Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 187-199)

COMMISSIONER FRANZ FISCHLER AND MS MAEVE DORAN

THURSDAY 20 MARCH 2003

Chairman

  187. Thank you for giving your time in what we know is an extremely busy day. Last time you and I met was when I was Douglas Hogg's deputy minister during the BSE crisis and I was also the UK fisheries minister. So I am glad that we meet in happier circumstances! We, as you know, are Parliament's development committee. We are conducting an inquiry into trade and development and we are obviously interested in what is happening in the Doha Round. I know that a number of my colleagues will have detailed questions about CAP policy, market access, Special and Differential Treatment. I wonder if I could start with a slightly broader policy question? I suppose that broadly, over the Iraq crisis, what we have seen is a failure in some ways of multilateralism where, from my perspective—other colleagues may have a different view—history is being written that the failure of multilateralism was due to some of our European Union colleagues, and it was for that reason that a coalition of the willing had to go it alone. I caricature, but I hope that I make my point. In a sense, there is not very much for the United States to get out of the WTO. If Doha fails, if the WTO fails, what is the downside for the United States? For Doha to succeed, therefore, the United States have to get something in return. It is quite clear that one of the things that they are looking for in return are some concessions on agriculture from the European Union. We had the fortune to meet Commissioner Lamy last night, who said, "Actually, there's no need for any concessions on agriculture because the CAP . . .—we are there". I think that is a fair summary of what Commissioner Lamy said. I make no value judgment about that; it is factually what he said. What prospects do you see of the WTO negotiations succeeding if the European Union is not able to make any further substantial concessions on CAP reform and meeting the agenda in the United States?

  (Commissioner Fischler) Thank you very much for giving me the opportunity to have this exchange of views. Thank you also for agreeing with me that, in the end in 1996, we managed the BSE crisis rather well, and we still have fish—we do not have mad fish, for the moment at least! Coming to your question, it is clear that there is a risk that, after this war, more unilateralism could take place in the world. On the other hand, I still believe that, exactly for that reason, we have to do everything we can to make sure that multilateralism will continue, because this is the only way forward. If you say that there is not much in this round for the US and therefore they could not have much interest, first of all we are speaking about the round and not only about agriculture. The round is much broader and covers many other things, not only agriculture. Secondly, we are speaking about the Doha development agenda and I am not aware that the US is a developing country. It is therefore quite right that there is not much for the US in this round in the agricultural sector, because there should be a lot for the developing countries and not so much for the developed countries. We see this rather differently, I must say, and now I will focus more on the agricultural sector. First of all, if we look at what has happened in the last years, you can see that the European Union is by far the biggest importer in the world. It is also by far the biggest importer of agricultural products from developing countries. We alone import more agricultural goods from developing countries than the US, Canada, Japan and Australia together. What we are asking in this round is that we should have a fairer burden-sharing. This is what is on the table for the negotiations. Unfortunately, we must say that in the last draft from Mr Harbinson we do not see that. We know that our US friends are asking for more market access, but this more market access is at the cost of developing countries. You will therefore understand that it is difficult for us to agree with that. It is also no longer true that the reason for the distortions in agricultural trade is our agricultural support. Our agricultural support, on export subsidies, compared with the value of the export, is more or less insignificant. If you look at the different commodities and the different sectors, however, then, to be fair, there are sectors where we still have a problem—and we clearly have to deal with these problems. This is also part of our reform process, therefore. Looking at the developments in the different commodities in the last years, you can also see that our market share is much lower than it was in the past. Our export share decreased in more or less all sectors. The only field where we gain is with the highly processed goods. There we are not in competition with the developing countries. For example, with our wine exports or our exports of ham and similar products, there is no direct competition with the developing countries. The other element where there is a discussion is the question of internal support. When we speak about internal support, the decisive question is which kind of support is trade-distorting and how do we reduce trade-distorting support. The problem here is that, with our reforms—we started in 1992 with the McSherry reform, but also with the reform in Agenda 2000 and the proposals which are now on the table—we have always gone in the same direction. We reduce the more trade-distorting trade elements and partly increase those elements which are not trade distorting. Unfortunately, our American friends have done the opposite—especially with their last Farm Bill. This is where we now have a rather difficult discussion. This is also now part of the negotiations in Geneva, with these new proposals. What we are asking for is nothing else but that, primarily, we would like to see a level playing field. We cannot accept that, for example on export competition, we have to phase out altogether our form of export subsidisation and others can continue their export subsidisation. Their form of export subsidisation has the same trade-distorting effect. There is no difference. In Mr Harbinson's last proposal, as it is drafted, there are also big loopholes where, for example, our American friends can continue with their practice of giving export credits, or with their abuse of food aid. Similarly with their internal support. It is really unacceptable that we are prepared to move away from amber box measures but, in Mr Harbinson's concept, the amber box is treated not so differently from the blue box. If you look at what the OECD says in the study they published recently, however, they say that the trade-distorting effect—if you make the relationship and calculate a ratio between the trade-distorting effect of their new amber box measures, their new counter-cyclical approach, compared with blue box measures—there is a ratio of 1:4. In other words, their form of internal support is four times more trade distorting than our form of internal support. This is what we have to discuss. There is also an important additional point which we should discuss further. We are always speaking about developing countries, but is it right, especially in agriculture, to put all the developing countries on the same footing? If you compare the competitiveness of Brazil, for example, with that of a sub-Saharan African country, it is like day and night. Nowadays and in certain areas, Brazil is perhaps more competitive than even the US—for example, if I look at the soya market and what is going on there. We should therefore be somewhat careful. I know that this is very difficult, because there is a UN definition and we will not change it—but it is a matter of fact that, economically speaking, it is not very logical just to speak about "developing countries". If we look at what has happened with Everything But Arms, we are prepared to do more—and especially to do more for developing countries and for the poorest countries amongst those developing countries. I think that this is what has to be reflected. We have a real problem where there is no, let us say, patent solution. As you know, with many ACP countries we have a contract—the Cotonou Agreement. The Cotonou Agreement gives these countries a clear preference. However, with ideas like those floated by the Cairns Group and others, they would totally lose their preferences. Exports to the EU would move away from the ACP countries and would go to these other very competitive developing countries like Brazil—especially if you speak of sugar, for example. This is something which we have to take into account when we discuss market access. Clearly it will be necessary to open up the markets more, but we must do it in a way so that it is not at the cost of the poorest and where only the richer developing countries—at least in the agricultural sector—would gain. Something similar applies with the tariff rate quotas. If I read studies from, for example, Oxfam and others, they just use the tariffs as they are notified in Geneva, but they never look at the details and that we give clear preferences to the developing countries, especially to the ACP countries, and that this has a major effect. The tariff rate quotas were introduced in the Uruguay Round, together with tariffication. It was necessary to do this because some tariffs were very high and the idea, therefore, was to make sure that there is a minimum market access. However, to say now that these tariff rate quotas should be increased—without looking at what is really going on in the markets, without also making sure that others who do not have tariff rate quotas should open their markets in a similar way—is also an imbalanced treatment of the different WTO members. I will stop there, and I hope that you have a feeling for where I see the problems which face us. Perhaps we can continue with our discussion and find out how to solve these problems.

  Chairman: That is extremely helpful. Perhaps we could ask a brief machinery-of-government question and then go on to CAP reform.

Mr Walter

  188. This is really about how you operate here with regard to the Doha Round. The Doha Round is a development round, but it is about trade and a major part of the trade picture for the developing countries is agriculture. Within the Commission here you have three different Commissioners dealing with those headings of development of trade and of agriculture, and you have three directorates-general. Can you give us an idea of how you work together on these matters?
  (Commissioner Fischler) This is very clear and very simple. I am responsible for agriculture, including the international part and including the WTO negotiations—full stop. I am clearly in close contact with my friend Pascal Lamy and also with the Commissioner responsible for the development policy but, in terms of the responsibility, this is different from the other sectors. Pascal Lamy is responsible for all sectors except agriculture in the international negotiations. Agriculture negotiations are done by DG-Agriculture under my responsibility.

Mr Colman

  189. Commissioner, you are quoted as saying that the new CAP would have to be agreed before EU Member States could provide you with a new negotiating mandate for the WTO agreement on agriculture. Could you then take us through the timetable of the next six months leading up to Cancun? I understand that the WTO deadline for agreeing modalities in agriculture is the end of March, but your proposals which you introduced on 22 January have not yet gone to the Council for approval. I think that there was a debate this Monday. How do you see the movement going forward which would enable there to be tabled, well ahead of Cancun, the negotiating position of the EU on agriculture?
  (Commissioner Fischler) I think there is a bit of a misunderstanding. We have already tabled our negotiating position on agriculture. We tabled this in January, and we are ready to negotiate on the basis of our proposal. I must also add that our proposal is really more in the centre than most of the other proposals. There is a group of countries, like the Americans and the Cairns Group, which says that our proposal does not go far enough, but the Japanese and others are saying that our proposal is going too far. The reality is that the proposal is there and we have a mandate to negotiate.

  190. That has gone through the Council, has it, Commissioner?
  (Commissioner Fischler) Our mandate, coming from the Council, decided in the Foreign Affairs Council, in the General Affairs Council—which is the same—in January, allows us to negotiate it basically on the basis of Agenda 2000. This is our mandate. It is also true that our positions—or the different positions of Members in the WTO—are far apart. The question is how can we converge these positions. I always wonder a little why the Europeans always have a tendency to blame themselves for something, but maybe this is a European tradition. Others do not do that. The point is that it is obvious—and this was repeated two days ago by Mr Harbinson—that a lot more technical work has to be done before the WTO, not the Europeans, is in a position to conclude modalities. He identified nine different areas where more technical work is necessary. It is true that it is no longer very likely that there will be an agreement at the end of March about modalities. However, our American friends tell us that they are not accepting the Harbinson paper as a basis for negotiations—so there is no difference. I therefore do not accept that one can blame the Europeans here. We have always said that we are prepared to negotiate; we can negotiate, but there is not much interest on the other side. There is then the other question of our internal reform. This is a different story. Our internal reform is there and there are negotiations going on in the Council. We hope that we will have an agreement about this additional reform in June. It is true that, if we are successful with this reform, we would, so to speak, have more negotiating capital; but this does not mean that this is a precondition for us to negotiate. This is perhaps an interpretation by the Australians, but it is not our interpretation.

  191. So you may have a new negotiating position after the Council meeting in June?
  (Commissioner Fischler) We can then amend our mandate—this is true. To put it bluntly, we have a strategic disadvantage here as the European Union. Why is this so? Because others—like, for example, the US—can make tactical proposals. The American proposal is a pure tactical proposal and nothing else, because they would have a huge problem if they were forced to implement their own proposal in the US: they would have to reform their policy. It is not possible for them to implement their own proposal under the present conditions. They can do this, however, because their trade representative has a free hand. We cannot do it, because we will never get the mandate from our Member States—and we can only operate on the basis of a mandate from our Member States—which is outside our present policy. Therefore, we are much more transparent. We cannot start tactical manoeuvres, saying, for example, "We are very keen to reform internal support", knowing that then the Americans will make sure that this will not happen. This is what they are doing. They know that we have to fight for certain things because our policy, as everybody knows, is a certain policy. They can therefore be relaxed and wait until we fight the result. This is how the game goes.

  192. Can I ask you questions about the impact of the CAP on developing countries? You talked about fairer burden-sharing amongst developing countries' farmers. Do you see the changes that you are proposing as being fairer on developing country farmers, either in terms of the protection of small farmers against the effects of dumping or to provide commercial farmers with export opportunities?
  (Commissioner Fischler) Yes, our reform proposal will have some effects in this direction. We said from the very beginning, when we started the reform process, that we were speaking about a process. What is on the table now, therefore, is not the last step. There is one very sensitive area, which is sugar, and this has a lot to do with the developing countries; but sugar reform will follow, and that has already been announced. When we have settled this first package, the next step will be sugar reform. Altogether, however, it is clear that if we move, with our own support measures, away from partly trade-distorting blue box measures and put these measures into the green box—which means by definition that they are no longer trade distorting—then, first, the competition situation will change. Secondly, if we move away from using export subsidies, for example in the dairy sector—if, following our reform, we no longer need to use export subsidies in the dairy sector—this will change the situation. If we decouple, for example, the whole beef sector—we should remember that we have already more or less abolished the intervention system in the beef sector, so that the market will regulate supply and demand—then developing countries in the beef sector are also in a much better competitive situation. As I said, however, no one should think that our export subsidisation will play a big role in the future because, in the future, the amount of money used for export subsidies will be about 5% of their export value—and this will not change the world.

Mr Battle

  193. Do you think that decoupling itself will make the CAP WTO-compliant? Will it get you there?
  (Commissioner Fischler) We are clear—decoupling means a shift to the green box.

John Barrett

  194. I am probably the first Scotsman you have met for a while who has not mentioned fish!
  (Commissioner Fischler) I mentioned fish at the beginning, but in another context—but not cod!

  195. Earlier, you mentioned market access not being at the cost of the poorest developing countries or the richer developing countries' gain. Is market access the most important issue for poor farmers in developing countries, or is it being given too much priority in negotiations?
  (Commissioner Fischler) I think this is rather difficult to say in a very general statement. It also depends on the objectives you have. If we would like to give trade—I would not say instead of aid, but at least in addition to aid—then we must give agricultural trade, because there it is much easier to have export opportunities for many developing countries. Usually there are some problems in establishing a regular export structure; for example, the question of standards for hygiene. Therefore, if we want to be serious about giving real opportunities to developing countries, it is not enough that we introduce quotas and so on; we must also give them certain technical assistance, so that they are able to make use of the new opportunities, in the form of how they can establish the necessary veterinary standards, phytosanitary standards and suchlike. Nowadays, because more and more products need a kind of certification, the introduction of such certification systems is also something on which we can give help to the developing countries, so that they can take advantage of this possibility.

  196. On the question of export subsidies, the graph which you presented to us showed a clear reduction in the percentage of subsidised exports; but are there particular sectors that pose particular problems within that, would you say?
  (Commissioner Fischler) Meanwhile, if you look at the big sectors, you could say that we no longer use export subsidies for wheat; I think that we will also be able to phase out export subsidies for the other cereals; we do not use export subsidies for olive oil or some other Mediterranean products. The remaining sectors where we substantially use export subsidies are beef, the dairy sector—but this will more or less go when we are successful with our reform ambition—and sugar. Sugar is a real problem, but it is also a very complicated problem in many respects. There is the problem of the ACP sugar regime; there is the problem that there is a different financing system because it is a kind of self-financing system and so, in the end, the consumer pays the price of the subsidies. It is a very close system between the industry and the beet producers. We therefore have to look at both. In this reform which we are planning we have to look at the transferability of the price—in other words, how big is the share which arrives at the farm gate from the consumer price. That involves the question of competition in the industry—or, rather, the lack of competition in the industry! In addition to that, we have to think about ways of how we can continue—clearly at a lower level and not at the same level as in the past—a certain sugar production in the European Union. The point here is that it will always be difficult to produce beet sugar at the price level of the most competitive cane sugar producers. You could also argue that Europe is no longer interested in sugar production and we could import all of the sugar. This is another alternative, but it is perhaps an alternative where the chance of getting agreement with the Member States is rather limited.

Hugh Bayley

  197. You direct us to parts of the export subsidy regime where progress is being made, but our committee was in Ghana recently and we saw a very large tomato canning factory and a large irrigated farm, both built with European aid. The factory had closed and the farm was producing about 10% of its capacity. The pumps had broken down. There was no market for the tomatoes, it appeared. European tomatoes were being sold in the market, which were much cheaper than they could produce locally. You say that export subsidies will be down to 5%, but that is an average. If my head is in the oven and my feet are in the snow, I am, on average, very comfortable! But what can we do to set a ceiling, product by product, on export subsidies? Because, if we do not do that, we will continue.
  (Commissioner Fischler) But how will this make sure that this canning industry in Ghana can survive? How would you like to solve the problem of Ghana here?

  198. Ghana suffers because European tomatoes—canned tomatoes and tomato paste—are exported at below the price that they can produce them. There is a policy contradiction here. I cannot recall whether it was EU development assistance or bilateral assistance from EU countries, but there is a lack of policy co-ordination here. I cannot ask you to respond to an individual case—I appreciate that—but the question is, should we not be setting a limit on the proportion of the value of a single product that we export that comes in the form of subsidy, rather than averaging it over the whole of our agricultural exports, including beef, olive oil, and things which bear no export subsidy at all?
  (Commissioner Fischler) Let us be clear—we have such a limit. The system as it works is that we say that the maximum export subsidy we can give is the difference between the world market price and our internal price. Sometimes the real problem is getting real figures about the world market price. However, we have no interest whatever in giving higher export subsidies so that it is possible to dump the market in such a way that we lower the world market price. Such things happened in the past. I do not deny that. I know that, for example, when we sold the butter storage at the beginning of the 1990s, we really dumped the world market with these products. From the Commission side, however, we have no interest whatsoever in such things happening. If there are such cases, for whatever reason, and if you have this case from Ghana, then please give me that case and we will check it. There was a similar problem in the south of Africa, in Botswana or Swaziland. It was true that there was some damage done there by European exporters. I can show you that, immediately afterwards, we changed our export policy here and we drastically reduced the maximum level of export support to these countries. So if there are trade distortions, then we are always prepared to look at these things. As I said, however, overall I think that the question of export subsidies will not be the decisive question for the future, because in future export subsidies will play less and less of a role. When we now reduce, or more or less abolish, export subsidies for the dairy sector and if we are then able to carry out reform in the sugar sector, there will no longer be very much left.

  199. At its fundamental, if we are reducing—or, better still from my point of view, eliminating—export subsidies, we must be amending the CAP so that the subsidised element only applies to that volume of produce that is consumed within the EU. Surely the difficulty with the tomato case is that we are providing subsidy for production according to our rules, but for more production than we consume? That, of course, is the case with sugar—but, as you say, that is a separate issue.
  (Commissioner Fischler) Yes, but there is no internal support for tomato production.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 23 April 2003