Select Committee on European Scrutiny Seventh Report


3. AGENDA 2000: OPERATION OF MILK QUOTAS


(23732)

10896/02

SEC(02) 789


Commission working document: Report on milk quotas.

Legal base:
Document originated:10 July 2002
Deposited in Parliament:9 August 2002
Department:Environment, Food and Rural Affairs
Basis of consideration:EM of 2 September 2002
Previous Committee Report:None; but see (22773) 12457/01: HC 152-ix (2001-02), paragraph 18 (5 December 2001)
To be discussed in Council:At various times
Committee's assessment:Politically important
Committee's decision:For debate on the Floor of the House (together with the Commission Communication on the mid-term review of the CAP)


Background

  3.1  When the Berlin European Council adopted the Agenda 2000 reforms of the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) in March 1999, it also asked the Commission to carry out a mid-term review. The main elements of that review are set out in the Communication which we have also considered today[18] (and which we have recommended should be debated on the Floor of the House). We deal here with one aspect of the review — the future of the milk quota system — which the Commission has addressed separately in a working document.

The current document

  3.2  The working document contains four main sections.

— (a) The importance of milk to the Community agricultural economy

  3.3  The document notes that, in the majority of the Member States, and in the Community as a whole, milk production is the most important agricultural activity in terms of value, representing around 14% of the total value of agricultural production at producer level. In addition, the Community is the world's biggest producer and consumer of dairy products, accounting for 21% of each, though Australia and New Zealand together have now overtaken it as the prime exporters of most dairy products, apart from cheese.

  3.4  This section also outlines the main price support mechanisms under the Community dairy regime — public intervention and private storage, internal aids to consumption, export refunds and quotas. It notes that the latter were introduced in 1984 to contain milk production which, stimulated by high support prices, was outstripping consumption. More particularly, there were fears that the resultant surpluses were leading to levels of Community expenditure on intervention storage which would jeopardise the very future of the CAP, whilst the level of subsidised exports was beginning to cause significant disruption on world markets. The quota system, under which producers are charged a levy (the so-called 'superlevy') if they exceed their quota, was considered by the Commission at the time to be the most effective method of addressing the problem, as it controlled expenditure whilst at the same time allowing the existing price support measures to be maintained, thereby helping to protect producer incomes.

— (b) The development of the Community dairy sector under the milk quota regime

  3.5  This section of the document notes that quota for the Community of ten Member States was set in 1984 at 104 million tonnes, in effect a 3.5% cut in production as compared with the year before, but that, since then, the global amount of Community quota has fluctuated. Thus, cuts had by 1992-93 resulted in a drop of 10.5% in quota for the Community of ten, but these were offset by increases in quota for certain Member States, plus the effects of German reunification and the accession of new Member States. As a result, the global quota for a Community of 15 now rests at around 120 million tonnes. At the same time, surpluses have been reduced from their all-time high of 22.3 million tonnes in 1983 to their current level of around 4 million tonnes, whilst annual CAP expenditure on the milk sector has decreased over the same period from around _5.2 billion to _2.8 billion.

  3.6  The report also outlines major developments since the quota regime was adopted. For example, the dairy cow population dropped sharply in the period 1985 to 1993 (following the imposition and then reduction of quotas), as producers tried to lower production costs, but, after 1993, with increases in quota in certain Member States, the rate of decrease in cow numbers slowed. At the same time, herd sizes have increased, as producers have aimed increasingly for economies of scale. This has been accompanied by increased consolidation in the processing industry, in response to the need to maintain margins with a more limited milk supply. The report notes that, despite the substantial CAP expenditure on the dairy sector, milk margins per kilogram have been static or slightly declining under quotas, and the Commission says it has been only structural change and the increase in quotas per farm which have resulted in rises in Community producers' incomes.

  3.7  In its analysis of the economic effects of the quota regime, the report defines 'quota rent' as the financial benefit which producers derive from the relatively high prices produced by a combination of quotas and the price support mechanism, and it suggests that this could account for up to one third of the value of milk at current prices. It also notes that a market for buying and leasing of quota has evolved, leading to a situation where the economically more efficient producers have tended to increase their production, at the expense of the less efficient. However, it adds that, where quota is purchased or leased from a holder no longer in milk production, a proportion of the 'quota rent' will drain out of the dairy economy.

  3.8  The report then looks at the effect of quotas on the competitiveness of Community milk production. It says that, because the quota regime, along with other price support mechanisms, helps to keep prices artificially high, it contributes to making Community dairy products less competitive both on the internal market, as compared with milk substitutes, and on the export market. However, the report argues that not all of the high price is due to the quota regime, and that, even under liberalised conditions, there would be barriers to producers realising full efficiency gains. It also highlights the importance of quotas in protecting milk production in the Less Favoured Areas, which represented 33% of total Community milk production in 1997.

  3.9  It concludes that quotas have had a significant and complex impact on all aspects of the dairy industry. It acknowledges that the system has not been stringently applied, and that the Council has, over time, introduced more flexibility. It says that the need to maintain this flexibility, whilst at the same time defining its limits, has led to a complex body of Community and national legislation, which has given rise to a raft of litigation.

— (c) Prospects for the Community milk sector under Agenda 2000

  3.10  The Report points out that, using economic modelling, independent experts have projected the impact of the Agenda 2000 agreement up to 2008. They estimate that, as compared with 2000-01, milk production would increase by 1.7% (in line with the increase in quota under Agenda 2000), and that the price of raw milk would fall to 87.7% of 2000 levels — a smaller reduction than the 15% cut in support prices — as a result of increased internal demand for cheese, fresh dairy products and whole milk powder (WMP). This growth in demand would be partly matched by an increase in production in the case of cheese and fresh dairy products. Skimmed milk powder (SMP) and butter consumption, on the other hand, is projected to decline, with the decrease in their use in animal feed and food manufacturing respectively. Imports of all major dairy products would increase (in the case of cheese, and SMP, by 50% and 80%, respectively), whilst exports decline. As a result of the cut in support prices, milk sector revenue (even after partial compensation through direct aid) is projected to be _2.7 billion less in 2008.

  3.11  The Commission concludes that, up to 2008, the projected outcomes are favourable as market balance improves, intervention stocks stabilise at a low level, and dependency on export refunds and internal disposal aids is reduced. Also, the quota increase and price reductions should lead to a reduction in the 'quota rent', thereby relieving the sector of some of the burden of quotas, and taking a first step towards their eventual lifting. However, the Commission also makes the point that the Council's decision to defer the price cuts until 2005, instead of 2000 as originally proposed, has delayed the full benefits of Agenda 2000, and that the continuation of the quota regime is associated with economic inefficiencies and administrative difficulties, constraints on Community production, and a continuing need for export refunds and disposal aids, albeit at reduced levels.

— (d) The future of the quota regime

  3.12  This section outlines four possible scenarios for the period from 2008 to 2015:

  • the status quo;

  • repeating the Agenda 2000 approach from 2008;

  • introducing a two-tier quota regime, and

  • abolishing quotas in 2008.

It is assumed that each option is implemented from 2008 onwards, and the measures agreed up to 2008 under Agenda 2000 will remain unchanged. The final result in 2014-15 is then compared with the situation in 2000-01 in relation to various factors, such as price, production, import and export levels, and sector revenue.

  3.13  Under the 'status quo' option, there would be no further changes beyond those in Agenda 2000, right up to 2015. The Commission says that, with the continued increase in internal demand for cheese, fresh dairy products and whole milk powder, and static production, the raw milk price would rise as compared with 2008, and would be 93.7% of that in 2000. Imports would be the same or increase as compared with 2008, whilst exports would decline still further, those for butter falling to only 5% of 2000 levels, with significantly lower levels also for the higher value products. This last consideration is identified by the Commission as one of the main negative aspects of this option, along with the fact that, with constant quota from 2008, the relief generated by the additional quota under Agenda 2000 would begin to be lost, and the sector would return to a state of being locked into quotas.

  3.14  Under the repeat of Agenda 2000 option, there would be a further increase in quotas of 3% in three steps between 2008-09 and 2010-11; a further cut in support prices of 10% (applied asymmetrically, with 15% for butter and 5% for SMP); and compensation in the form of more direct aid, representing 60% of the cut in prices.

  3.15  The Report says that, as a result of strengthening internal demand, raw milk prices under this option would be 15.6% lower in 2015 than in 2000, and hence less than the corresponding cut in support prices. As a result of the quota increases, milk production would be 4.7% higher than in 2000. Consumption of dairy products by 2014-15 would be marginally higher than under the 'status quo' option, as would production and exports (especially of whole milk powder and butter). However, under this option, exports would still be lower than in 2000.

  3.16  The paper also mentions that, under this scenario, the study examined the possible impact of quota trading between Member States, in order to reduce further the economic inefficiencies introduced by quotas. It concluded that any savings would be short-lived (_1 billion for 2008-2015), due to the overall shortage of quota within the Community.

  3.17  The Commission summarises this option as representing an important step towards long-term market balance, with the processing sector benefiting from producing more higher value products, with positive impacts on producer prices. Intervention stocks would not reappear, and export refunds and aids to consumption would be less necessary for both butter and SMP. Unsubsidised exports would increase compared with the Agenda 2000 scenario, especially in higher value products such as cheese. Further total quota increases and lower prices would result in a considerable gain to consumers through lower prices, whilst the sector would be better able to respond to market signals rather than support mechanisms. On the other hand, the option would increase considerably Community budgetary expenditure through a further round of direct payments, whilst the quota system would continue to restrict the shift of production to low-cost producers. As a result, the sector as a whole would continue to lose potential added value and income.

  3.18  The Report says that, under the two-tier option, quota would be set for the internal market at the level of unsubsidised internal consumption (effectively a 5% cut in the 2008 quota level). Thus, domestic disposal aids would be abolished, and, although intervention or private storage measures would be retained, this would be at a minimal level needed to absorb fluctuations in demand. Alongside this, there would be an open, independently managed quota for exports. This option would maintain internal prices above world prices, while at the same time exports would be unsubsidised, and so no longer subject to World Trade Organisation (WTO) constraints.

  3.19  Under this option, milk production in 2015 would be 8.8% higher than 2000 levels, with the price under the internal quota 14.2% lower. The effective 5% quota cut would act as a constraint on internal consumption, with SMP and butter consumption in 2015 below projected 'status quo' levels. The major impact would be on exports, which would benefit from unlimited milk supplies. As a result, exports for all dairy products (other than WMP) would be higher than 2000 levels, with the biggest impact on butter, where exports would be 143% of 2000 levels.

  3.20  The main advantages of this option, as identified by the Commission, are that there would no longer be a need for export refunds and internal disposal aids; reliance on intervention and private storage aids would be heavily reduced; and Community export capacity, reduced under Agenda 2000, would be restored. However, the Commission says that the two negative aspects identified call into question the feasibility of this option. The administrative burden of ensuring that only milk produced within the quota system benefits from market support is potentially huge. Even more importantly, there are serious doubts whether this option would be WTO-compatible. The Report notes that Canada has been operating a similar system for milk since 2000, which was challenged in the WTO by the US and New Zealand. The WTO Dispute Panel found against Canada, which is appealing against the decision. Consequently, the Commission suggests that continuing concerns about its WTO compatibility would probably rule this out as the option for the Community.

  3.21  The final option would involve removing quotas in 2008. Since this would lead to an immediate increase in production, the paper suggests that there would need to be cuts in support prices of as much as 25% in addition to those in Agenda 2000 (making a 40% price cut in total), in order to make intervention purely a safety net mechanism of last resort. The projections also assume that, in order to compensate for these cuts, direct payments would need to increase, and, for the sake of simplicity, it is assumed that these would double the level set under Agenda 2000.

  3.22  The Commission estimates that production under this option would increase more than under the others, and, as compared with 2000-01, would increase by 12.6%, as compared with only 1.7% under the status quo. This in turn would mean that prices would be far lower under this option (falling by 38.5% compared with 2000-01, as against only 6.3% under the status quo). The Report adds that, as a result, the increase in consumption of milk products would also be significantly higher than under the other options, as (with the exception of the two-tier option) would exports.

  3.23  The Commission identifies the advantages of this option as being the removal of the economic burden of quotas on potentially efficient farmers; the elimination of artificial support measures, with consumer prices reflecting the cost of milk production by the most efficient means; the creation of a self-sustaining, completely unsubsidised export capacity, and the increased market transparency and simplification of the Community milk sector. The disadvantage it identifies is that the fall in prices would not be fully compensated for by increased market opportunities for the cheap milk, with consequential impacts on the viability of individual and regional production.

  3.24  This section of the report also provides a comparison of the four options, which is summarised at Annex I. It also provides an analysis of the impact on milk sector revenues, which assumes that the direct payments under Agenda 2000, and any other additional direct payments under the scenarios, continue at the same level up to 2015. It concludes that the highest revenue in 2015 would be under the 'status quo', option, where brightening market prospects and firm milk prices would lead to a gain of _2 billion in 2015 as compared with 2008. The lowest would be under the removal of quotas option, where the price falls are only partially compensated for by the direct payments, leading to a drop in sector revenue in 2015 of _4.4 billion as compared with 2008.

  3.25  The Report says that the biggest influence on the budgetary impacts of the options is the level of direct payments, as, under all the scenarios, it is assumed that internal aids to consumption and export refunds would be zero, or close to zero, by 2015, and that there would be no intervention stocks. As a result, the 'status quo' and two-tier options are assumed to be the cheapest options by 2015, at _2.9 billion, as they would involve no change in the level of Agenda 2000 payments. The removal of quotas would be the most expensive option, at _5.9 billion, as a result of the assumed doubling of Agenda 2000 direct payments.

  3.26  In its assessment of the environmental impacts of the options, the Commission does not predict any great changes in intensity of milk production, in terms of feed and land use. The economic model used assumes that there will be a growth in milk yields up to 2015. Therefore, even for the quota abolition option, where production is projected to rise, the Commission considers that cow numbers will not be higher in 2015 than in 2000. The two options which result in the lowest levels of production ('status quo' and repeating Agenda 2000) would result in the greatest reduction in cow populations, and thus the lowest impacts in terms of greenhouse gases.

  3.27  The Commission concludes that the prospects for the Community milk sector under Agenda 2000 are generally positive until 2008, but that, after that date, the quota constraints and comparatively high prices associated with the status quo, would by 2015 damp down the rise in domestic consumption and result in a significant loss of export opportunities for higher-value products. It therefore presents the other three options, which aim to increase Community competitiveness through further quota relaxation and price reduction, as those which Member States should examine for the mid-term review.

The Government's view

  3.28  In his Explanatory Memorandum of 2 September 2002, the Parliamentary Under-Secretary of State (Lords) at the Department for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs (Lord Whitty) says that the report is disappointing in that only one of the options — quota removal from 2008 — fulfils the commitment for eventual abolition, as agreed under Agenda 2000 for the mid-term review.

  3.29  He also considers that the way in which quota abolition is presented in the report makes this option appear less attractive than it might otherwise be. He says that, in not quantifying the impact of the options on consumers, the analysis in the report is limited in scope, and that it does not take into account any dynamic benefits from the freeing up of the dairy market. For instance, an independent UK study, commissioned and funded by DEFRA and the devolved administrations, identified a significant net gain to the Community as a whole of _2.3 billion a year through this approach, mostly due to dynamic benefits through increased innovation and productivity improvements, worth an estimated _0.7 billion each to the farm sector and the dairy marketing chain.

  3.30  The Minister says that, in terms of the analysis which has been done, the loss of revenue to the milk sector indicated in the paper is likely to be exaggerated. The projected cut in support prices of 40% in preparation for quota abolition may be too great — some estimates have pointed to 25-30%. Similarly, the economic model used for this study tends to exaggerate the impact on prices of increases in production. Despite this, the projected increase in milk production of 12.6% in 2015 as compared with 2000 indicates that milk production would be viable even at the low prices indicated in the paper. The fact that the direct payments envisaged by the Commission are decoupled should mean that the returns solely from milk, as opposed to any direct payment, would provide the incentive to produce.

  3.31  The Minister comments that the report attaches importance to the role of quota in yielding general social and environmental benefits, including the protection of LFAs, and that this is inconsistent with the Commission's general Mid-Term Review paper, which highlights the importance of attaining such benefits through targeted aid via the CAP's Second Pillar — a view with which DEFRA agrees. However, he adds that the devolved administrations are concerned about the impact of quota abolition on marginal areas, particularly within the LFAs, as they are not necessarily confident about the capacity of Second Pillar payments to mitigate these effects.

  3.32  The Minister believes that the 'status quo' option is generally undesirable, and that there are serious practical difficulties in implementing the two-tier option. This leaves the repeat of Agenda 2000 as the only other potentially viable option. He comments that the Commission's recitation of advantages suggests that it appears to favour this option, despite the fact that the advantages identified are the same as those for full quota abolition, though to a lesser degree. He says the report does acknowledge the negative impact of the continuation of the quota system, adding that it is 'one more step on the way to the lifting of the quota regime'. However, if this option were adopted, it would appear that abolition would not be possible until around 2015, given the apparent need, according to the report, for still deeper price cuts in preparation for this eventuality. As such, the Minister suggests that this option would merely postpone the inevitable, perpetuating uncertainty for producers.

  3.33  The Minister stresses that abolition of quotas has been UK policy since their introduction and remains the Government's aim. He says that Italy, Sweden and Denmark are also still firmly in favour of milk quota abolition in 2008, and that the UK intends to continue to work with them towards this objective.

  3.34  The Minister has also provided in his Regulatory Impact Assessment of 8 January 2003 on the Communication setting out the main mid-term review proposals a comparison with the status quo of two of the other three options for milk quotas (repeating the Agenda 2000 approach, and abolition). This is summarised in paragraph 3.35 of this Report.

Conclusion

  3.35  Although we have tried to summarise the main elements in the Commission's working document, the analysis in it is lengthy and detailed, and perhaps has the effect of confusing as much as enlightening. In addition, we note the Minister's suggestion that the presentation in the document indicates a Commission preference for a continuation of the approach adopted in Agenda 2000, rather than the abolition of the quota system favoured by the UK. Be that as it may, this is clearly an important document, which forms an integral part of the mid-term review. It should therefore be debated on the Floor of the House alongside the main review document. We also think it would be helpful if the House had before it on that occasion the report on the operation of milk quotas, produced by the European Court of Auditors in October 2001, on which we reported on 5 December 2001.

ANNEX I

COMMISSION COMPARISON OF THE FOUR QUOTA OPTIONS

  



Year

2000-10

Projected situation in 2014-15


Status quo

Further

Agenda 2000

Two-tier

quota

Quota

removal

CONSUMPTION






Cheese

100

111.4

113.5

113.5

118.9

Fresh products

100

142.5

142.6

142.7

143

SMPA

100

82.3

87

91.8

99.2

WMPB

100

2.6

144

140.7

148.5

Butter

100

95.9

99.5

90.6

109.1


PRODUCTION






Raw milk

100

101.7

104.7

108

112.6

Cheese

100

1080.6

111.1

112.8

117.5

Fresh products

100

140.6

141

141.4

141.8

SMP

1000

76.1

81.4

88.6

96.1

WMP

100

80.2

89.1

115.1

111

Butter

100

84.6

89.4

95.6

102.3


PRICE






Raw milk

100

93.7

84.4

85.8

61.5

Cheese

100

99

95.1

95.3

84.1

Fresh products

100

102.8

101.3

100.5

98.2

SMP

100

84.3

79.3

73.7

65.7

WMP

100

87.7

83.6

93.2

71.5

Butter

100

93.7.

84.4

85.8

61.5


EXPORTS






Cheese

100

82.5

89.4

116.1

108

Fresh products

100

94.5

101.2

106.9

112.1

SMP

100

87.9

93.5

106.3

111.9

WMP

100

38.2

51.9

97.6

85.5

Butter

100

5.4

17.6

143

50.6

A Skimmed milk powder.

B Whole milk powder.





ANNEX II


BUDGETARY IMPLICATIONS (_ million)



Projected situation in 2010-11 and 2014-15


Status quo

Further Agenda 2000

Two-tier

quota

Quota

removal


2010

2015

2010

2015

2010

2015

2010

2015

Consumption aids

135

0

154

11

0

0

0

0

Export refunds

70

0

26

2

0

0

0

0

Direct payments

2938

2938

4895

4895

2938

2938

5876

5876

Total expenditure

3143

2938

5075

4908

2938

2938

5876

5876



18  See paragraph 2 above. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 4 February 2003