Select Committee on European Scrutiny Seventh Report


2. COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY: MID-TERM REVIEW OF AGENDA 2000 REFORMS


(23670)

10879/02

COM(02) 394


Commission Communication on the mid-term review of the Common Agricultural Policy.

Legal base:
Document originated:10 July 2002
Deposited in Parliament:19 July 2002
Department:Environment, Food and Rural Affairs
Basis of consideration:EM of 29 July 2002, Minister's oral evidence of 11 December 2002 and SEM of 8 January 2003
Previous Committee Report:None, but see footnotes
To be discussed in Council:See paragraph 2.39
Committee's assessment:Politically important
Committee's decision:For debate on the Floor of the House (together with the document on milk quotas)



Background

  2.1  The 1992 reforms of the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) introduced major changes by shifting the emphasis of Community support away from intervention in favour of direct income payments to farmers. However, it was recognised that further changes would be needed both to accommodate the accession of countries in central and eastern Europe, and for the Community to comply with the relevant World Trade Organisation (WTO) rules. This eventually led to the Agenda 2000 measures[2] agreed by the European Council in Berlin in March 1999, which (although considerably weaker than the Commission's original proposals) extended the earlier reforms and consolidated rural development as a second pillar of the CAP.

  2.2  The Berlin European Council also asked the Commission to carry out a mid-term review of the Agenda 2000 reforms, and in particular to examine the development of the cereals and oilseeds markets; to monitor the beef situation; to present a report on the future of the milk quota system, with the aim of allowing the present arrangements to run out after 2006; and to submit an account on the development of agricultural expenditure. This remit was subsequently extended to include the effects of the reforms on the environment and sustainable development.

    The current document

  2.3  The Commission's mid-term review is set out in this document, in which it addresses the various issues under three main headings.

  • (a) The evolution of the CAP

  2.4  The Commission says that much has been achieved since 1992, in terms of improved market balance and the favourable development of agricultural incomes, and that a sound basis has been established for enlargement and for the next round of WTO negotiations. In particular, it says that the reductions in price support for cereals and (to a lesser extent) beef have helped both domestic uptake and exports, and thus helped to reduce the level of intervention stocks. However, it comments that Community producers in both these sectors are likely to face stronger competition, and that, although the role of intervention is now increasingly limited to that of a safety net, the continuing (albeit partial) link between production and direct payments makes it difficult for farmers to adapt to new opportunities, despite the growth in average farm size and greater specialisation.

  2.5  The Commission also identifies a number of gaps between on the one hand the mechanisms available under the CAP and the aims of Agenda 2000, and on the other hand wider expectations in such areas as food safety and quality, animal welfare, and rural and environmental development. In this last connection, it notes that, although Agenda 2000 introduced the concept of voluntary modulation (involving reductions in direct payments) in order to target farming systems requiring adaptation and to reinforce rural development, only a limited number of Member States have shown an interest, and even then at levels considerably lower than that permitted. The Commission further comments that the implementation of the environmental measures adopted as part of Agenda 2000, including cross-compliance, has been uneven, and that the price support mechanisms in some cases actually encourage more intensive production.

  2.6  The Commission also highlights two further constraints. First, it says that rural development will be limited as long as it continues to account for only 16% of expenditure under the European Agricultural Guidance and Guarantee Fund (EAGGF). Secondly, it suggests that the range of different mechanisms available under the CAP, and their complexity, discourages initiative, and that there should be greater simplification and decentralisation.

  • (b) Aims of the mid-term review

  2.7  The Commission says that, in addition to the task it was given by the European Council, the review provides a "unique opportunity" to respond to wider concerns about agricultural policy, and that a number of changes are needed. These include:

  • reinforcing the role of intervention as a safety net without compromising the export potential for European agriculture;

  • orientating output more to what the public wants, and not to artificially created price incentives or product-specific aids;

  • preventing direct income payments from influencing farmers' production decisions, whilst ensuring they still support farm incomes;

  • integrating food safety and environmental concerns fully into the CAP through cross-compliance;

  • providing more targeted support enabling farmers to adapt to the market and to demand for quality products;

  • achieving a better balance between the two pillars of CAP support;

  • ensuring that budgetary stabilisation remains a guiding principle;

  • working towards simpler legislative and implementation mechanisms.

  2.8  As regards the market organisations, the Commission proposes in the arable sector:

  • that the final 5% reduction in the intervention price for cereals (from _101.31 per tonne to _95.35 per tonne) envisaged in Agenda 2000 should take place in 2004-05, with direct payments being increased by an amount equal to 50% of this reduction; that the monthly increments payable on these crops should be abolished; that intervention for rye should also be abolished; and that the special additional supplement for durum wheat in traditional areas should be reduced from _344.50 to _250 per hectare;

  • that there should be no further changes in the relative position of cereals and oilseeds following the Agenda 2000 decision to align direct payments for the two sectors;

  • that there should be a one-off reduction of 50% in the intervention price for rice, coupled with the introduction of a private storage scheme, and an increase in direct payments;

  • that there should be new arrangements for dried fodder, involving an income support envelope of _160 million, distributed between Member States in proportion to national guaranteed quantities.

  2.9  The Commission also looks closely at the effects on the beef market of the Agenda 2000 reforms, notably the 20% reduction made then in the intervention price, and its replacement by a basic price for private storage. It says that, following the crises created by BSE and foot and mouth disease, the Community has been able to re-balance supply and demand, thus demonstrating the robustness and flexibility of the Agenda 2000 changes. However, it also suggests that concerns remain over the complexity of the direct payments in this sector, and the extent to which they provide incentives towards intensification.

  2.10  It is therefore proposing that headage payments should be de-coupled from production, and replaced by a single income payment per farm, based on historical entitlements — a step which, together with reinforced cross-compliance conditions, it believes will reduce pressures towards intensive production and help to achieve a more balanced market. The only other measure it proposes on beef is to reinforce the conditions and controls under which export subsidies for live animals can be granted, in recognition of the increasing concerns in this area over animal health and welfare standards.

  2.11  The Commission recalls that its Agenda 2000 proposals for the dairy sector had envisaged a 15% reduction in intervention prices in four stages from 2000, with a 2% increase in quotas, but that the Berlin European Council had delayed the entry into force of the main reform until 2005-06, and had made a 2.4% increase in quota levels. It points out that the current Communication is accompanied by the report it was asked by the Council to produce on the future of the quota system. Since we have considered the latter separately,[3] we are simply noting here the Commission's main conclusions. These suggest that the changes agreed in Agenda 2000 should have a beneficial effect, particularly from 2008 onwards, and can thus be seen to have forestalled to a considerable degree the comments made in October 2001 by the European Court of Auditors.[4]

  2.12  We also note that the Report identifies four main options for the period 2008-2015, namely:

  • a simple maintenance of the Agenda 2000 measures;

  • a repeat of the Agenda 2000 approach, involving a further 3% increase in quotas and a lowering of the intervention price (by 15% for butter, and 5% for skimmed milk powder);

  • the introduction of a two-tier quota system, with a 5% reduction in the quota for domestic production being offset by an unlimited export quota;

  • the abolition of the quota system, coupled with a 25% reduction in intervention support.

  2.13  In addressing the need for simpler and more sustainable direct support, the Commission says that the shift since 1992 from the product to the producer, and the introduction of partially de-coupled direct payments, has promoted greater competitiveness, stabilised agricultural incomes, and reduced negative environmental incentives. It adds that, although doubts have been expressed about full de-coupling, it sees merit in integrating all the existing direct payments (with a few minor exceptions) into a single income payment per farm, determined on a historical reference basis. It believes this will introduce both a major simplification and greater transfer efficiency into Community support, allow farmers to benefit fully from market opportunities, and remove certain incentives which currently are potentially damaging to the environment. Finally, it considers that such a change would facilitate the integration of the new Member States into the CAP, and help to ensure compatibility in future with WTO rules on agricultural payments.

  2.14  More specifically, the Commission proposes that the new single payment should cover all products under the cereals, oilseeds and proteins regime, grain legumes, starch potatoes, beef and sheep, as well as the revised payments for rice, durum wheat and dried fodder. Milk payments would be integrated on completion of the Agenda 2000 decisions, whilst other sectors scheduled for reform (sugar, olive oil, and some fruit and vegetables) could follow later. It adds that, although the new scheme would not cover all sectors at this stage, farmers receiving the decoupled payment would have the flexibility to farm all products on their land, including those still under coupled support, subject in the latter case to their continuing to observe any necessary market support constraints, such as production quotas etc.

  2.15  The Commission also says that the decoupled income payment will be established at farm level, with the overall entitlement being split into parts (payment entitlements) in order to facilitate a partial transfer when only part of the farm is sold or leased. It will be providing further details in the context of its legislative proposals, but, in order to allow sufficient flexibility, Member States would be able to follow different approaches.

  2.16  A significant element in the Commission's review addresses the need to reinforce environmental, food safety, animal health and welfare, and occupational safety standards, where it stresses that the full granting of the decoupled income payment will depend upon these being met. It adds that cross-compliance will be applied as a whole-farm approach, with conditions attached to both used and unused agricultural land, and that it will involve both the respecting of statutory management requirements and the obligation to maintain land in good agricultural condition. Where cross-compliance conditions are not met, the Commission believes that direct payments should be reduced, though in a way proportionate to the damage involved. This approach would be under-pinned by a Community-wide system of farm auditing, aimed at increasing farmers' awareness of processes relating to environmental and other standards, which would be a mandatory part of the cross-compliance requirements for producers receiving more than _5,000 a year in direct payments (and open to others on a voluntary basis).

  2.17  The Commission proposes that, in order to maintain the supply control benefits of set-aside, whilst reinforcing its environmental benefits, rotational set-aside on arable land should be replaced by compulsory long-term set-aside (10 years). However, this would have consequences for energy crops, which currently account for the largest amount of non-food production on set-aside land, and which would be of increasing importance if the recent proposal to incorporate biofuels within gasoline and diesel were to be adopted. It is therefore proposing that the existing set-aside arrangements for non-food crops should be replaced by a non-crop specific "carbon credit" for energy crops, aimed at achieving carbon dioxide substitution. Such an aid, which would be _45 per hectare and paid to producers entering into a contract with a processor, would complement investment and establishment measures under the CAP's second pillar. It would, however, be subject to a maximum guaranteed area of 1.5 million hectares, which would be allocated between Member States, taking into account historical energy crop production on set-aside land and carbon dioxide commitments under the Kyoto burden-sharing arrangements.

  2.18  The Commission is also concerned to achieve a better balance of support between sustainable agriculture and rural development, in order to increase the social acceptability of the CAP, and enable consumer, environmental and welfare concerns to be addressed. At the same time, it points out that, although the shift to decoupled direct payments will reduce incentives towards environmentally damaging production, it may also create pressures towards abandonment in some marginal areas: it therefore argues that this increases the importance of instruments to promote sustainable agriculture throughout the Community, such as agri-environment and less favoured area payments.

  2.19  The Commission says it will therefore be monitoring Member States' efforts to make full use of these instruments in future, but that it is in addition proposing a "system of dynamic modulation on a compulsory basis" for all Member States to replace the present voluntary arrangements. This would involve all direct payments being reduced progressively in steps of 3% a year, up to 20%. However, the Commission also considers that modulation can contribute to "correcting the allocation of funds", where it notes that smaller farms are generally more labour intensive, less prosperous and receive less support, but are also less capable of adjusting to new technologies and achieving economies of scale.

  2.20  It is therefore proposing a franchise of _5,000 for each farm with up to two full-time "annual work units", with Member States being allowed to grant on an optional basis an additional _3,000 for each additional annual work unit. It says that this would fully exempt from modulation around three quarters of the farms in the Community, which account for less than one fifth of the direct payments made. The Commission also proposes that, after the application of the franchise and modulation, the maximum sum paid to a farm will be _300,000, and that any direct aids beyond this amount will be capped and made available for transfer to the second pillar in the Member State concerned. The savings arising from modulation would also be devoted to rural development, but would be distributed to Member States on the basis of agricultural area and employment and a "prosperity criterion" to target specific rural needs, such as those in the poorer and more mountainous countries. All in all, the Commission estimates that the additional funding for rural development guaranteed by "dynamic modulation" will amount to around _500-600 million in 2005, and will increase annually by an equivalent amount with each 3% modulation increase.

  2.21  Finally, the Commission says that it intends to consolidate and strengthen the second pillar of the CAP in two ways. First, the accompanying measures[5] would be extended to address concerns about food safety and quality, to help farmers adapt to new standards, and to promote animal welfare. This would involve encouraging farmers to participate in recognised quality assurance and certification schemes; supporting the promotional activities of producer groups; paying temporary and degressive aid to help farmers meet the "demanding" standards set in Community legislation; and support for farm audits. The Commission also proposes to introduce into the agri-environment chapter the possibility of offering animal welfare payments for efforts which go beyond mandatory reference levels, and that, as from 2005-06, the inclusion of the food quality chapter would be compulsory for Member States within their rural development programmes. All these steps would be complemented by a widening and clarifying of the scope and level of certain measures.



  • (c) Likely effects of the proposals

  2.22  The remaining part of the Communication focuses on the internal, external and budgetary effects of these proposals. On the first count, it says that, as a consequence of decoupling and greater transfer efficiency, the prospects for the farming sector as a whole should improve, as should the potential for long-term sustainability in the sector and the social balance of support within it; that the food industry will benefit from the reduced cost of its raw materials in a number of sectors; that there will be major benefits for consumers from the integration of food safety and other concerns into the CAP, and the generally greater responsiveness of farmers to market signals; that taxpayers will also benefit from a better use of public resources; and that Member States authorities will benefit from the simplified payment and control measures proposed. Externally, the Commission points out that the proposals will help the integration of the new Member States into the CAP, and that they will also help the Community's strategic goals and commitments internationally by promoting sustainable development and minimising trade-distorting domestic support (adding that it expects other trading partners to make comparable efforts). On the budgetary front, the Commission says that it does not envisage any overshoot of the average annual expenditure laid down in the financial framework set by the Berlin European Council for the period 2000-06, and indeed it considers that the changes proposed for the various sectors and the decoupling of direct aids would lead to an annual reduction of around _200 million.

The Government's view

  2.23  In his Explanatory Memorandum of 29 July 2002, the Parliamentary Under- Secretary of State at the Department for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs (Lord Whitty) says that there are a number of important policy implications for the UK in the Commission's proposals, which he sub-divides into three broad areas

  2.24  The first is the proposed shift in support from production-related agricultural subsidies towards wider agri-environment and rural development measures. The Minister points out that, under the second pillar, Member States may run a number of agri-environment and broader rural development measures, and that, whilst the UK has long advocated such a shift in support, it does not believe that the Commission's proposals go far or fast enough. Specifically, the Government would have liked proposals which offered real budgetary savings with only some of the money cut from payments being recycled into the second pillar of the CAP, and the rest being returned to the Community budget. It believes this is needed to put the CAP budget on a sustainable footing as the UK takes forward its environmental and rural development objectives, and that enlargement makes it all the more important that the CAP budget is under control. In addition, the Government is concerned that the inclusion in the Commission's proposals of a franchise at farm level below which modulation would not apply, and a ceiling above which producers would not be entitled to any direct payments, risks creating an unnecessarily complex system which will prove unworkable and discriminate unfairly against certain categories of farmers.

  2.25  The Government welcomes the Commission's proposal to introduce an objective key for the distribution between Member States of the increased rural development funds generated by this shift in support. It considers that there is a serious and damaging imbalance in the current allocation of funds and that it will be important to take the opportunity to correct this. It also welcomes the proposals for simplifying and widening the scope of spending under the second pillar of the CAP, and says that the UK is considering whether it should go even further, for example, by widening the range of schemes eligible for funding under the Rural Development programmes, and the range of potential beneficiaries.

  2.26  Secondly, on the decoupling of agricultural support from production, the Minister says that the Government is pleased that the Commission has proposed abolishing the link between agricultural subsidies and production, which is something long advocated by the UK. He adds that decoupling would remove many of the present incentives to over-production and consequent risks of environmental damage. Farmers will no longer have to produce anything to receive their decoupled payment, but will have to meet certain environmental and/or animal welfare standards and to maintain their land in good agricultural condition. This will allow them to make business decisions based on a realistic appraisal of market opportunities, focussing on quality and choice rather than quantity. It would also carry real merit in relation to the UK's wider interests in the Doha Development Agenda. However, the Minister points out that a workable system will be complex, and that the Government will need to work hard with the Commission and other Member States on the detail of what is proposed.

  2.27  Lastly, on the market reform measures, the Minister says that the Government can support the proposed 5% cut in the cereals intervention price, which completes the Agenda 2000 process of making intervention a safety net only. However, it is not convinced of the need for this cut to be compensated for. Most significantly, it is disappointed by the lack of any firm proposal for dairy reform in line with the mandate established by Agenda 2000. It stresses that milk quotas are scheduled to end in 2008, and says that it believes that arrangements must be put in place to allow the sector time to adjust.

  2.28  The Minister's Explanatory Memorandum also deals briefly with the regulatory impact of the proposals, their financial implications, and the likely timetable. He says that a full Regulatory Impact Assessment will be supplied once the Commission has provided more detail, but that an initial assessment suggests that the main effect will be on the commercial environment within which producers operate (as regards the encouragement in future to concentrate on the market), and on the overall administrative burden. Likewise, the financial implications for UK expenditure and receipts will depend upon further information on such issues as modulation. He says that the Communication will be discussed at Agriculture Councils during the autumn, and that legislative proposals are expected to be tabled before the November Council (but see paragraph 2.32 below). He adds that complex negotiations are at an early stage, and that it is difficult to predict when agreement might be reached, it being possible that discussions will continue into the first half of 2003. In the meantime, the Government has asked for comments on the proposals by early October, and will be submitting after then an analysis of the responses received.

Minister's oral evidence of 11 December 2002

  2.29  Because of the wide-ranging implications of these proposals, we thought it right, before reporting to the House, to seek oral evidence from the Minister, particularly in the light of the agreement in the European Council in Brussels at the end of October on the budget limits[6] on CAP market expenditure between 2007 and 2013. Also, since the Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Committee has been conducting an inquiry into the internal aspects of the mid-term review, we decided to pay particular attention to the implications of the Commission's Communication for the enlargement negotiations.

  2.30  As it turned out, we were not able to take evidence from the Minister until 11 December 2002,[7] just before the meeting of the European Council in Copenhagen at which the accession terms for the ten countries due to join in May 2004 were agreed (see Annex). We were, however, still able to question him on a number of important aspects of the negotiations, as a result of which he told us:

  • that the differential in the first ten years after accession between the level of direct payments in the existing Community and those available to the new Member States could be justified on the grounds that such payments should be considered as compensation for past price support which had been removed, and that, since the incoming countries had not previously had such high levels of support, direct payments were in a sense a bonus so far as they are concerned;[8]

  • that, if (as the UK wished) all direct payments were phased out, a level playing field would be reached relatively rapidly;[9]

  • that he had in any event told the applicant countries that a shifting of resources into rural development was in their interests, as their agricultural industries need incentives to restructure and modernise;[10]

  • that he did not think the increased level of direct payments for the applicant countries agreed at the Copenhagen summit would jeopardise reform of the CAP, partly because the main decisions would need to be taken by the Community of 15 prior to enlargement, and partly because the pressures for reform came from the budget limits set and, perhaps most immediately, from the need for the Community to go into the WTO negotiations later this year with an acceptable package.[11]

  2.31  In addition to these external aspects of the mid-term review, we also pressed the Minister further on a number of other points arising from the Communication and from his Explanatory Memorandum. In the course of his evidence, he confirmed:

  • that the adoption of the proposals as they stood would leave very little headroom between CAP market expenditure and the new ceilings agreed by the European Council in October;[12]

  • that the problem would be exacerbated if reforms in the dairy sector and of the sugar regime required farmers to be compensated, at least for a transitional period;[13]

  • that, although the UK wished to see production subsidies removed altogether, it had to be recognised that politically a single decoupled payment of the kind proposed was the only way to proceed, at least in the short term;[14]

  • that, although the UK recognised there was a case for exempting from compulsory modulation small farms receiving less than _5,000 in direct aid, it was concerned that the Commission's proposal would fall disproportionately on Northern European farming;[15]

  • that the UK did object very strongly to a _300,000 cap being put on the amount of aid payable to any one farm because this would penalise the larger, more efficient farms, and would encourage dis-aggregation of farms purely to preserve the level of subsidy.[16]

Supplementary Explanatory Memorandum of 8 January 2003

  2.32  The Minister has now provided with his Supplementary Explanatory Memorandum of 8 January 2003 an initial Regulatory Impact Assessment, pointing out that a full Assessment (which will be possible only after the Commission has released its legislative texts[17]) should be available by the end of May.

  2.33  In general terms, the Assessment provided recalls the Commission's estimate that the reforms proposed should lead to an annual saving to the Community budget of _200 million, but adds that it is not possible to estimate fully the impact on the UK without detailed proposals or further information on some of the issues raised, such as modulation. However, it points out that the annual budgetary cost of the CAP is at present around _45 billion, and that in addition consumers in 2000 paid some _48 billion in higher food prices. The Minister says that this does not provide value for money, and that, in many cases subsidies received at farm level were higher than the profits made, with producers being forced to "chase subsidy" rather than respond to market demands. He also points out that the current CAP has both positive and negative effects on the environment, and that, although these are difficult to measure, the latter have been put at between £1 - 1.5 billion a year, as against benefits of just under £600 million. He believes that CAP reform would reduce the negative impacts, and that there would also be substantial benefits arising from the liberalisation of trade, particularly for a net importer of foodstuffs like the UK.

  2.34  In the case of particular commodities, the Assessment says that, since the outlook in the medium term is for world cereal prices to be at or above the Community support level, the proposed cut in the intervention price would have little impact on market prices (and hence on either producers, consumers, or the level of export refunds). On the other hand, Community producers would receive a net benefit of _770 million from the increase in direct payments, giving rise to a broadly similar increase in budgetary expenditure. It also suggests that the impact on production and on the budget of the changes proposed for set-aside are unlikely to be significant, and it contrasts this with the benefits which consumers in particular would derive, were set-aside to be abolished, as the UK has argued.

  2.35  The Assessment also estimates the impact of the four options put forward by the Commission for the dairy regime (see paragraph 2.12 above). It disregards the possibility of a two-tier regime as being incompatible with WTO rules, but compares the remaining two approaches (Option 2 — repeating the Agenda 2000 approach, and Option 4 — the removal of quotas) with the status quo. On that basis, the impact within the Community as a whole (in _ million) is put as follows:


Option 2

Option 4

Producers' returns

-1345

-4550

Consumers' savings

3125

7105

Taxpayers' costs

1385

1655

Net welfare

395

900

  2.36  The Minister comments that the overall benefits to economic welfare are greatest from the option under which quotas are removed, but that this also produces the highest losses to producers. He adds that the analysis does not take into account the further dynamic adjustment that will take place when quotas are removed, though he also points out that most of these would accrue to other Member States which have not introduced the same liberal quota trading regime as in the UK. He concludes that, notwithstanding the impact on milk producers, the overall economic benefit strongly supports the UK policy of quota abolition.

  2.37  Finally, the Assessment looks at the impact of the proposals for decoupling and modulation. It says that there is a strong economic case for the first of these, though this is difficult to measure. However, research carried out in Denmark suggests that, in the Community as a whole, there would be net benefits of _10.5 billion in 2013 arising from a more efficient allocation of resources, of which some _3.4 billion would be in the UK. On the other hand, the Assessment suggests that the environmental and social impact of decoupling could be more mixed. Thus, although the resultant decline in production should lead to environmental benefits, there is likely to be an intensification of production in some areas, whilst in others environmental harm could arise as a consequence of undergrazing. Likewise, whilst farm incomes may in some cases increase, structural changes could lead to rural depopulation.

  2.38  In the case of modulation, the Assessment says that the resulting reduction in direct support payments (and hence in production) in favour of increased rural development expenditure is likely to produce a range of positive effects on the environment and on the wider rural economy. It adds that, although these cannot be measured precisely, the _5,000 franchise would in the Community as a whole exempt 34% of payments from modulation (16% in the UK). Further exclusions would arise from the optional adjustment for additional labour units, though this would also involve considerable administrative complexity and the potential for fraud. Also, since farmers receiving direct payments would in future be able to switch production and compete with those in unsubsidised sectors, issues of fairness would arise, as they would in relation to larger farmers as a result of the exclusion of small farms from modulation and the placing of a ceiling on CAP receipts.

  2.39  The Minister has also provided an updated timetable. As already noted, the Commission is expected to publish its draft legislative texts on 22 January, and it would apparently like to secure agreement at the end of the Greek Presidency in June. He describes this as an ambitious timetable, but says that the Government supports a deal being reached in good time for the WTO Ministerial meeting in September.

Conclusion

  2.40  It is clear that this is a document of major importance, and we are therefore recommending it for debate on the Floor of the House. Moreover, as with our recommendation on the proposals for reforming the Common Fisheries Policy, we hope that the Government will make possible a debate considerably longer than the 1½ hours normally available for the consideration of European Union documents.

  2.41  Such a debate will provide the Government with the opportunity to explain the proposals more fully to the House, and to give a progress report on the negotiations so far in the light of the reportedly very different reactions among the various Member States. We also suggest that there are a number of issues in particular on which the House may wish to press the Government for further clarification:

  • subject to the detailed arrangements eventually proposed, the concept of a single decoupled direct payment has been given a broad welcome in principle, but it would seem to imply producers receiving without any 'degressivity' (reduction over time), or any obvious time limit, substantial payments without the need to produce anything: we appreciate that there will be obligations to maintain the land in good agricultural condition, but we wonder how long such an open-ended arrangement will be acceptable to the taxpayer;

  • this lack of degressivity could give rise to budgetary problems, given that the level of direct payments envisaged in the applicant countries will be aligned with those in the existing Member States by 2013;

  • although the concept of modulation is not new, the compulsory measures now proposed by the Commission would represent a new departure, as would the suggestion that the resultant savings should be distributed to Member States for rural development on the basis of various criteria: however, whilst the objectivity of the latter approach is to be welcomed, it is clear from the Minister's oral evidence that the exemption proposed for farms receiving less than _5,000 in direct aid would bear disproportionately on countries such as the UK;

  • similarly, there are clear grounds for concern about the relative impact on the UK of the proposal to place a cap of _300,000 on the amount of aid paid to any one farm.

  2.42  Finally, the timing of the debate needs careful consideration. On the one hand, this needs to take place well before the end of June target set by the Commission for an agreement. On the other hand, it would clearly be desirable for any consideration of the subject to take into account the Commission's legislative proposals, and, assuming these are presented on 22 January as expected, and that the Government is able to let us have an Explanatory Memorandum as quickly as possible, it should prove possible for us to produce a Report in time for a debate during March. All other things being equal, we suggest that this would be a sensible aim.


ANNEX I

ENLARGEMENT: AGREEMENT ON AGRICULTURE

—  The new Member States will receive a rural development package, more favourable than those applied to the present Member States, and amounting to _5.1 billion for 2004-06. This can be used for various measures, including early retirement of farmers, support for less favoured areas or areas with environmental restrictions, agri-environmental programmes, afforestation of agricultural land, special measures to make semi-subsistence farms viable, the setting up of producer groups, technical assistance, and aid to meet Community standards. These will be co-financed at a maximum rate of 80% by the Community. However, this money can also be used to top up direct payments.

—   Direct aids for the new Member States will be phased in over ten years. They will receive 25% of the full Community rate in 2004, rising to 30% in 2005 and 35% in 2006, but they can choose to top this up by 30% - to 55% in 2004, 60% in 2005, and 65% in 2006. Until 2006, such top-up payments can be co-financed up to 40% from their rural development funds.

—   Direct payments after 2006 will be increased by percentage steps so as to ensure that the new Member States in 2013 reach the CAP support level then applicable in the rest of the Community. From 2007, the new Member States may continue to top-up these by up to 30%, but financed entirely by national funds.

—   Alternatively, topping up will be allowed up to the total level of support a farmer would have been entitled to receive, on a product by product basis, in his country prior to accession (2003) under a national scheme increased by 10%. However, the total a farmer is granted cannot exceed existing Community levels.

—   The new Member States will have the option of a simplified system of direct payments for three years. This is a de-coupled area payment applied to the whole agricultural area, and all types of agricultural land would be eligible. After that, the new Member States will enter the regular system of direct income support in the form then applicable.

—   Production quotas have been agreed, mainly based on the most recent historical reference periods for which data are available, but taking account of specific problems, such as the Russian crisis or the anticipated switch from on-farm consumption to marketed milk.

—   The new Member States will have full and immediate access to CAP market measures, such as export refunds, and intervention for cereals, skimmed milk powder and butter.


2  (19028) 7073/98; see HC 155-xxvi (1997-98), paragraph 1 (29 April 1998); Official Report, 21 May 1998, cols. 1130 - 1179; and (19585) -; see HC 34-ii (1998-99), paragraph 6 (2 December 1998) and HC 34-ix (1998-99), paragraph 2 (10 February 1999); Official Report, European Standing Committee A, 15 February 1999. Back

3  See paragraph 3 below. Back

4  (22773) 12457/01; see HC 152-ix (2001-02), paragraph 18 (5 December 2001). Back

5   Agri-environment, less favoured areas, afforestation of agricultural land and early retirement. Back

6   That the level of market support expenditure under the CAP should between 2007 and 2013 rise by no more than 1% a year as compared with 2006. Back

7   The evidence is published with this Report. Back

8   Q.8. Back

9   Q.8. Back

10   Q.9. Back

11   Q.17. Back

12   Q.18. Back

13   Q.24. Back

14   Q.28. Back

15   Q.31. Back

16   Q.31. Back

17   It is expected to do so on 22 January 2003. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 4 February 2003