Hogg and J. Hummel (2002) The Legislative Driven Economic Framework for Recycling in the UK, Final Report to the National Resources and Waste Forum, www.nrwf.org. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 22 May 2003