Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Oxfam

INTRODUCTION

  1.  Oxfam welcomes the opportunity to feed into this important inquiry into trade and development. Trade is one of the most powerful forces linking our lives, and a source of unprecedented wealth. Yet millions of the world's poorest people are being left behind. Increased prosperity has gone hand in hand with mass poverty. Already obscene inequalities between rich and poor are widening. Oxfam believes that world trade could be a powerful motor to reduce poverty, and support economic growth, but that potential is being lost. The problem is not that international trade is inherently opposed to the needs and interests of the poor, but that the rules that govern it are rigged in favour of the rich. In our submission to the committee we will be addressing the impact of some of these rigged rules and double standards on developing countries and where we believe the UK government and the rest of international community must take action to reform these practices.

  2.  If Africa, East Asia, South Asia, and Latin America were each to increase their share of world exports by 1%, the resulting gains in income could lift 128 million people out of poverty. In Africa alone, this would generate $70 billion—approximately five times what the continent receives in aid.

AGRICULTURAL REFORM IN THE CONTEXT OF THE DOHA COMMITMENTS

  3.  To echo the Secretary of States' own words to the Committee, we must have Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) reform if Europe is to adhere to its Doha commitments, if not, "Europe will have thrown away Doha"[6]Under the World Trade Organisation's (WTO) Agreement on Agriculture (AoA), developed countries made a commitment to reduce their agricultural subsidies, "we commit ourselves to, comprehensive negotiations aimed at . . reductions of, with a view to phasing out, all forms of export subsidies"[7]In practice, they have done the opposite. EU agricultural subsidies were approximately $5 billion higher at the end of the 1990s than a decade earlier.

  4.  Thousands of agricultural producers across the world sell their goods on local, regional, and world markets. Yet many smallholder producers in developing countries suffer low prices, lost market share, and unfair competition. In Oxfam's experience, the CAP depresses and destabilises markets for farmers who receive no subsidy, including those in the developing world. The continued practice of dumping—exporting at prices far below the costs of production—is destroying domestic markets in developing countries.

  5.  Within the EU dairy and sugar regimes the practice of dumping is particularly pernicious. The OECD estimates that the EU supported its dairy sector to the tune of

16 billion (40% of the value of EU dairy production) in 2001. This is equivalent to over $2 a day per cow, which is more than the income of half the world's population. The regime directly costs EU taxpayers around

2.5 billion a year. At least half of this amount is spent on export subsidies to dump surplus production on world markets. The direct winners from EU dairy subsidies are the major European processing and trading companies, such as Nestle and Arla Foods, though it is impossible to obtain a breakdown showing which companies receive what subsidies. The losers include small-scale dairy farmers in Jamaica, India, Kenya, the Dominican Republic and across Europe. The Indian dairy industry, the largest dairy producer in the world, is currently seeking to expand into new net dairy-importing markets in countries in South-East Asia, the Gulf, and the southern Mediterranean. However, its efforts are being hampered by unfair competition from subsidised European dairy exports.

  6.  Under the EU's sugar regime, quotas and high tariffs set Europe's sugar prices at almost three times world market levels. High guaranteed prices to European farmers result in huge surpluses that are dumped overseas. As a result, the EU, one of the world's highest cost producers of sugar, is the world's biggest exporter of white sugar, exporting almost 7 million tonnes in 2000-01, accounting for 40% of the world market. These exports are subsidised in two ways: first, 3.1 million tonnes of quota exports (from A and B quota production) receive massive export refunds (around

500 per tonne) enabling EU sugar to match the world price. Second, exports of 3-4 million tonnes of non-quota, excess production (known as C sugar, which must either be stored or exported) are cross-subsidised by the very high prices farmers receive for their quota sugar beet. These C sugar exports are often ignored by the EU in debate because they fall outside its official regime—but they are even bigger than quota exports (3.8 million tonnes in 2000-01 compared to 3.1 million tonnes of quota exports), they fluctuate from year to year, so exacerbating the instability of the world market, and they are equally damaging as quota exports in their price-depressing impacts. Britain and France are the worst offenders in exporting this excess production: almost one quarter of each of their production is C surplus dumped overseas. While Europe's major sugar processors reap high profits (British Sugar enjoyed an astounding 21% profit margin in 2001), European consumers and taxpayers pay

6 billion a year to fund these exports that are undercutting export opportunities for developing countries. In 2001, for example, Europe exported 770,000 tonnes of white sugar to Algeria and 150,000 to Nigeria—these are lost export opportunities for the far more efficient producers of southern Africa.

  7.  The mid-term review of the CAP is an historic opportunity for the European Union to address this devastating aspect of its agricultural policies and meet its Doha commitments under the AoA. In recognition of the fact that high prices to EU producers, new technologies, and higher yields have led to chronic overproduction and increased exports of some agricultural products, the European Commission has proposed a further de-linking of subsidies to production in favour of a shift to investment in rural development. While welcome, this will not be enough to prevent the export of products at prices below the cost of production, or to stop the use of export subsidies. Moreover, serious reform of the sugar and dairy sectors—the sectors in which dumping is most prominent—is currently excluded from the Mid-Term Review reform proposals.

  8.  On 16 December 2002, the EC presented a proposal for WTO negotiations on agriculture, detailing how it will comply with commitments made on agriculture in the Doha Declaration. The EC presented the proposal as progressive and pro-development. However, Oxfam is concerned that it fails to address dumping effectively and has, despite development-friendly language, relatively weak proposals on special and differential treatment. The proposals included cutting export subsidies by 45% and domestic farm support by 55%. The proposals may seem significant at first glance, however, they would leave untouched the great majority of subsidies that ruin the lives of poor people in developing countries. The reforms would not apply to several products, including dairy and sugar, as these products are also excluded from the MTR of the CAP, even though subsidies in these areas inflict enormous damage on developing countries. Furthermore, the suggested reforms may not come online until 2013. Oxfam believes that the timetable for rolling out the elimination of export subsidies must begin immediately.

  9.  Reforming a system that reaps big rewards for a minority in Europe, while undermining the markets and opportunities for farmers and agricultural labourers in the developing world, is an essential step towards making trade fair and making globalisation work for the poor.

MARKET ACCESS

  10.  Under the right conditions, access to Northern markets can provide producers in developing countries with important opportunities for poverty reduction. At a household level, production for exports can support the diversification of livelihoods and create incentives for investment. At a national level, improved market access can help to diversify foreign exchange earnings and reduce the risk of dependence on a narrow range of commodities.

  11.  The problem facing developing countries is that tariff and non-tariff barriers in agriculture are exceptionally high. Average tariffs range from 16-20%, with peaks in excess of 100% a common feature. These tariffs are some five to six times the average tariff applied by rich countries when they trade with each other in the manufacturing sector, suggesting that the rural poor enter world markets carrying a weighty handicap.

  12.  Industrialised countries have repeatedly committed themselves to provide free access for all exports from the world's poorest countries. Yet the vast majority of their initiatives to date have excluded key products of export interest to the Least Developed Countries (LDCs). Only New Zealand has fully opened its markets to all products exported by the LDCs. The EU's 2001 "Everything But Arms" (EBA) initiative was originally intended to provide immediate free market access for all non-military exports from LDCs. However, following a concerted campaign by European producers and traditional Caribbean exporters, who feared that they would lose market share to LDC exporters, the proposal was modified so that free LDC market access for three important products (rice, sugar, and bananas) will be delayed for up to eight years. With the introduction of the EBA, some LDCs have gained export opportunities in these products, but they are still very limited. The total EBA quota for sugar was just 74,000 tonnes in 2001—just 1% of the sugar that the EU annually dumps on world markets. Having been excluded from the EU market for sugar, Mozambique, for example, was granted an export quota of just 8,000 tonnes in 2001, to be increased by 15% annually until 2009 when duty and quota free access will be granted. If Mozambique can successfully rehabilitate its sugar industry, it is expected to create up to 20,000 new jobs in the sugar mills and plantations, with jobs benefiting poor people living in rural areas where there are few alternative employment opportunities, and helping to stimulate the wider economy. By 2004, Mozambique will be ready to export around 200,000 tonnes of sugar. But in that year, its quota to export to the EU will be a mere 12,000 tonnes. Oxfam estimates that, at current EU prices, the country has, as a result, lost the chance to earn an estimated

108 million ($106 million) in 2004 because of the very limited quota. That's almost three quarters of the EU's annual development aid to Mozambique of

150 million ($136 million).

  13.  Sugar is one of the commodities for which a number of African, Caribbean and Pacific (ACP) countries are granted preferential access into European markets. As a part of the sugar regime, raw cane sugar is imported from 17 of the 77 ACP countries[8] (plus India) restricted by quotas but purchased at the high EU price. It is refined into white sugar primarily in the UK (by Tate & Lyle), Portugal and France. Although it accounts for just 8% of total EU production, it has provided these countries with stable export earnings and, in recent years of depressed world market prices, it has annually been worth around

500 million over what could be earned on the world market.

  14.  The EU justifies its sugar regime by claiming that ACP preferential access is a form of development aid—but its current policies undermine this claim. ACP imports are only 1.6 million tonnes per year—less than one quarter of what the EU dumps on world markets. Only 17 ACP countries are part of the preferential sugar arrangements and many other sugar producers—including some least developed countries—have been excluded. Of the 17 countries with preferential access, only four are among the least developed countries—Madagascar, Malawi, Tanzania and Zambia—and their combined share of the ACP quota is just 4% of the total. Until 2001 other sugar producing LDCs, such as Sudan, Ethiopia, Mozambique and Senegal, had no access to EU sugar markets at all. Among the lucky 17, almost 80% of the benefits accrue to just five of them—Mauritius, Fiji, Guyana, Swaziland and Jamaica—none of which are least developed countries. Although preferential access has provided secure sources of foreign exchange, it has also led several countries that are no longer competitive producers to have a high degree of dependence on these exports of raw sugar cane.

  15.  Furthermore, although preferential access for sugar has been extended to the least developed countries through the EBA, it has been done at the expense of the ACP countries. The EU claims that it is a leader in opening up access to developing countries—but it is actually making the poor pay for the poorest. Instead of cutting back on domestic quota production, the EU has made room for the EBA sugar by cutting back the import quotas from the ACP states.

  16.  In regard to the recent challenge to EU sugar exports made by Brazil and Australia, Pascal Lamy was reported as saying that the challenge was "very bad news" for the ACP group—implying that these countries would be the first to lose out from any adjustments to the regime. Oxfam is calling on the EU to show leadership in its agricultural reform by not pushing the costs of adjustment onto developing countries.

  17.  The impact of reform of the sugar regime upon developing countries will depend very much on how that reform is carried out. If the regime is reformed in a way that continues to guarantee high internal prices, while reducing total production, then the interests of the ACP and EBA countries must be safeguarded within that adjustment, by ensuring that quota cuts come from the excessive EU production and not from developing country import quotas. In contrast, if the reform process reduces the internal price to a level below that which is remunerative for the less competitive of the ACP producers, then their interests must be taken into account and they must be given compensation to assist them in adjustment and diversification. For any process of reform, the ACP countries must be included in discussions of the timing and nature of reform since they have such significant interests in the outcome.

  18.  EU Member States and other industrialised countries must do more within the WTO to reduce tariff peaks, eliminate all tariff escalation and provide comprehensive duty-free and quota-free access for all low-income countries. Trade can realise its potential only if industrialised countries reshape the global trading system to spread opportunity more equitably.

TRADE LIBERALISATION

  19.  Oxfam believes that developing countries should not liberalise trade and investment rapidly, or completely. Rich countries are pressing developing countries to open up domestic markets (including finance, services and government purchasing), and to deregulate foreign investment. This is a glaring example of double standards, since the rich countries themselves did not liberalise in order to develop, they liberalised once they had developed and had become internationally competitive. They stand accused of the sermon, "do what I say, not what I did".

  20.  The evidence on the impact of trade liberalisation on poverty reduction is mixed at best, so Oxfam takes a cautionary approach. Oxfam is convinced that countries at lower levels of economic development need to be able to decide for themselves if, when, and how liberalisation should take place, so that it promotes national development. Policies, such as favouring national industry, regulating foreign investment, and offering a measure of protection to their key sectors were critical in creating the success of the Asian "tigers" and rich countries in global markets.

  21.  Open markets are neither inherently good nor bad for poverty reduction. What happens to poverty when a country opens its markets depends on many factors. Amongst the most important are the initial distribution of income and assets, what people living in poverty produce, buy and sell, and whether the national producers are internationally competitive. Where trade restrictions have benefited poor people by raising the price of the goods they produce, this group will lose out with import liberalisation.

  22.  The removal of trade barriers in rich countries would produce clear benefits for poor countries. Carefully designed and properly sequenced import liberalisation in developing countries can also benefit the poor, especially when the lowering of trade barriers is part of a coherent poverty-reduction strategy. However, rapid import liberalisation in developing countries has often intensified poverty and inequality.

  23.  Loan conditions attached to IMF and World Bank programmes are a major part of the problem. Partly as a result of these loan conditions, poor countries have been opening up their economies much more rapidly than rich countries. Average import tariffs have been halved in sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia, and cut by two-thirds in Latin America and East Asia.

  24.  Oxfam's Trade Report compares the experience of opening markets in a sample of developing countries. In contrast with the claims of the World Bank that open markets lead to poverty reduction, Oxfam's analysis shows a diverse array of outcomes and no simple relationship between openness and poverty reduction. Some of the countries that opened their markets most rapidly and deeply have poor records on economic growth and poverty reduction (eg Haiti, Nepal, Mali and Peru). Case studies from Peru show smallholder farmers in highland areas operating at a disadvantage, compared with commercial farms. In Mexico, the "poverty belt" states in the south are becoming poorer, in comparison with states in the north. In India, import liberalisation is intensifying inequalities within rural areas, and between urban and rural areas. These inequalities matter, because they slow the rate at which economic growth is converted into poverty reduction. Meanwhile, some countries that have been cautious about opening their markets to imports have sustained far higher economic growth rates and achieved a strong record on poverty reduction (eg China and Vietnam).

  25.  Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers (PRSPs) provide the IMF and the World Bank with an opportunity to place trade at the centre of their dialogue with governments on poverty. That opportunity is being lost. In a review of 12 PRSPs we found that only four mentioned the possible impact of trade reform on poor people, of which two considered measures to protect the losers. In Cambodia, the IMF and the World Bank are supporting a strategy which will sharply reduce import tariffs on agricultural goods, exposing millions of rice farmers to competition from Thailand. Yet no poverty assessment has been carried out.

  26.  The World Bank and the IMF have spoken out strongly against trade protectionism in the EU and the US, to quote Mr Kohler giving evidence to the Treasury Committee last year, "There is too much of hypocrisy, double standards, in the international community. I am, indeed, advocating more trade integration. Then, I think, it is only clear that I also have to speak up against subsidies, trade distorting subsidies in Europe, in the US, in other advanced countries, and I am doing that"[9]Yet IMF/WB loan conditions for developing countries that place a premium on rapid liberalisation, without proper consideration of the consequences for short-term poverty and long-term development, are among the factors that prevent trade from working for the poor.

THE CRISIS IN COMMODITY MARKETS

  27.  Commodities are the most fundamental trade and poverty issue. Most poor countries are highly dependent on a narrow range of commodities, and commodity markets are characterised by a rapid price decline and high price volatility. While globalisation may be transforming international trade, many countries—and many millions of producers—remain heavily dependent on the export of commodities. More than 50 developing countries depend on three or fewer commodities for more than half of their export earnings. Dependency is most pronounced in sub-Saharan Africa; there are 17 countries for which non-oil exports account for three quarters or more of export earnings. Yet over the past 30 years, the share of non-fuel commodities in world trade has been declining almost without interruption. National economies have suffered in terms of reduced prospects for economic growth and pressure on their balance of payments. For households, global market pressures have damaged people's livelihoods and reduced their sense of security. The collapse of the global coffee price provides one example.

  28.  The price of coffee has fallen by almost 50% in the past three years to a 30-year low. Long-term prospects are grim. Developing-country coffee farmers, mostly poor smallholders, now sell their coffee beans for much less than they cost to produce—only 60% of production costs in Viet Nam's Dak Lak Province, for example. Farmers sell at a heavy loss while branded coffee sells at a hefty profit. Ten years ago, producer countries earned $10 billion from a coffee market worth around $30 billion. A decade later, they receive less than $6 billion in export earnings from a market that has more than doubled in size. The coffee crisis has become a development disaster whose impacts will be felt for a long time.

  29.  The economies of some of the poorest countries in the world are highly dependent on trade in coffee. Dependency is particularly high in some African countries. In Uganda, the livelihoods of roughly one-quarter of the population are in some way dependent on coffee sales. In Ethiopia, coffee accounts for over 50% of export revenues, while in Burundi the figure is almost 80%.

  30.  Families dependent on the money generated by coffee are pulling their children, especially girls, out of school. They can no longer afford basic medicines, and are cutting back on food. Their obvious move out of coffee and into something else is fraught with problems. It requires money that they don't have and alternative crops that offer better prospects. For a farmer to turn her back on the four years spent waiting for coffee trees to start bearing fruit is a highly risky strategy. Furthermore, many of the possible alternatives including: sugar, bananas, cotton and dairy products, are all heavily protected industries in the EU and the US. Beyond farming families, coffee traders are going out of business. National economies are suffering and some banks are collapsing. Government funds are being squeezed dry, putting pressure on health and education and forcing governments further into debt.

  31.  The central problem is one of over-supply. Since the coffee market was liberalised in 1989 supply has risen well above demand. The current growth rate of 1-1.5% per year in demand is easily outstripped by a more than 2% increase in supply which leads to lower and lower prices. Even if demand were to meet supply over the next few years, there would still be a glut of unsold coffee stocks on the market—estimated at 40 million bags—depressing the world price.

  32.  Despite the stagnant consumer market, the coffee companies are making handsome profits. The big four coffee roasters, Kraft, Nestlé, Procter & Gamble, and Sara Lee, each have coffee brands worth US$1 billion or more in annual sales. Together with German giant Tchibo, they buy almost half the world's coffee beans each year. Profit margins are high—The Economist estimates that Nestlé has made an estimated 40% profit margin on instant coffee but no one knows the exact figure. Today coffee farmers receive 1% or less of the price of a cup of coffee sold in a coffee bar. They receive roughly 6% of the value of a pack of coffee sold in supermarkets and grocery stores.

  33.  The challenge is to make the coffee market work for all. The failures of previous efforts at intervention in the market must be understood and lessons learned. But so too must the lessons of the moment. The low coffee price creates a buyers' market, leaving some of the poorest and most powerless people in the world to negotiate in an open market with some of the richest and most powerful. The result, unsurprisingly, is that the rich get richer and the poor get poorer. Active participation by all players in the coffee trade is needed to reverse this situation. This year is critical. Coffee-producing governments have agreed a plan that aims to reduce supply by improving the quality of coffee traded. Future action on diversification, market intervention and coffee promotion will be discussed at the ICO/World Bank International Coffee Conference from May 19-20. These actions will only work if they are backed by the companies and by the rich countries, including the UK government, and are complemented by measures to address long-term rural underdevelopment and open up markets for alternative products.

SPECIAL AND DIFFERENTIAL TREATMENT

  34.  One of the strengths of the WTO system is that it applies universal rules which restrict, however inadequately, the scope for bilateral power politics. Unfortunately, universality is also a weakness in one crucial respect: not all WTO members are of equal economic strength—and they face different problems. In particular, developing countries need multilateral trade rules that enable them, within a broad-based system of accepted ground rules, to implement the policies needed to generate growth and poverty reduction. Under the GATT, industrialised countries did acknowledge that trade liberalisation had different implications in developing countries from those that applied to their own markets yet whilst these principles of special and differential treatment (S&DT) were endorsed this had relatively little impact in negotiations over market access or in the design of WTO rules.

  35.  Under most WTO agreements under the Uruguay Round, the only concession granted to developing countries is a slightly longer time-frame for implementation. Given the scope of these agreements and associated administrative demands, this is a very limited provision. Oxfam believes that even these extended implementation periods are too restrictive to be classed as adequate S&DT measures. Under the Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) Agreement there are procedures for extending implementation deadlines for developing countries. The general implementation deadline is 2000 for developing countries, and 2005 for developing countries which had not previously implemented product patenting for pharmaceuticals and chemicals. An extension to 2016 was agreed for pharmaceutical products at the WTO Ministerial Conference in Doha. Whilst this is welcome, this will be a relatively meaningless measure unless steps are taken to ensure that developing countries can continue to produce and export affordable generics to those developing countries without manufacturing capacity. Oxfam believes that all developing countries need greater flexibility to determine the length and scope of patenting in order to ensure access to affordable medicines. The most simple and direct solution would be to grant all developing and least developed countries much longer transition periods to comply with TRIPS, based on their achievement of agreed development milestones, rather than arbitrary dates as at present. The UK government goes some way towards supporting this position, in an answer to a parliamentary question on the subject, the Secretary of State for Trade and Industry said, "The UK government support the development of objective criteria to form the basis upon which extensions on TRIPS transition periods should be agreed. The Government therefore support the introduction into TRIPS of a mechanism for extending transition periods for individual developing countries."[10]

  36.  The idea of introducing a package of enhanced special and differential treatment measures for developing countries in the WTO Agreement on Agriculture has been termed a "Development Box". Unlike the existing Blue and Green Boxes, whose provisions institutionalise the agricultural support policies of industrialised countries, a Development Box would provide greater flexibility for developing countries to implement tariff and non-tariff protection to strengthen their domestic production, promote food security, and maintain and improve rural livelihoods.

  37.  The Development Box provisions would aim to protect poor farmers from surges of cheap or unfairly subsidised imports and provide and sustain existing employment and livelihoods opportunities for the rural poor. Specific instruments would include exempting food-security crops from trade-liberalisation commitments, allowing developing countries the flexibility to raise tariffs or use quotas against cheap agricultural imports that are damaging domestic production, and exempting government subsidies from liberalisation commitments.

  38.  In the Doha Declaration the S&DT issue was marked as a priority, placed in the same category for negotiation as the implementation of various aspects of the Uruguay Round. The Declaration states that, "We therefore agree that that all special and differential treatment provisions shall be reviewed with a view to strengthening them and making them more precise, effective and operational"[11]These reviews of S&DT provisions apply to the TRIPS Agreement, the AoA and the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS), among others. Yet the practice is out of step with the principle. At the end of 2002 the WTO was struggling to make some S&DT measures operational as mandated by the Doha Ministerial Declaration. Delegations had been meeting throughout the year to develop S&DT provisions through a series of formal and informal sessions under the Special Session of the Committee on Trade and Development (CTD). Unfortunately, while developing countries have tabled over 85 issues for consideration, the bulk of which are proposed by the Africa group, the WTO could barely arrive at agreement on four of them by the end of last year.

  39.  The principles underpinning special and differential treatment have been eroded since the end of the Uruguay Round. Developing countries are now assuming obligations that are inconsistent with policies for poverty reduction. There is an urgent need to return to some first principles on special and differential treatment, in particular to ensure that there is no WTO prohibition on policies that promote growth and poverty reduction.

THE CAPACITIES OF DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

  40.  Since the end of the Uruguay Round, the authority of the WTO has been extended, with crucial consequences for the poor. Multilateral trade rules now constrain the development of national policies in a wide range of areas that are vital to poverty reduction. Developing countries are already over-stretched in dealing with the issues already on the negotiating table a) in terms of their negotiating capacity under the Doha Round and b) regarding the administrative burden that comes with implementing these requirements at a national level. Developing countries are becoming more skilled at trade negotiation, and the worst excesses of the Green Room process have been curbed, but they are still at a huge disadvantage because they do not have the staff and know-how to accompany such a vast and complex range of issues, compared with EU Member States and the US who have a huge wealth of resources and specialists at their disposal. The WTO has 70 committees, councils and working groups and there are a total of 1,000 official committee meetings every year. On the implementation side, according to the findings of World Bank surveys, the up-front average cost of implementing the TRIPS agreement alone in a low-income country is approximately $1.5 million, with annual recurrent costs of $2 million (World Bank 2002). An expense that the poorer developing countries can ill-afford.

NEW ISSUES

  41.  There are four new issues which many developed countries would like to see included under WTO auspices: investment, competition, government procurement and trade facilitation. Oxfam's view is that WTO multilateral negotiations on new issues will, at best, bring no benefit to poor countries and at worst bring considerable harm. Moreover, they would contribute to a hugely overloaded agenda, making it even more difficult for poor countries with limited negotiation capacities to participate. This is why Oxfam strongly supports developing countries exercising their right under the Doha declaration not to launch negotiations on new issues at the next Ministerial meeting in Cancun in September.

  42.  The inclusion of investment in WTO negotiations, despite strong reservations in many developing countries, is cause for great alarm. Although the EC has promised that a WTO investment agreement would not repeat the mistakes of the defeated OECD Multilateral Agreement on Investment and would put development at its heart, there is no development rationale for an agreement at the WTO and every reason to believe it is about opening markets for international corporations and reducing developing countries power to regulate.

  43.  In line with the principles that underpin Chapter 11 of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), current discussions on investment in Geneva continue to focus disproportionately on investors' rights. Worryingly, the growing privileges of foreign investors are impinging on the right of developing countries to regulate foreign investment adequately in the interest of national development. Existing bilateral agreements on investment are already weakening governments' control over profit remittances and export performance requirements, for example, which, in turn, will have negative effects on their balance of payments. WTO rules, such as the agreement on Trade Related Investment Measures (TRIMs), potentially preclude government policies aimed at establishing dynamic linkages between foreign investors and local industry, and at increasing the share of export value retained locally. Oxfam fears a new multilateral agreement on investment, without fundamental changes to the WTO, could also restrict the ability of developing countries to target foreign direct investment to deprived regions. The danger is that developing countries will be prevented from using precisely those measures that enabled the East Asian "tigers" to make foreign direct investment work for development.

  44.  Oxfam strongly believes that all countries stand to benefit from the stability that a rules-based system can provide. Lacking the economic power and the retaliatory capacity to pursue their demands outside such a system, developing countries need multilateralism to work. For multilateralism to work, however, it has to be fair and balanced. It has to protect weak countries from the abuse of economic power, rather than concentrate advantage in the hands of rich countries and corporations. Until the WTO can pass this test, there is little reason to believe that a multilateral agreement on investment would contribute to making trade fair.

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY

  45.  Some of the multilateral rules already under discussion within the Doha Round threaten to widen inequalities associated with trade, and to weaken the links between trade and poverty reduction. The rules governing intellectual property rights provide such an example.

  46.  By obliging all governments to grant a minimum of 20-year patents, the TRIPS Agreement shields pharmaceutical companies from generic competition globally. This results in higher prices for vital new medicines in rich and poor countries alike . This will seriously restrict poor people's access to new medicines to treat diseases such as HIV/AIDS, and to newly improved medicines for drug resistant versions of old killers such as malaria and tuberculosis. However, the Doha Declaration on TRIPS and public health states that "the TRIPS Agreement does not and should not prevent governments from taking measures to protect public health" and as such it should give developing countries greater confidence in using the existing public health safeguards in TRIPS in order to improve access to affordable medicines.

  47.  Under TRIPS, the US or UK government can override a patent on a medicine using a "compulsory license" and commission a domestic company to produce a generic equivalent. This tool greatly enhances the government's ability to negotiate reasonable prices with the patent-holding manufacturer. But developing countries are caught in a Catch-22 situation. Most countries don't have the technology or size of market to manufacture affordable generic versions of new medicines so they would need to import them. But they cannot do so because TRIPS prohibits the export of generic versions of patented medicines. The bottom line is that they have to either pay the high price of the patented product—which their population can ill-afford—or to leave patients without any treatment.

  48.  Trade Ministers at Doha recognised this problem and agreed in paragraph 6 of the Ministerial Declaration on TRIPS and Public Health to "instruct the Council for TRIPS to find an expeditious solution to this problem and to report to the General Council before the end of 2002" . Yet in the last 12 months, no change has been achieved as rich countries, led by the US, are blocking meaningful solutions to this problem. The solution currently promoted by the United States, the European Union, Switzerland and Canada would include only a limited number of epidemics and be swathed in red tape. Developing countries would not have access to cheaper generic drugs for major killer-diseases such as pneumonia, diarrhoea, heart disease or cancer. The US proposal also places restrictions on eligible countries and includes a whole raft of safeguards and conditions which would make it hard for countries to implement. Furthermore, the proposed legal mechanism would leave the importing country unacceptably dependent on the political will of the exporting country to meet its health needs. Oxfam, along with most developing-country governments and NGOs, believes there is a straightforward way to honour the pledges made to poor people at Doha and grant developing countries the same rights to affordable medicines as those enjoyed by rich countries. The legal mechanism which would best achieve this would be for the WTO to issue an authoritative interpretation of Article 30 of the TRIPS Agreement which would allow the export of affordable generic medicines to countries with unmet health needs.

CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS

Agricultural reform in the context of the Doha commitments

  49.  Oxfam is calling on the EU to use the mid-term review of the CAP to agree a plan which will stop the dumping of EU agricultural produce on world markets. As a member of the EU we hope that the UK Government will use its position to encourage other member states to reach a common EU position to:

    —  Agree a plan for rapid phasing out all agricultural subsidies that facilitate export dumping—the sale on world markets of goods at prices below their costs of production. As an immediate step, the EU should agree a binding timetable to eliminate all forms of export subsidies before the 5th WTO Ministerial Conference in Mexico (September 2003).

    —  Reform the EU's sugar and dairy regimes, in order to avoid the damaging effects on developing country interests. This will include:

    —  Eliminating the need for dairy export subsidies by cutting milk production quotas to levels that bring domestic EU production in line with internal consumption, and;

    —  An end to EU sugar dumping. This would mean cutting EU domestic quota production by 25% so as to make possible an end to all quota exports and an end to all non-quota (C sugar) exports by storing all C sugar for use in the following year's quota.

    —  Assess the impact of proposed CAP reforms on poverty reduction and food security in developing countries.

    —  Include a specific objective that CAP reform should foster poverty reduction and food security in developing countries.

    —  Support the introduction of a "Development Box" in the WTO Agreement on Agriculture, giving developing-country governments the flexibility to protect their small farmers from dumping.

    —  Restructure domestic support towards less industrial agriculture and measures aimed at enhancing the welfare of small farmers and the environment, rather than large-scale corporate agriculture.

MARKET ACCESS

  50.  Oxfam believes that the EU and other industrialised countries must begin to dismantle protectionist barriers which are squeezing developing countries out of their world market share by:

    —  Providing full and immediate access for imports from LDCs through the "Everything But Arms" initiative and extending it to low-income countries.

    —  Implementing an immediate across-the-board reduction of all tariff peaks in excess of 15% to less than 10%, with further reduction to less than 5% by 2005.

    —  Immediately eliminating all tariff escalation on products exported from developing countries.

  51.  Oxfam is calling for the EU to show leadership in its agricultural reform, while protecting the interests of the ACP and EBA producers, by cutting EU domestic quota production by 25% so as to make reform of the sugar regime possible, including:

    —  Restoring quotas for ACP preferential sugar imports (that have been cut to make way for EBA imports) and standing by the EU's commitment to support the economies of these countries.

TRADE LIBERALISATION

  52.  Through their influence over the design and implementation of IMF-World Bank policies, industrialised countries have been able to maintain a highly unbalanced process of liberalisation. The following measures should be implemented to redress the balance, ensuring that the consequences of liberalisation for short-term poverty and long-term development are taken full account of:

    —  IMF/World Bank programmes should not impose further loan conditions requiring trade liberalisation.

    —  Rich countries should reciprocate previous liberalisation undertaken by developing countries under IMF/World Bank conditions by making equivalent reductions in their own import barriers.

    —  All PRSPs should include a detailed analysis of the potential impact of trade liberalisation on income distribution and poverty reduction.

THE CRISIS IN COMMODITY MARKETS

  53.  Oxfam is calling for a Coffee Rescue Plan to make the coffee market work for the poor as well as the rich. The plan needs to bring together the major players in coffee to overcome the current crisis and create a more stable market.

  54.  Within one year the Rescue Plan, under the auspices of the International Coffee Organisation, should result in:

    1.  Coffee companies paying farmers a decent price (above their costs of production) so that they can send their children to school, afford medicines, and have enough food.

    2.  Increasing the price to farmers by reducing supply and stocks of coffee on the market through:

    —  Coffee companies trading only in coffee that meets basic quality standards as proposed by the International Coffee Organisation (ICO).

    —  The destruction of at least five million bags of coffee stocks, funded by rich-country governments, including the UK Government, and the coffee companies.

    3.  The creation of a fund to help poor farmers shift to alternative livelihoods, making them less reliant on coffee.

    4.  Coffee companies committing to increase the amount of coffee they buy under Fair Trade conditions to 2% of their volumes.

SPECIAL AND DIFFERENTIAL TREATMENT

  55.  Developing countries should retain the right to develop industrial and agricultural policies that facilitate successful integration into global markets through the strengthening of special and differential treatment provisions.

  56.  Specifically, the EU and other industrialised countries should support:

    —  The extension of the time-frame for developing countries' liberalisation commitments.

    —  Developing countries' proposals to incorporate a Development Box in the Agreement on Agriculture to promote food security and rural livelihoods.

    —  Granting all developing and least developed countries much longer transition periods to comply with TRIPS, based on their achievement of agreed development milestones, rather than arbitrary dates as at present.

THE CAPACITIES OF DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

  57.  Developing countries are already coping with an overloaded work programme which stretches their negotiating capacity and administrative capability beyond breaking point. The EU and other industrialised countries should agree to:

    —  Reject a launch of negotiations on new issues at the next Ministerial meeting in Cancún in September.

    —  Support the negotiating capacity of developing countries on issues currently under negotiation.

  58.  On the TRIPS agreement specifically, WTO Member States should:

    —  Call for a review of the development and health impact of TRIPS with a view to granting greater flexibility to developing countries to determine the length and scope of patenting.

    —  Agree an interpretation that Article 30 can be used by countries to allow exports of generic equivalents of patented medicines to developing countries that cannot manufacture these products themselves. This revision should be permanent and legally secure, cover all diseases and all pharmaceutical products, benefit all developing countries, permit economically viable production of generic drugs and be quick and simple to operate.

Oxfam

January 2003


6   The Rt Hon Clare Short MP, November 5 2002, evidence to the International Development Committee on the outcome of the IMF/WB Annual Meetings. Back

7   From the text of the Doha Declaration, November 2001. Back

8   Barbados, Belize, DCR, Fiji, Guyana, Ivory Coast, Jamaica, Madagascar, Malawi, Mauritius, St Kitts and Nevis, Surinam, Swaziland, Tanzania, Trinidad and Tobago, Zambia and Zimbabwe. Back

9   Mr Horst Kohler, July 10, 2002, in an evidence session with the Treasury Select Committee. Back

10   The Rt Hon Patricia Hewitt MP, November 14, 2002, written answer to a parliamentary question. Back

11   From the text of the Doha Declaration, November 2001. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 21 March 2003