Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 60-79)

TUESDAY 11 FEBRUARY 2003

MR DUNCAN GREEN, CLAIRE MELAMED AND MR MICHAEL BAILEY

Tony Worthington

  60. To go back to two points about campaigns, WTO and the prospect of the weekend of 27 and 28 June being taken up with trade matters, we are going to get lots of letters which will be inspired by NGOs, the World Development Movement, by the Trade Justice Movement, in which WTO will come across as the anti-Christ and yet there is a huge danger in this. One feels that the NGOs would be campaigning for the creation of the WTO if it did not exist because it is democratic, it has all the nations of the world in it, and yet the WTO does not really exist in terms of its members. If it did not exist, the bullies would win all the time. Do you not feel there is a danger in the style of campaigning that you are going to undermine something that could be a considerable force for good in the world?
  (Ms Melamed) That is a difficult question. Obviously, when you are campaigning and attempting to reduce what are very complex policy arguments to issues which can be campaigned on, there are always issues. I think that NGOs have been very careful to try and emphasise to supporters in the course of building up the trade campaign that the WTO is not like the World Bank and the IMF, which are significant actors in their own right, and that the issue of the WTO is, as you say, very much more about the way in which countries act within it, that the WTO as an institution actually is driving trade policy forward. That said, I think there is a big distinction between the way the WTO could and should work and the way it does work. It is absolutely legitimate to draw attention to the problem of democracy within the WTO. As you say, in theory it has 145 members, no voting, decisions by consensus, et cetera. In theory it is a very much more democratic institution than most other international institutions. In practice, as we have already alluded to and as I am sure you will find out if you to go to Geneva in the course of this inquiry, it does not work like that. The experience of the developing country delegates at the WTO is not that they are participating in a democratic process as equals with the EU, the US and the other developed countries; their experience is that they are under-resourced, they cannot attend key meetings but if they do not happen to be in the room at the moment of decision, their approval is assumed. It is passive consensus; you have actively to say "no" rather than actively say "yes". There all kinds of ways in which the day-to-day experience of developing country delegates in Geneva is that the WTO is simply not as democratic as it could be and as it should be. There are very few commentators on these issues who would say at this point that things would be better if there was no WTO but one absolutely should not make the leap from there to say, "And therefore the WTO is fine". In a sense, it is that ground that we are trying to cover.

  Chairman: I have some sympathy with Tony's point. My point is that maybe a month before the WTO lobby, the Trade Justice Movement lobby, we might see if the Committee could have an informal session with your policy advisers rather than campaigners and an exchange of views on what works so far as we as parliamentarians are concerned and what they are trying to achieve as campaigners. I agree with Tony: I think there is a danger sometimes in campaigns becoming very simplistic in single lines, and then people say that is unreal.

Mr Battle

  61. I am not sure that 27 June is going to be a mutual cuddle. Just as we think there is a quick and easy answer and that the World Trade Organisation is undemocratic, not very efficient and still playing the capitalist game, we tend to say this of the American and European farmers. I think underneath those words such as "trade openness", "trade liberalisation" and "market access" are massive unspoken hidden assumptions of different economic models and we do not really open up that debate and try and understand the complexity of it. I put it to you this way in an attempt to stir it up. I do not think it is an easy consensus about what we want or what the NGOs think they want, what poor farmers think they want or what northern Europeans and the rich world wants. An official from DEFRA last week said that as far as relations with developing countries goes, the primary purpose of CAP reform is to provide better market access, to use a phrase. In the CAFOD memo, market access is "very far from being a poverty panacea or even the most important issue for poor farmers in developing countries". I would like to ask: why is market access not a poverty panacea and what do you think poor farmers really want?
  (Mr Green) All two and a half billion of them! I start with my own experience. I went to Kenya this year and last year. Among other things, I went to see the people who grow flowers and vegetables for Marks and Spencer. If you are growing mangetout in Kenya and you want to sell to Marks and Spencer, you have to get the product from the fields to the Marks and Spencer shelf, or to the Tesco shelf, or any of the other shelves in Britain, within 48 hours in chilled conditions for as much of that time as you can. The mangetout have to be all of the same kind and the same length. There must be no kind of a blotch. Now you must use no pesticides because of the requirements of the EU. The level of technical skills, marketing skills and capital investment required is beyond most small farmers and so the small farmer is being squeezed out of that production chain. That is one reason why the kind of simplistic market access equals trade equals poverty reduction should be questioned. Actually, those markets are quite job-creating and so they do reduce poverty, but in other cases, such as soya bean exports from Brazil or Argentina, the impact on jobs is quite limited through the tax system. You have a situation where people are making a claim which they cannot back up with anything like a serious case study or research. One of the things DFID could be doing is trying to look at the cases in which export promotion has led to poverty reduction and the cases where it has not. This can lead to the expulsion of small farmers from the land if big guys come and buy it all up to grow flowers. There is far too much dogma and not enough evidence on the whole issue. I want to plug somebody else's book for a change. There is a Korean economist who is my number one guru at the moment, a chap called Ha Joon Chang. He has written a book called Kicking Away the Ladder. He goes back to the 14th century and shows how countries managed trade, intellectual property rights, investments, all the issues which are now being debated in WTO. He shows that in every case, except possibly Holland, they have always discriminated between national and international producers; they have always used high levels of state regulation. This idea that these things should now be made illegal under the WTO is, in his words, kicking away the ladder, which comes back to the point right at the beginning about the importance of looking at history when discussing this subject and not approaching it in a Chicago boys' vacuum.
  (Mr Bailey) I would add this on the market access issue. Our Trade Report emphasised that developing countries could earn about $100 billion more a year if the northern countries were less protectionist. This is looking at agriculture, footware and textiles. All the things that developing countries are good at exporting, we are good at stopping at the border. There is a clear development benefit with improved market access. However, that does not come automatically. We would argue that that market access is a necessary but not a sufficient condition for there to be benefits in the developing countries. There are a lot of other things that developing countries have to do to make sure that the benefits from exporting, as Duncan has suggested, are actually shared more widely and do not accrue simply to local elites or at the expense of the environment. Though one of the demands in Oxfam's trade campaign is to reduce these northern barriers. We have to be very careful that we do not then subscribe to the view that export-led growth is the way to go. In that sense, we do have to qualify our call for market access very quickly and very carefully.

  62. What resonance does that receive in the Agreement on Agriculture negotiations where they are still pushing very hard for export-led growth and market access, which is the final category?
  (Mr Bailey) Certainly developing country governments in Geneva are pushing hard to improve market access, along with other things.
  (Ms Melamed) The important issue with market access is the terms on which you get it. Quite often market access is offered under conditions which actually make it less useful in that countries are less able to improve their supply response in order to have more for exports. For example, the current negotiations in which the European Union is involved with the ACP countries, the Cotonou and negotiations. The idea is that the ACP countries are being pushed to move from non-reciprocal market access to reciprocal market access. The danger there is that that is going to undermine the whole way in which market access might potentially be useful. The countries that have benefited under the previous non-reciprocal regime are those that have actually used various kinds of interventionist and protectionist trade policies within their own economies in order to boost their production, in order to benefit from market access, such as Mauritius. If those options are not being made available to the ACP countries under the proposed new arrangements, market access will be a lot less useful in future than it has been in the past.
  (Mr Green) We should be careful about saying what developing countries say. The positions of developing countries usually reflect their own economic situation. The big agri-exporters, like South Africa, Egypt, Argentina and Chile, want market access. The importers are much more worried about the impact of dumping. There is one other factor. DFID has funded something called the Globalisation and Poverty Programme over the last three years, which spends £3 million on a number of research areas, such as the impact of investment, impact of trade liberalisation and what good government in the WTO looks like. The Committee might like to think about asking the researchers, who are led by Professor John Humphrey from IDS, to present their findings which should be ready by June or July.

  Chairman: We move on to special and differential treatment and development box proposals.

Mr Walter

  63. We move into the area of jargon. The Doha Declaration agreed that: "all special and differential treatment provisions shall be reviewed with a view to strengthening them and making them more precise, effective and operational". That is SDT. The development box was not actually mentioned in the declaration itself. We had, as you probably know, the DTI officials, and officials from several government departments, here last week. The DTI officials stated that the Government believes in principle that there should be appropriate special differential treatment to allow developing countries to be smoothed into the liberalised system. Is this the right objective and what, in your view, should the development box include and how would it help developing countries?
  (Ms Melamed) The development box is, in a sense, a specific instance of special and differential treatment. If you do not mind, I will start with a general discourse on special and differential treatment and then perhaps others will come in on the development box. We seem to keep coming back to your first question here about what is good trade policy from the point of view of development. The debate on special and differential treatment is perhaps, of all the debates in the WTO, the one that most closely touches on that issue. The Government's approach to special and differential treatment, outlined in what you have just said, is that the purpose of special and differential treatment is to deal with the difference between WTO members in terms of their capacity to implement WTO rules, so that, for example, with particular complex rules, it may take longer for a developing country to implement the agreement on intellectual property rights because it has to develop certain institutions and so on. It is an expensive and complicated business. Therefore, it makes sense to give developing countries longer to implement what are virtually the same rules. That was the approach taken for special and differential treatment in the Uruguay Round, and that is the approach which the UK Government, and most other industrialised country governments, are still taking. The difficulty is that it is precisely that approach which the developing countries objected to, which is why special and differential treatment is such a big issue at the moment. What the developing countries in the WTO tend to argue, and again obviously there will be differences between developing countries, put crudely is that what they require is in fact special and differential treatment which will reflect their different trade policy needs, rather than making a difference in implementation. What they need is special and differential treatment, which will actually allow them to have a different kind of trade policy for a period of time, which will allow them, as Duncan said, to do exactly what the European, American and other countries have done in terms of building up their domestic industries, protecting their vulnerable populations, and so on. That is the crux of the argument. Within the WTO, as is wont to happen with the WTO, this has taken all kinds of political and bizarre twists and turns. The outcome, after nearly a year, has been absolutely nothing. Despite the very heavy engagement of developing countries in this process, very little has happened. Actually, apart from the importance of issues of special and differential treatment, there has been an interesting test case on the capacity arguments in the WTO. We are used to hearing that the problem with developing countries in the WTO is that they lack capacity and therefore if you put money into capacity-building, everything will be OK. In the special and differential treatment discussions, in fact there has probably been an equal level of participation from developed countries. They have put in an enormous amount of resources; they have taken all the advice they can take; and yet, even when they put in equal amounts of resources and even when capacity is less of an issue, they still do not get what they want. That is something of an aside but it gives you quite an important indication into the realities of power politics in the WTO.

  Chairman: Hugh Bayley has two specific questions on SDT and then we will come back to the other questions on the development box.

Hugh Bayley

  64. First of all, Claire, can you tell me a little bit more about the framework agreement your paper talks about? How would that work? Can I link to that: is there not a danger that too much SDT will undermine the principle of reciprocity upon which the whole WTO edifice is based?
  (Ms Melamed) I will start with the framework agreement. The idea of the framework agreement was first mooted by a group of developing countries before Doha as something they wanted to put on the table as a possible way of dealing with this.

  65. Can you remember who they were?
  (Ms Melamed) I think Pakistan, Kenya and India were involved. I can send you the original proposal that they tabled in the WTO[13]The idea was essentially to deal in advance with the kinds of problems that had come up in discussion. At the moment, the way the special and differential treatment is dealt with tends to be on an agreement-by-agreement basis, so that developing countries have to negotiate the special differential in agriculture, industry, TRIPS and so on. Basically what they have to do in WTO, in the mercantilist way in which the WTO operates, is to give something away every time. In a sense, they are negotiating the same point over and over again in each agreement, that they need to have more flexibility, they need to have longer implementation times. They are achieving the same thing every time and yet having to give something away separately every time. The political purpose of the framework agreement is to prevent that happening. If we think collectively as WTO members that this is an appropriate way of dealing with the differences between countries in the WTO, then let us set that out at the outset rather than having to negotiate it separately every time. That was the political purpose of the framework agreement. The economic purpose was as I have just said. It came from this understanding of the history of trade policy, that developing countries have specific requirements in terms of trade policy, in terms of being able perhaps to use a wider range of trade policy instruments than a more industrialised county needs, and that therefore that should also be reflected in WTO agreements. I think the whole experience of what has happened to special and differential treatment since Doha has borne out that political calculation, that developing countries are going to be required to pay an extremely high price come Cancun for whatever they get in special and differential treatment. In a sense, everyone agrees that they should get special and differential treatment but yet everyone is returning to extract the maximum possible price for that.

  66. I have one little supplementary on that point before we move on. If you have within a framework agreement an acceptance that the least developed countries, or some developing countries, should simply notify, shall we say, the WTO what their SDT requirements would be in relation to TRIPS or whatever it might be, there will come a point of course when least developed countries graduate out of the need for special assistance. That, of course, is the critical issue. It is about when Malaysia, for instance, needs the ladder and when it is reasonable for the ladder to be kicked away. How do you deal with that issue if you have institutionalised special terms of trade? How do you deal with the graduation?
  (Ms Melamed) The graduation issue is one of the matters that is holding everything up. The WTO at the moment has this rather bizarre system where the category of developing countries is self-selective, so that any country can simply announce that it is a developing country and receive the benefits due to it. The United Nations category is used for least developed countries. There has been an enormous amount of debate on this subject. It is one of the things that is really holding up the whole discussion. This is an illustration of the problems with the way WTO works, that in a sense the politics of the situation get in the way of what are perfectly sensible economic discussions. At the moment, there is huge resistance by developing countries even to discuss the issue of graduation because they fear that basically it will be used as a device to give away less things to less countries, whereas in private some of them do agree that obviously it is something that will have to be discussed. Even some of the developing countries' proposals do have the germs of ideas about differentiation. Perhaps the most sensible way to look at it would be to have a framework agreement which set out a requirement that within each agreement there should be special and differential treatment; that it should be designed in such a way as to give developing countries more flexibility for development purposes; and that within each specific agreement there has to be some kind of consensus on the criteria that could be used to define which countries could be eligible for special and differential treatment under that agreement. The special and differential treatment has to be appropriate to the problems which it is designed to solve. Clearly, there may be some countries that would require much greater flexibility in their agricultural policy which perhaps would not require it in their industrial policy, and vice versa. It is important to make sure that the instruments countries are allowed to use are appropriate to the particular problems that they have.

  67. May I make one comment in leaving that? I do not think the problem is just in terms of defining the countries which are least developed or developing and therefore need special and differential treatment, but it is in designing the process of removing that assistance in a way that does not simply knock them back to square one. There is the graduation process but there is an economic problem as well as one of definition. That is a comment. Duncan, you said in your paper that you wished that trade rules could be redesigned to distinguish between social groups and not just between countries. I wondered how that could possibly be achieved? What does it mean? Does it not undermine the role of the government in a developed country which has the responsibility to pursue economic policies for poverty alleviation and a more equal society?
  (Mr Green) That is all about squaring various circles and this is an attempt to square the development circle, if you like. If you are presented with a large country, and let us take Brazil where you have millions of small farmers and a few tens of thousands of very big farmers, somehow it is very arbitrary to apply the same trade rules to both those groups. In the past, trade rules have always been done country by country. The development box is an attempt to see whether trade rules could be designed in such a way to be a filter and only apply to certain social groups. This actually already exists in the Agreement on Agriculture. There is talk of special rules for low income and resource-poor farmers. There is talk of special rules for staple foods in the existing rules on agriculture; it is just that no one has really picked it up. We took that existing stuff and said that staple foods are mainly grown by the poor, not by the rich, in developing countries—that is a very generalised view—and if the low income, resource-poor farmers exist, then surely we can have trade rules which do things like allowing governments to exempt staple foods from liberalisation commitments or allowing them to subsidise low income, resource-poor farmers in ways that they cannot subsidise big farmers? This is about trying to drill down a little bit below these national categories, which I think is an alternative to this endless attempt to differentiate between developing countries. There are poor people in Brazil and in Ghana: why do we have to classify Brazil as one thing and Ghana as another if we can find a rule which picks up poor people in both countries?

Chairman

  68. That is helpful and brings us back to Robert Walter's question: what in your view should the development box include and how would it help developing countries?
  (Mr Green) I laughed when I read the transcript and the awful idea of spending a Sunday afternoon in Oxford debating what a development box is. That rings true. The development box is a way of talking about development in WTO jargon, and in particular in the case of agriculture. It is asking how we can talk about development in such a way that people in Geneva understand what we are on about. That is the big picture. Specifically it means that you have a set of exemptions and allowances within the Agreement on Agriculture which deal with precisely this problem: small farmers and staple food producers. The experience is that one of the worst impacts of over-hasty trade liberalisation has been the impact on those small farmers. There is a group called Friends of the Development Box; there is Friends of Fish, Friends of Geographical Indicators and there are all sorts of bizarre groups in Geneva. The key proposal of Friends of the Development Box is to exempt staple foods from reduction commitments. There is a number of other bits and pieces within the development box. I would say that is at the heart of it. Can you take staple foods and treat them differently within the trade rules? That received a lot of interest in Doha. There was a head of steam. It did not make it into the ministerial declaration, and that is a great shame. There has been a number of submissions since. DFID has taken the issue seriously. The EU has taken the issue seriously in its own way, which is to co-opt language and remove almost all content. The EU has now said it supports what it calls a food security box, and actually it has much less in the box than developing countries would like to see, but it has successfully confounded the campaign for the development box by doing that.

Mr Walter

  69. I want to pursue the development box idea because there is a danger, is there not, and I think the DEFRA officials we had here last week did not say any different, that agricultures become isolated and that actually what you should be doing is trying to encourage them to diversify, to get into different areas where they would be competitive, rather than just protecting and effectively ossifying their own domestic agriculture. Do you think there is that danger?
  (Mr Green) I come back to Michael's point, that that requires good government policy over a long period of time and a transition, not a vast swathe being cut through small producers. Something like 97% of the world's small farmers are in developing countries. The enormous majority produce for the domestic market. The idea that all of them are going to start growing mangetout is not clearly thought through. UNCTAD in the last Trade and Development Report said, especially for the larger countries, that those countries like China and India are going to have to develop on the basis of their domestic markets and there have to be domestic linkages, and not on the basis of export loan credit. There is just not enough demand for that level of export. The term "ossify"is very emotive language and we would not want to condemn those two and a half billion people for being poor; they have had terrible lives as under-resourced farmers. But trade liberalisation right now is not going to make things better. The experience of the FAO, UNCTAD and NGOs has been that it makes it worse. The question is: how much will a more holistic view of an agricultural policy help those farmers improve their productivity? It may help some of them move into international trade, but the market access that matters, and will continue to matter to those small farmers, is access to their domestic markets.

  Tony Worthington: Take the case of Caribbean bananas. What about trade patterns that are historical and those Caribbean banana producers have been producing not for their domestic market but for the export market but they have been protected? Should we not be looking at things that they could produce more efficiently to replace the bananas that could be produced much more cheaply elsewhere in central America?

Chairman

  70. Anybody else want to talk about bananas?
  (Mr Green) I am not a bananas person.

  71. Michael, do you want to talk about bananas?
  (Mr Bailey) No.
  (Mr Green) The answer is yes.

Tony Worthington

  72. One of the areas where there is agreement by everybody is that the developing countries, not all of them but many, are ill-equipped for the negotiations within the WTO and that if the WTO is, in the future, going back to what I said earlier, to be seen as a positive force for developing countries, we have to do something about that negotiating capacity. How should that be done?
  (Ms Melamed) The first and most obvious thing that should be done is, if not to reduce it, to limit it to the number of issues that are on the WTO table, and within those constraints of the number of issues that we are dealing with there are then various other measures about boosting capacity that could be done over the long term, but I think the most immediate short term response to that is to say that if we all accept that there is a problem of capacity we have to stop where we are now and not have any new issues.
  (Mr Bailey) We would agree with that. Also, the way that the WTO does its business and reaches its agreements is problematic for developing countries. As you know, since the Uruguay Round what they employ is the method of a single undertaking, so-called, which means that they negotiate a whole series of agreements (in the case of the Uruguay Round a vast number of agreements) and then agree them, all or none, so you are either completely in or you are completely out. This means that developing countries have to sign up to a whole bundle of things at the same time. In the case of the Uruguay Round they really did not understand half of what they were signing up to or the implications of it. We would like to see a reversion to the old way of doing business at the GATT, which is to negotiate agreement by agreement. Then developing countries can know what they are getting into and be conscious of what the implications are for them rather than have this huge package to which at the end of the day they have no choice but to say, "Yes, we agree". This links the point about the volume and pace of the agenda in Geneva.

  73. Neither of those points is about negotiating capacity or about building the capacity of the developing countries. They are about slowing down what is coming at them.
  (Mr Green) Yes. There was an interesting study by Sheila Page of the ODI, funded by the Globalisation and Poverty Programme—I do not know if she is going to be a witness—who has compared developing country participation in a number of different negotiating fora, including the climate change negotiations under WTO, and has come up with some ideas on how that can be improved. One interesting one is that the best way to learn about negotiating is to negotiate and that the countries that have been involved long term in WTO or other negotiations are much more skilled at it and much more aware of it. The logical conclusion from that is that the whole round structure is questionable, and that permanent negotiations actually lead to capacity building in a way that endless seminars from consultants flying into the capital city and giving a talk do not. She sees ideas that can be picked from other UN processes which could be useful to the WTO. As far as I know none of that kind of thinking is going on except in the ODI. I have got her paper here which I can leave[14]It is fairly short by ODI standards.

  (Ms Melamed) Can I sum up that what we are all saying is that the problems to capacity lie in the structure of the WTO rather than in bunging in a few more million quid to run a few more seminars, because I think that approach has been tried and developing countries in Geneva are rather cynical about that approach and NGOs are becoming so.

  74. I am a bit surprised that none of you has suggested building up capacity on a regional basis. We are recently back from Malawi and are therefore familiar with SADC. I think it is difficult to believe that Malawi, given the size of the country and the under-development, could realistically cope with all of Geneva on its own in the foreseeable future.
  (Mr Green) Sheila is one of Malawi's negotiators.

  75. In one of them?
  (Mr Green) In one of the summits, yes.

  76. But the regional point. That is how we do it, is it not, in the European Union?
  (Ms Melamed) Yes. I think in Geneva to some extent developing countries do do that informally. There is a strong Africa Group which organises among itself and there is an informal division of labour within that group as to which countries will be focusing on which negotiations. I think it is an important approach where it comes from the countries themselves and where it is based on definitions of mutual self-interest. The danger comes if it is imposed—"You are all in southern Africa so you must have the same interests", whereas in fact, for example, in southern Africa there are a number of occasions on which South Africa has taken a very different negotiating stance from other southern African countries, so I think there is a danger of assuming that because they are all developing countries they must all have the same negotiating interests. That often is not the case but I think there is a lot of mileage in self-selecting groups, sometimes regionally-based, sometimes issue-based, and that is actually happening in Geneva.
  (Mr Green) But there are also a lot of stories—this is all on the level of gossip in Geneva—that where regional groupings do emerge countries who are negotiating against them do their best to undermine the unity of those groups. There is a lot of talk, for example, about (and these are all allegations) the US using AGOA (the African Growth and Opportunity Act) to pick off certain countries who are key within the Africa Group and thereby weaken its voice. It is not as if everybody is saying, "Oh, great. Our negotiating partners are better at negotiating now". That is not how it works.
  (Mr Bailey) Just on the capacity building, clearly there is a need. It is important that the capacity building that is provided, the resources that are provided, do go to genuinely assist developing countries work out what is in their interests and how to negotiate. Our anxiety is that some of the resources that have gone for capacity building are actually about helping developing countries implement WTO agreements, in other words, to conform, if you like, to what is expected of them by the system rather than understanding more clearly what their interests are and how to battle for them.

  77. You have said that we should drop the new issues in the forthcoming negotiations. What do the developing countries themselves feel about that?
  (Mr Bailey) It is quite difficult to know exactly what they feel. When we talk to most of them in private, and certainly when they were making public declarations before the Doha Ministerial, the majority of them are against the expansion of the WTO agenda. But through a variety of means which we can go into if you like, they were persuaded to accept at the Doha Ministerial that negotiations could start after the Fifth Ministerial, the Cancun Ministerial, which is coming up. However, a number of them were still unhappy with that and, as you may recall, India mounted a last-ditch effort to keep the door open at Cancun to not starting negotiations on these new issues. So we have this rather strange situation where formally negotiations can start after Cancun but any country can say, "We do not agree with the scope of the discussions", or the scope of the negotiations or the details, and therefore indefinitely postpone starting negotiations. Before Doha the least developed countries and the African-Caribbean-Pacific countries came out clearly against negotiating the 'new issues'. But by a variety of devices, including particularly skilful manipulation, I would say, Pascal Lamy managed to persuade them to go along with it at Doha. Currently, there are one or two countries that clearly are in support of the new issues—Korea at the top end, almost the OECD end, of the developing countries scale, and Costa Rica, but I would say the majority are against and if they had a free choice they would not expand the agenda.

  78. What would happen if you had your way, if new issues were put on the backburner? That does not mean those issues would have no activity associated with them. I assume that bilateral activity would go on and that it would be taken out of the framework of the WTO. Would there be a down side to that?
  (Mr Bailey) There have been discussions at the WTO since 1996 when a working group on trade and investment started, for example, so discussion would continue within the WTO on negotiation of new rules and possibly market access as well. Investment, procurement, and competition can be subjects of regional trade agreements and clearly we would be concerned if the Americans were successful, for example, in pushing these through in their bilateral treaties. The sad fact is, though, that although we have the multilateral process on a whole range of economic governance issues it does not stop the bilaterals. It would be nice if they did but I think that is the reality. What we do say is that there are important issues to do with investment, competition and procurement that need addressing by the international community. We know that there are problems of cartels, for example, in some international commodity markets. We know that there are problems of market domination in coffee or in grains. Restrictive business practices abound and they operate internationally—tax evasion, tax avoidance by companies, transfer pricing, use of tax havens. There is a whole series of issues concerning management of the international economy that we do want to see addressed in order to assist developing countries. What we are saying though is that that is not what the rich countries are proposing when they propose expanding the WTO agenda. What they are about much more is increasing market access and actually deregulating international investment.
  (Mr Green) WTO is the wrong place. Everything gets sucked into the WTO because it has a court and it has teeth vis-a-vis the settlement procedure, but actually one of the WTO's two core principles is national treatment. You have to treat foreign entities at least as well as domestic entities and for all the historical reasons I laid out earlier that does not work for investment. You actually have to distinguish between foreign and national. Our argument is that it is just the wrong place and also you have got to find a forum that can balance the rights and responsibilities of large companies and that will not happen in the WTO.

Mr Khabra

  79. The WTO is holding Mini-Ministerials to ensure that sufficient progress is made prior to Cancun. What is your view of Mini-Ministerials and should we welcome them as a way to break the deadlock in trade negotiations or condemn them as limiting the effective participation of developing countries in trade negotiations?
  (Ms Melamed) It is a difficult one. I think to some extent in the WTO with the very large membership there is a kind of efficiency/equity trade-off and that if you have meetings with smaller numbers of people then you will be looking to get faster progress. The question is really what you want in the WTO. Do you want progress or do you want good rules? We would argue that the Mini-Ministerial process is perhaps erring on the side of efficiency at the cost of equity within the WTO process and that there is a real danger with having a small group of countries where it tends to be the same countries invited over and over again, that they are being given in a sense a privileged position in decision-making, other countries by definition being squeezed out of that process, and there is a danger that what you come out with may be decisions but they may not be the right decisions.
  (Mr Green) It is an extraordinary situation. I asked DFID once if they would fund the WTO on the basis of its governance. There is a de facto executive committee, which is what Mini-Ministerial is becoming, where it is down to the host country to decide who to invite, presumably in consultation with the WTO Secretariat, but the whole thing is completely unaccountable, completely un-transparent, and they may or may not help break deadlocks but where is the governance in all this? It is rather worrying. For example, the next Mini-Mi, as they are now called, is taking place in Tokyo this weekend. They are discussing agriculture as the main issue and as far as I can see from the list of countries there is not a single one of the countries that proposed the Development Box invited. That is probably an accident but that means where is the accountability in that? No-one has been involved in making that decision. It is very worrying.
  (Mr Bailey) It is a hand-picked group of developing countries, certainly the larger ones, because you cannot not invite Nigeria or Brazil. But in the case of the Tokyo Mini-Ministerial, Bangladesh, the current Chair of the least developed countries group, which is obviously really important from the development perspective, was not invited. Of the Africa Group you have Senegal and Lesotho, who are fairly tame; they are not the outspoken ones who are going to raise tricky issues. Particularly for the smaller countries there is definitely a problem of inability to participate in key moments in moving things forward.


13   Proposal for a Framework Agreement on Special and Differential Treatment, WT/GC/W/442, 19 September 2001, World Trade Organization. Available at: http://www.wto.org/english/thewto-e/minist-e/min01-e/proposals-e/wt-gc-w442.pdf Back

14   Developing Countries: Victims or Participants. Their Changing Role in International Negotiations' Sheila Page, Globalisation and Poverty Programme, Overseas Development Institute: http://www.odi.org.uk/iedg/Publications/dev-countries-web.pdf Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 21 March 2003