Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 300-308)

TUESDAY 29 APRIL 2003

MR JONATHAN PEEL, MR SIMON HARRIS, MS RUTH RAWLING AND MR CHRIS TYAS

Tony Worthington

  300. Yes, but I am using them as an example?
  (Mr Tyas) Perhaps I can just explain a little bit some of the situation on coffee; but, particularly in the light of Mr Khabra's question during the previous session, on coffee prices, I would like to say very clearly, from the beginning—

  Chairman: Can I say, also, I think Piara has another question he wants to put. I am sorry, we will not lose it, Tony. Piara has another question he wants to put on coffee; so why does not Piara put his question on coffee as well and then you can respond to them all, rather than having two bites. Is that alright, Tony?

  Tony Worthington: Yes.

Mr Khabra

  301. This question is following the question which I asked earlier on and you listened to the response made by the first group. Now my question to you particularly, Chris, is because Nestlé is a big producer where coffee is concerned, and could you say what role processors and retailers can play in seeking to address the coffee crisis? That is one question. And, following that, will your members be supporting and participating in the International Coffee Organisation meeting which is taking place on 19 and 20 May? What can Nestlé do to persuade competitors to support such initiatives?
  (Mr Tyas) I think, first of all, I have to say very clearly that Nestlé is not in favour of the low coffee price environment, not only is it bad for farmers but, as predominantly a soluble coffee producer, instant coffee producer, then it is bad for our business. Perhaps if I take just a few minutes to explain that, in terms of two sorts of coffee, basically, soluble coffee and roast and ground coffee. If you buy a soluble coffee then you have to have behind that a large amount of processing in which to be able to turn it into the instant product that you consume, which has a high capital cost and processing cost and skilled people behind it. If you take roast and ground, the ground coffee, then the price of that moves up and down purely at the green coffee price. So at a time with very low coffee prices then ground coffee becomes much more competitive in real terms, because the green coffee is a higher proportion of the total cost, than does soluble coffee; so it is bad for our business as well as being bad for the farmers. But let me say that the fundamental problem of low coffee prices is actually supply exceeding demand, so the most that we can possibly do to aid, whether it is ourselves or the retailers, is to increase coffee consumption. To put it in very simple terms, last year's production of coffee was 117 million bags, but only 109 million were consumed; you can all see the answer to that. And, fundamentally, you go back to the mid 1990s, you look at the World Bank subsidisation of production in Vietnam and you see the size of production in Vietnam today has changed that fundamentally. Nestlé as a whole has worked very hard to grow consumption; in the last 10 years, coffee consumption has grown by about 17%, as a whole, but Nestlé have grown their part of the market, the instant coffee market, by 40%. But, clearly, that is the main way in which we can increase the price paid to the farmer. If I turn to Mr Worthington's question for a moment, and I would like to come back to your last one, on the ICO, afterwards, in terms of seeing Nescafé in the developing market, the market of origin, we are trying to add more and more value in the country of origin. So, if you look at Nescafé today, something like 55% of that is processed in the country of origin and then shipped as instant coffee, it is not packed necessarily in the country of origin, in fact, it is not normally packed in the country of origin, because that adds a huge amount clearly to transport costs, and in fact to duties, because of the escalating tariff. The chief area of escalation, rather in the way our colleague, Ruth Rawling, has put it, is not at the stage of processing, turning it into instant coffee, but is at the stage of packing, or filling into jars, or something like that. So the coffee that you drank in the country of origin quite probably was processed there, and indeed packed there, it had not been taken to a developed country and then shipped back.

Tony Worthington

  302. You see, there is a central point here, that you see this formidable disincentive to developing countries going into manufacturing, processing, value-added areas, because of the tariffs. What I would like to know is whether, if those tariffs disappear, you think there will be a great surge of value-added activity in the developing world, or are there other barriers, other difficulties, other obstacles, that will stop the benefit of removing those tariffs coming through?
  (Mr Tyas) I think there are other barriers. As Ruth Rawling said earlier, the tariff at a primary process level at the moment is not all that great, it is particularly at the packing level; but there are other barriers, political instability is another. If you take another major commodity, which companies are interested in, as is Cargill, it is cocoa. Cocoa is sourced largely from the Côte d'Ivoire, and the Côte d'Ivoire, to some extent, has moved into primary processing, into cocoa liqueur. Now, clearly, in the period of political instability that the Côte d'Ivoire has been through, that has put companies that depend upon that in a great degree of difficulty. So it is not the only factor involved.

  303. On a wider plain, how big a factor is it; will there be no development of manufacturing or processing unless those tariffs are removed, or will there still not be development if those tariffs are removed?
  (Ms Rawling) Chris, if I may just make a point here. I think one of the things you have to look at in the processing chain for food is what does it consist of? Does it consist of major capital investment, because some very sophisticated, highly developed processing, producing highly sophisticated processed products were involved; in that case, the advantage of that capital investment, by and large, seems likely to remain in the developed countries. Whereas, if you look at a product which has a large amount of labour involved in its production then it is much more likely, because many developing countries have an advantage with their labour costs, that that production could happen in a developing country. I can speak briefly about poultry. There is a growing western market for white poultry meat products which it is very difficult to meet from home production because people do not want poultry farms expanding all the time in the countryside. So what is happening is that poultry production is growing in some of the countries that previously have been mentioned, and the processing of that poultry meat, because it is very labour-intensive, is something that can be done very well in developing countries, providing it is done to a very high standard. That kind of processing we are seeing growing rapidly in countries like Thailand, Brazil, and I would expect in the future in China, because the labour cost involved gives the developing countries a comparative advantage.

Chairman

  304. Just before we move on to sugar, can I ask just two, very quick, naïve questions. Ethiopia. Ethiopia is so poor they cannot afford fertilisers or pesticides, so, by definition, their coffee is organic. There is a premium for organic goods; why would it not be possible increasingly to market Ethiopian coffee as organic coffee per se?
  (Mr Tyas) We do buy, in fact, a great deal of Ethiopian coffee, but most coffees that are preferred by the consumer are a blend of different coffees, and therefore are unlikely to be 100% Ethiopian in origin, but certainly they make up a very large fraction of many of the coffees that I am sure you consume.

  305. And the second question, in relation to the difficulties with cocoa in Côte d'Ivoire, to what percent does that present an opportunity for Ghana and Syria and other countries on the west coast to increase their capacity? There must be a benefit to the countries demonstrating stability, that they will increase their yields?
  (Mr Tyas) It provides a very great opportunity, and much further afield even than that, in that one sees already Vietnamese farmers growing cocoa to replace some of their coffee plants, clearly with the low prices involved.

Mr Walter

  306. The Chairman said, in the earlier session, that probably we eat too much chocolate, and I think probably we all consume too much sugar, and it is in many processed products, as you will be aware. Perhaps I can just quote what is a slightly provocative statement from Oxfam, "The Great EU Sugar Scam," it is right on the front cover. It says: "European consumers and taxpayers are paying to destroy livelihoods in developing countries. Under the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP), the EU has emerged as the world's largest exporter of white sugar. Subsidies and tariffs generate vast profits for big sugar processors and large farmers—and vast surpluses that are dumped on world markets." Not my words. Now the EU's sugar regime is going to be reformed, I think that probably is inevitable, but what sort of reform would the Food and Drink Federation favour, and what relevance, what weight, do you give to the concerns of the developing countries, the other sugar producers in the world, and are there any conflicts in your position? And we might want to hear from British Sugar on this, between the position of the producers, the food manufacturers, who use the sugar, and somebody like British Sugar, who is actually a producer as well as a processor?
  (Mr Peel) The Food and Drink Federation is a very broad church, we represent something like 95% of all the food manufacturing industry in this country. Obviously, we work very hard to get a common position wherever we can; sugar is one area that probably we find harder, far harder than any other area, and what we say is that, on the one hand, the primary processors say this, which you will hear from Simon in a minute, and, on the other hand, the secondary users say that, and I am sure you will hear from Chris in a minute too.
  (Mr Harris) I think, as a first point, that as a point of fact, we should all remember, is that in the United Kingdom, actually we share this market 50/50 with developing country suppliers; so, when people make comments about the European sugar regime, I think it is important to bear in mind the point that actually the nub of those comments should be directed at the Continent. The UK has kept a balance between beet and cane as an objective of Government policy since before the Second World War; the proportion has altered over time, particularly when we joined the EU, but even now it is about 50/50, roughly. And the second point is that our quota is such that we do not have surplus quota sugar, we sell all our beet sugar quota in the UK market; if you like, we have that luxury, whereas countries like France have a quota which is double their consumption, in Belgium it is even higher than that. So, although we are sitting in the UK, when we are talking about the sugar regime and the excesses of the sugar regime, we need to be looking more towards the continent than the UK context, if I can so put it. The next point is that, actually, our own beet sugar processing industry, is among the top three in the world as a processor, and our beet sugar industry as a whole, including the growing of the agricultural crop, is one of the most efficient in the EU; so we have a good industry here. Also, through Tate and Lyle, there is a very good cane-refining industry here; so we have efficient industries here. When it comes to reform of the sugar regime, the point to bring out, which no-one will love me for, is that, in reality, it is very complex, because the sugar regime is trying to achieve several policy objectives at the same time, and, as normal, when you are trying to do that, you get something which is very complex, and you get into issues, even within the EU, like efficiency versus regionalisation. At the moment, the quota system allows sugar beet to be grown throughout the EU, and the southern EU Member States, for example, place a lot of importance on this, because some of their other, alternative crops, like cotton, are under attack as well. Also, the EU gives very significant preferences to developing countries for sugar already. The ACP Arrangements, the African, Caribbean and Pacific Arrangements, which are a direct lineal successor of the Commonwealth Sugar Agreement, have been in place since about 1951, if you include the Commonwealth Sugar Agreement in that. The recent innovation has been the "Everything But Arms" Initiative, which for sugar will not start to phase in fully until 2006, and will come into full application in 2009, I think. But we have here a conflict. If we are saying that the objective of sugar regime reform is to lower prices in the EU then we are going to lower the prices to a lot of poor countries in the ACP, and we are going to devalue any investment that the EBA countries might make, in order to supply the EU market. Because, as has already been said, sugar is very much an example of a capital-intensive industry; it is the most capital-intensive of any soft commodity to process. If you build a new cane mill or a new beet factory then you are into hundreds of millions of dollars. So if we are saying that by having this initiative for the EBA countries, we have opened up our market, or are going to open up our market to them, access is one thing but value is another matter. If they have access at the world market price then it is no use to them, because they cannot compete at the world market price. The world market price, of course, is a residual price, highly distorted, but Brazil is the only country that can take advantage of free trade.

  307. So you are saying that, to set an extreme example, if we abandon completely the sugar regime, quotas, tariffs and all the rest of it, in fact, that would not have the desired advantage, other than maybe to Brazil?
  (Mr Harris) Yes.

  308. What would it do to the European sugar industry?
  (Mr Harris) A good question. Two points. One, how much reform is there going to be in the rest of agricultural production, and what is that going to do to land prices, because the value of support, of course, is capitalised into land values; and, secondly, are we going to be allowed to include sugar beet in the system of decoupled farm payments, in which case we may find that quite a lot of the European sugar production is still quite competitive. Just because it is grown in Europe does not mean necessarily that it is per se uncompetitive, particularly if you had a less distorted world market; the trouble is, everyone says European consumers are paying a price three times the world price, but the world price does not represent anything, and that is one of the problems about this whole exercise. European sugar yields are a technical measure rather than a financial measure, but European sugar yields expressed on a per hectare basis are much higher than most cane sugar producing countries, not necessarily all but certainly most; and technical innovation in the beet sugar industry has been far faster than in the cane sugar industry, where, indeed, in many countries, there has been a stagnation of yields in recent years.
  (Mr Tyas) I think Jonathan explained that there is a divergence of view, clearly, within the Food and Drink Federation, between the primary processor, we try to represent, and the manufacturer, such as ourselves. From our position, we find ourselves that UK food manufacturers are at a substantial disadvantage with competitors in other Member States and third world countries, because of the EU sugar regime. It is quite right to say that, although that disadvantage is something like threefold at the moment, because it is about three times the world market price that we have to pay in our factories, that factories on the edge of the EU, for example, have to pay, if there were a less distorted market, without the kinds of restrictions for the countries of Mozambique, Australia, or anywhere else, to access the EU for its sugar, then the difference would be less than that. But I think most of the surveys, and indeed the Oxfam survey itself says that the difference would still be something like a half what it is today. Those high costs mean that undoubtedly there is a loss of jobs, there is a loss of exports, and there is an impact on investment decisions that are made by major companies because they will try to source at areas which can access much lower sugar prices than you can in the UK today. I think, however, probably it does bring us back to the first question which was asked, which was the WTO round, and our views on that, and a lot of the exports that go outside of the EU are at the moment only vaguely competitive because of the restitutions, because of the export subsidies. If those export subsidies are to disappear then we have to see a corresponding reduction in the input price, and sugar is the classic example which we are talking about at the moment, but dairy products also are included in that, otherwise we will see a large loss of jobs and of export income into this country.

  Chairman: I think we will look and see both of those statements. I think we could have a dialogue on this for a long time. Let us look at both those statements in the written text and I think to segregate them out in a while, because I think those two answers just demonstrate the complexity of what we are having to deal with, in a sense, in this. Thank you very much for coming and giving evidence this afternoon. Thank you very much too for coming and giving evidence kind of simultaneously wearing two hats, which I think must always require enormous discipline, both as being part of a trade federation and giving collective views, and also ensuring that your own individual sectoral views are not forgotten. So thank you for that; and thank you, Jonathan, for co-ordinating it.





 
previous page contents

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 9 June 2003