Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witness(Questions 100 109)

DR STEPHEN DEVEREUX

TUESDAY 3 DECEMBER 2002

Mr Tony Colman

  100. We asked the same question of the Southern Africa Director of the World Food Programme when she came to give evidence about two weeks ago, and I paraphrase but she was saying that crucially it was the national states who had the responsibility of delivering the right to food to their populations. Obviously the World Food Programme was their back-up. Clearly this is a situation in Zambia where the President of Zambia has taken a particular position. Do you want to comment on that particular situation at all?
  (Dr Devereux) It is a tricky one. It is difficult to force a government to accept GM food aid, if they feel strongly that the health and agricultural implications could be quite damaging. So they are taking a longer term view in response to a short-term crisis, and that I think is problematic. Are they responsible for dealing with the short-term emergency right now, independent of the possible long-term consequences; or do they have the right to say no at this point, knowing that the longer term consequences could be quite serious? They are trading off the present for the future. I do not have a view about whether they have taken the right decision or not. I think every national government has the right to take or reject whatever advice and aid they are given or offered. I do feel that national governments should be more accountable than they are; and that partly means saying no more often, particularly to pressures from the international community, which sometimes forces them into policies which are damaging to their own populations. There is no doubt that that has been the effect of some policies. The international community does not always speak with the same voice; it does not always share the same objectives as the national government; even the donors themselves do not always agree on the right way forward. Yet governments, in response to poverty and the need for international assistance, are adopting structural adjustment, liberalisation and poverty reduction strategies which they did not actually design and choose for themselves.

  101. I think we have moved on to poverty reduction strategies rather than structural adjustment. Could I suggest you are suggesting that NGOs know better than elected governments?
  (Dr Devereux) NGOs often have more information about what is going on, on the ground, than governments, in the sense of government officials sitting in the capital city. It is certainly the case that in Malawi the NGOs working in the communities were sending information to the central level in late 2001, which was apparently ignored by the central government. They either did not know or they were denying the evidence they were getting from the field, from the NGOs. I think that is probably a reflection of the power that NGOs now have, as having stepped in following, to some extent, the scaling down and the withdrawal of the government and the public sector generally, in the sense that we do not have the same number of agricultural extension officers and other government workers at community level that there were ten or 15 years ago when the government were much bigger.

  102. Obviously when we go to Malawi, Zambia and other countries we see a situation where land is held communally. Do you believe that one of the reasons why there has not been a move forward in having a vibrant and strong agriculture-producing economy in many African countries is because there is a lack of agreement on private ownership of land, which would enable farmers to be able to build up those farms and to be able to profit from the production of crops that could be sold elsewhere within that country? Zambia is an example where there is a lot of very fertile land but a very strong view on not allowing individual ownership of land to develop.
  (Dr Devereux) This is a debate which has a number of viewpoints and no clear consensus. My own view is that ownership of land, or least access to communal land, provides a very important safety net for households in Africa who risk losing everything in the first drought if they have a potential opportunity to sell that land. This is a view which is held very strongly by the government of Ethiopia, and I do not entirely disagree with them. They are very concerned that if land was privatised in Ethiopia then with the first drought that comes along millions of peasants would sell their land because they would need to buy food and they only have land to sell, and they would be forced into the cities. They would migrate to the city and become urban squatters, probably very vulnerable to poverty and food insecurity but now in an urban context rather than a rural. Some people would say, "Maybe that's not a bad thing. At least we don't have urban famine on the scale of rural famines".

  103. This is a trend which is happening all over the world and not just in famine areas.
  (Dr Devereux) Yes. Certainly it is clear that development (if we take by "development" urbanisation, people moving off the land into towns, offices, factories and so on) is associated with a decline in famine vulnerability. We should not reject the potential for urbanisation in Africa to solve some of the problems of poverty and food insecurity. However, I would be reluctant to support a policy which, in a sense, forced people off the land because they have to sell it in order to survive the drought. That is not the way to urbanise Africa.

Mr Piara S Khabra

  104. Firstly, with your vast experience of work in Southern Africa and the Horn of Africa and the research on famine and food security, you may have better ideas of how to deal with different famine situations in many of the countries of Africa. How, in your view, does the crisis and emergency response in Ethiopia differ from that in Southern Africa? Secondly, are there any lessons from Ethiopia—as regards the WFP's multi-annual planning of food aid—which might be applied in Southern Africa?
  (Dr Devereux) I think that one clear difference between Ethiopia and Southern Africa is that Ethiopia has a long, tragic, but sometimes successful history of dealing with food insecurity. In a sense, they are better prepared for the current crisis, because they have had to deal with it in the past. They have an infrastructure; they have an institutional set-up there. For example, even in a normal year, or in most years, about 4-6 million people get some kind of food assistance anyway. This year it is going to go up to 10, 12 or 14 million, but the institutional structures are in place. Ethiopia is better prepared logistically to deal with the crisis. I think what is happening in Southern Africa is as much a logistical crisis right now as anything else, because they have do not have enough transport; they do not have the institutional support; they do not have the presence of aid agencies like WFP on the same scale; they do not have the history or institutional memory for dealing with these kinds of crises. Southern Africa more generally has a bigger problem in the short-term dealing with the crisis, just because they are not used to dealing with it as much as Ethiopia is. You mention the specific case of WFP's multi-annual programming—one of the innovations that donors are trying now in Ethiopia (the latest in a long line of attempted innovations) is to take some districts out of the annual food needs appeal process, whereby it is assessed every year how many people will need food aid, and to try to work with them on a more long-term basis to recognise that these districts are chronically food insecure; there will always be people needing assistance and, rather than wait for the annual food emergency appeal, they will programme three or five years of assistance for that district. The point about that is not just to make sure that food aid arrives in time, because often it is late, but also to try to build assets and protect assets and livelihoods in those communities. In a sense, it is what we call "linking relief and development". It is about trying to move beyond seeing every year as a food crisis, and seeing it as a longer term development crisis and making sure that interventions are protecting livelihoods and not just saving lives. For example, using food for work or public works programmes to build infrastructure, because road building is still a very important feature of long-term anti-famine strategy.

  105. Taking up a question and taking it further, the distribution and ownership of land by small farmers is a problem in many of the countries on the continent. What do you think about the situation in Zimbabwe as far as distribution is concerned? It is not going to help food production if the land is distributed from big farmers to the smaller ones.
  (Dr Devereux) Again, the land issue is very complex all over Africa, and it is different in different places. Just to pick up on the first point, it is certainly the case that in highland Ethiopia and in Malawi, and in some other places like Burundi, farm size per household is so small that some people have called them "starvation plots"; you cannot grow enough food to feed your family even in a good year, even with fertilisers. Those livelihoods are going to remain unviable until people find alternative sources of income: either they have to work off the farm for six months of the year doing something else to earn enough income to buy food, or they have to move out of agriculture altogether. There is a kind of Malthusian crisis in some places where it is a lack of alternative livelihoods to agriculture that is keeping people trapped in their highly vulnerable livelihood system. In Zimbabwe it is much more a policy issue. The land distribution programme has been potentially very catastrophic for food production; and it is more to do with policy and politics than it is to do with actual land availability. There is plenty of land in Zimbabwe which has been very badly distributed in the past, but the way it has now been redistributed is not necessarily the way forward in terms of guaranteeing food security for the poor.

Tony Worthington

  106. Can we come back to Malawi and the issue of what you do about it. Just to describe what we saw. We saw severely depleted soil. There was an obsession with growing maize. It was land which had been over-farmed, over populated for food to support the population. There was dependence on foreign seeds and foreign fertiliser, with obvious power for multinational companies to exploit that. There was no legal system; there were no exports; there were no animals to speak of; no internal means of producing compost. Then there was AIDS. Nothing I have heard or seen makes me think we will not be there next year in the same position. What I am interested in from you is for you to say: how do we get out of that? What are the key things that need to be done in order to make that a more sensible agricultural land?
  (Dr Devereux) Unfortunately, I think I share your pessimism about Malawi. I do not see in the short-term any way of avoiding a series of food crises as we have had this year. In the long term we need to re-think again what policies are most appropriate for Malawi. I am certainly not the person who knows what Malawi should be doing in terms of generating economic growth; but my feeling is that livelihoods need to be supported, and that means a two-pronged approach looking at supporting agriculture, increasing agricultural yields; by giving people access to input which they do not have at the moment; and, at the same time, supporting the opportunities for people to find income off farm. Malawi does not have much of a non-agricultural sector, and that is one of the main problems they face. Some investment and some thought needs to be given to finding alternative livelihoods for people who are presently farming but not making a livelihood out of farming. One of the key points about agriculture in Malawi has been the undermining of access to inputs over the last several years. As you say, soil has depleted; there is very little livestock for manure or ploughing in Malawi. The interventions that have been put in place, for example DFID supported Starter Pack/Targeted Inputs Programme, have provided some fertiliser and seeds to some farmers but in a rather ad hoc way, and it does not give people the choice over how much fertiliser they acquire and when and so on. It is more about improving the structural provision of inputs, and making them available at affordable prices to the farmers, and giving them choice over their production. That is one set of factors. The other set of factors is to try and find alternative incomes for people so that they can move off these very small plots and out of this vulnerable livelihood system. At the moment, nobody seems to know where those alternative livelihoods are going to come from. One strategy which I think the donors are more or less behind right now is to try to set up a rather large safety net programme for the foreseeable future of 10-15 years maybe; and, at the same time, to invest rather heavily in primary and, increasingly, secondary education which has been somewhat neglected, as a way of trying to give people the skills base so they might find employment outside of agriculture. I think that might be a longer term solution; but it is very important to invest now in the next generation, otherwise the problems are going to intensify.

Hugh Bayley

  107. Mine is a macroeconomic question. When we were in Malawi we were told that even in a good year Malawi is not food self-sufficient. We were told that production last year was down by 15%, I think. Either country by country or across the region of Southern Africa, if one were to total the GDP of the countries affected and total the value of the food deficit, how does one compare with the other? What I really want to know is: is it a shortage of resources, a shortage of money to purchase food? It is an absence of money, or is it an absence of policy? That there are the resources there to feed everybody, but choices are made not to spend the resources in ways that do feed everybody. I am asking you as our adviser, if the answer is not immediately to hand could you chase after some development economist and get a paper written looking at whether it is a resource problem or a distribution problem?
  (Dr Devereux) I think it is a very important question. I do not have the figures to hand to answer that question here. My feeling is that it is a combination of both. It is partly because governments are so resource-constrained; they have so little foreign exchange, particularly a country like Malawi, that they cannot really afford to import food on a significant scale when a crisis occurs; and the private sector which was supposed to be doing this job is not responding partly because the policy environment is uncertain and partly because of poverty, and there is not much incentive for traders to provide small isolated communities with food for a short time every hungry season. It is certainly a problem of national resources. I would say, without going into too much detail here, that government spending seems to be more pro-poor than it has been in the past in countries like Malawi, and Ethiopia for that matter. There is much less spent on defence in a country like Ethiopia than there was before. The Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers that have been completed in many countries, including Malawi and Ethiopia this year, have a large component of pro-poor spending in them. Health and education, and food security to some extent, but less immediate, are getting much more attention from government budgets than they were before. I would say probably it is a resource constraint as much as a distribution issue. The resource constraint is manifested in the fact that the government has had to go to the international community for aid and they have had to write the poverty reduction strategies to qualify for debt relief, and at the same time they are continuing to pay a heavy percent of their income in debt relief and accepting conditionalities that they do not necessarily want to impose in order to get those funds. So there is an issue of resource constraints leading to policy problems that I mentioned earlier. That intersection, I think, is what is creating a large number of problems.

Chairman

  108. If one goes back to the 1997 White Paper and then you have all that work on sustainable livelihoods, the theoretical work the IDS, ODI, and others did, so we now have maximising people's assets, a whole range of assets, and then that leads on to the Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers and so on. When one travels through the Horn, goes to Malawi or whatever, the extent of the impact of the HIV/AIDS disease combined with drought seems increasingly to make a nonsense of those sorts of concepts of sustainable livelihoods. Going back to an earlier answer you gave to Tony Worthington about the need perhaps for jointly owned organisations, between the local community and international community, for dealing with the famine—I know that sustainable livelihoods were not looking as far back as 1997, but do you think that methodology needs revisiting in the light of the impact of HIV/AIDS on Africa and the frequency now of drought and famine in Africa?
  (Dr Devereux) Yes, I do. The sustainable livelihood approach is really just an analytical framework which looks at the various assets—that households and communities, or even national governments and countries, have, and then looks at options for achieving livelihoods which are sustainable and self-reliant in the longer term. One of the values of the approach is that it identifies different types of assets that people and communities have. Human capital is obviously one, and HIV/AIDS severely undermines human capital, in the sense that it makes people unproductive, it makes them ill, it drains household resources caring for them, and it leaves large numbers of dependants who cannot necessarily fend for themselves. What we are seeing, using the sustainable livelihoods approach, is a collapse of the human capital component of a household's asset base. The value of that approach is, therefore, to identify where the gaps are so we can think of where to put appropriate interventions. It is not obvious how you replace an economically active cohort of the population that has been removed, but certainly we can think of ways to introduce labour-saving technologies or to provide livelihoods for people that do not require heavy physical labour. That would be a way of dealing with the human capital crisis that has been created by HIV/AIDS. The other part of the framework is alternative livelihood strategies. There are three that were identified in the original formulation: agriculture intensification; extensification (farming more land); and migration. This comes back to the point about urbanisation. It might well be the case that a combination of agricultural failure and HIV/AIDS will require people increasingly to urbanise, to leave the land, to migrate to town and, hopefully, to find work there in the informal sector and ultimately in formal sector jobs. I think the framework is fairly useful. It has limitations, of course, but it does indeed identify where the problems are, and therefore suggest appropriate interventions.

  109. Politicians and civil servants spend some time working up policy and, for a long time, work up policy on sustainable livelihoods and build up literature and practical examples. Somehow one has the impression that, irrespective of what is now happening, the policy is still pursuing those approaches when clearly, just setting aside the drought, the impact of HIV/AIDS on Africa is signalling something rather more seismic happening: a million AIDS orphans already in Malawi alone. I wonder whether it does not require people waking up and saying, "Maybe for these countries we need a different type of intervention than that developed through the 1997 White Paper sustainable livelihood intervention, or have I got this wrong—it is just perspective and scale?
  (Dr Devereux) I think you may well be right on that. One of the features of academics like ourselves is that we are much better at explaining the last crisis than the next one. I think some of the frameworks we have developed have explained what happened in the past; but what is happening now is changing. The crises we are seeing, particularly in Southern Africa, are so different from what we have analysed or conceptualised in the past that we need to think again. The Horn of Africa might be a continuation of a fairly familiar type of scenario, where we can apply the old models and the old framework; but I think the Southern Africa emergency, where you have democracy, free markets, campaigning opposition and active, healthy opposition press, fairly fertile land, is a different story. What is going on in Southern Africa is different from the Horn of Africa and requires new thinking, and HIV/AIDS comes in, as you say, as a seismic factor there which has not been adequately built into previous models. That is certainly true. I think that the Southern Africa crisis which we are now experiencing or seeing is something which requires us to look again at policy and conceptual approaches.

  Chairman: Thank you very much. Thank you for answering all our questions.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 30 January 2003