Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 231-239)

TUESDAY 8 APRIL 2003

MR JOHN HILARY AND MR PETER HARDSTAFF

Chairman

  231. John and Peter, thank you very much for coming to help us with our inquiry on trade and development and Doha. The House starts, as you know, on a Tuesday at 11.30, so we have just under an hour, so colleagues have promised to be reasonably brisk with questions, and I am sure you will be reasonably brisk with your answers. You both might like to answer this, because really it applies to both of you; in your view, what would make the Doha agenda a genuine "development round", what are the litmus tests, what are the bullet-points, what are the indicators by which you believe that Doha will be judged a genuine development round, and how do you rate the prospects of this occurring? Peter, let us start with you, from the World Development Movement.

  (Mr Hardstaff) Thank you, and thanks to the Committee for the opportunity to provide oral evidence. I think, if we run through a number of the key issues then what WDM would be looking for from a genuine development round would be some significant reform of the way that the WTO operates currently and also reform of its current rules. So clearly within that would be some significant reform on agriculture, currently we have a very unfair trading regime, as the IDC has recognised a number of times. We would be looking for reform on TRIPS (intellectual property rights) both in terms of the "access to medicines" issue, but also, more broadly, from the development perspective, we would be looking at reform of patenting rules relating to life forms. We would be looking for significant reform on GATS. Obviously, we will be covering this in more detail later in this session, but, to summarise, we believe that GATS has some serious flaws which need to be addressed. Also there are issues like trade-related investment measures (TRIMS), a review of which is under way but no progress has been made, and the so-called "implementation" issues which include TRIMS but also covers a wider range of issues. And we would like to see reform of the way that the WTO actually operates. For example, last year, a group of developing countries put in a proposal for reforming the way that the WTO operates its negotiating procedures[48], to try to make them more transparent, to try to ensure that developing country proposals get heard and that the procedures at ministerial conferences operate in a way that draw in a larger number of countries to the decision-making process, but unfortunately this was ignored. So I think that forms quite a substantial agenda to change the way that the WTO already operates, to make it fairer, more transparent, involve a greater number of countries, and also to reform it in terms of the rules.

  232. John, have you got anything to add?
  (Mr Hilary) Yes, thank you, just briefly, and can I extend my thanks also to the Committee for allowing us to present evidence here today. When we came back from the Doha Ministerial, in November 2001, a group of 10 of the UK's NGOs, including both the World Development Movement and Save the Children, produced a statement on what we believed would constitute a genuine development agenda for the Doha round, and obviously I will be very pleased to make this available to the Committee. This was written over a year ago, and it is very interesting now to look back and to see how incredibly few of those suggestions, of those provisions, which would make this round a genuine development round, have actually been put into practice. We have seen already the incredible block on any movement in terms of special and differential treatment, in terms of TRIPS and public health, in terms of any progress on agriculture, or indeed in terms of the assessment of the impact of GATS. All of these were key indicators which we believed would show whether or not we had a development round; they simply have not been met. And I think that is why a lot of developing countries, in the run-up to Cancún, are throwing up their hands and saying, "Where is this development agenda that you've been talking about?".

  Chairman: John, let us have that, and obviously we can have it as a sort of exhibit to your evidence, so to speak, when it comes to the printed report as well[49]; a very useful document.

Hugh Bayley

  233. I wonder whether you will accept the Government's argument that having a multilateral agreement on various new issues would be better than having a patchwork of bilateral agreements on these things like contracting and public procurement and investment, and so on? More generally, what are your impressions of what developing countries are saying about the desirability of putting the new issues on the agenda at Cancún?
  (Mr Hardstaff) I think that it is important to distinguish between the issues, when we are talking about a patchwork of bilateral deals. I am not aware that bilateral deals tend to encompass, for example, competition policy. I think the main issue, when it comes to bilaterals, is investment, and, you are right, there is a large number of bilateral investment treaties around the world, apparently some 2,000. I think the critical thing to recognise with this is that the investment agreement, as seems to be proposed by the European Union and countries like Japan, will not replace these bilateral deals, it will not supersede them in any way, so, the regulatory spaghetti that is apparent currently from bilateral deals will not be replaced by a multilateral agreement within WTO. It will merely add to it. So we do not agree with the argument that it would affect the number or content of these bilateral agreements. Also it is important to recognise that the European Union has proposed what is called a GATS-style approach for a new agreement on investment. GATS is negotiated on a bilateral basis, the so-called "request-offer" process; so if you use the same process within a WTO agreement on investment then what you have is a series of formalised bilateral negotiations within the WTO. Therefore the proposed WTO investment agreement will create a process where bilateral pressure can be put on developing countries—making it no better than a bilateral investment agreement.
  (Mr Hilary) If I might just reply as well. In terms of the competition policy suggestions, where the European Union also is pressing for a multilateral framework agreement on competition policy, it is often put forward in very unambiguous terms that this is a very pleasant, a very positive thing for developing countries because it is going to be tackling the problems of hard-core cartels, particularly in some of the industries where they have actually had particular experience, and negative experience, of those. And I think everybody would agree that hard-core cartels are one of the things which the world does need to tackle. However, there is no need at all to embark on a whole round of new negotiations into the issue of competition policy at the WTO for that; it is perfectly possible, as indeed the UK Government itself has acknowledged, to pursue hard-core cartels and the international co-operation needed to deal with them within a discussion framework, as currently it is, at the WTO. The negotiation process is about introducing national treatment provisions into the domestic competition laws of WTO member countries, and for that reason developing countries themselves are extremely wary of it. Your question was: what is the developing country view on this? We have had very strong statements from developing country representatives, from African and Asian countries, in particular, but also from some Latin-American countries, that, just as before Doha, they simply do not wish to see the WTO agenda expanded to include these new issues. And I think there is a growing body of civil society opinion across the world which really supports developing countries in their resistance to what is, in effect, quite an aggressive EU agenda.

  234. We have heard some really quite compelling evidence about the capacity of developing countries to operate these agreements, even if they were to sign up to them, and so we have heard a lot about that. Leaving that aside, what are the reasons given by developing countries for not engaging in the debate about this issue; after all, they want investment, they want to drive corruption out of their systems; apart from the capacity issues, what are the other reasons why they would want to resist making agreements in the WTO about these matters?
  (Mr Hilary) The key one is the policy space which they are allowed, as sovereign governments, in order to maximise the positive effects of foreign investment, because it is that policy space which is under threat, particularly, for example, where a country will be requiring of a foreign investor that it joins with a domestic partner in a joint venture, or indeed putting levels on the equity participation of foreign investors. Also, performance requirements, where a foreign investor will have to provide a certain number of jobs at a high management level, or indeed will be committed to technology transfer. All of these provisions allow developing countries to make the most of foreign investment, and it is precisely those provisions which are under attack from the proposed multilateral investment agreement. So that policy space argument is absolutely key.
  (Mr Hardstaff) If I can just follow up on that, I think that the recent paper by the Indian Ambassador, at a seminar a couple of weeks ago in Geneva, set out a range of arguments why India currently is opposing insertion of an agreement on investment in the WTO[50] As John said, the critical issue is policy space and the flexibility which developing countries have to use the different measures to maximise foreign investment. It is not that they, or we, oppose FDI. This is not about whether or not to attract foreign investment, it is how then you can regulate it to maximise benefits. If I can just quote from the Indian Ambassador: "We are of the view that we do not want an MAI in the WTO," and by MAI he is referring to proposals for investment rules in the WTO. So I think it is important to recognise that there is a range of opinion against inserting investment into WTO because of its core principals of national treatment, which over time will affect the ability of countries to maximise the benefits of FDI.

Alistair Burt

  235. You are very cross about GATS, you are very, very cross about GATS, and you are in contact with people who support you and you ask them to write to us about GATS. We have tested this out, when we have been going round taking evidence from other people, and I will come back with one or two things they have said in a second, but could you explain just why you are so concerned about it, do you not believe there is any opportunity for developing countries to benefit from the liberalisation of trade in services, and what evidence do you have that developing countries really are opposed to this?
  (Mr Hilary) The first thing, which I think is a critical distinction to make, is to distinguish between the liberalisation of trade in services and GATS; they are two very, very different things. We do believe that in certain sectors there are certain benefits which developing countries can gain from liberalising and opening up to competition from foreign providers, but that is a completely different issue from making a binding commitment under GATS. Under GATS, your commitment introduces a whole range of disciplines, which again, very similar to the investment argument, close down the policy space which governments have to maximise the positive use of FDI. Also in GATS, as we know, there is the lock-in clause, which makes any commitment irreversible, effectively, and that means that you are setting up a particular policy choice into the long-term future without the prospect of being able to bring it back if it turns out to have been a mistake. The document which we have circulated to you just today—which is hot off the press, so you will excuse me that it was not circulated earlier—is on GATS and water[51], and it looks particularly in that sector at the damaging results of liberalisation, in country after country, across the developing world. Now, given that some of those countries have had such negative experience, in our view, it would be madness for them to commit these sectors under GATS.

  236. Do you mean liberalisation, or privatisation?
  (Mr Hilary) In this case, in water, liberalisation is akin to privatisation because it is a natural monopoly. If you have one particular provider within any geographical locality, opening up the sector to competition ipso facto opens it up in some way to privatisation, not wholesale privatisation maybe, not even the transfer of assets, but, in terms of privatisation of service, that certainly is what it opens up in terms of a particular sector like water.
  (Mr Hardstaff) Again, just to follow on from that, I think to reiterate the point that you do not need GATS to liberalise, and you do not need GATS to attract foreign investment. The United Nations Conference on Trade and Development have done research[52] suggesting there is no link between signing up to GATS and attracting more foreign direct investment. So in order to retain the kind of policy flexibility to maximise the benefits from services investment then signing up to GATS does not make sense. Our problem is, with GATS, not so much with investment, our campaign is not a kind of anti-FDI campaign, it is pro-flexibility, pro-regulation, and so our problems with GATS are about the ability of countries to regulate, to change, in the light of experience, and in the light of changed political or social circumstances. Recently WDM has produced a report[53] looking at the European Union's requests, which were leaked, and one of the examples we draw on in that report is of Thailand, which submitted a paper to the WTO last year looking at retail liberalisation. Thailand some years ago liberalised in retail, attracted a lot of foreign direct investment from European companies; over time, Thailand has realised that there have been some adverse impacts on domestic retailers and now is looking to re-regulate. Critically, it is able to do that because it has not made a GATS commitment, although the European Union now has requested it to do so. But the whole idea of locking in liberalisation under GATS is one of the critical issues, and the ability of countries to change over time, in the light of adverse impacts or changed political circumstances, is crucial.

  237. The response we tended to have, from World Bank, from IMF, from the EU, was a sense that GATS they felt was not well understood by NGOs, they felt that if there had been poor privatisations it should not knock out privatisations per se. I think we have been a bit more flexible with what you have said now. Putting to the EU, putting to Pascal Lamy, the straightforward point about why the commitment, he said, "Well, it's a trade-off, in return for this opening up," and there was a necessary trade-off in terms of a commitment. Do you think you have taken a stance which has been very anti, and actually that there might be more flexibility in what you said, because, with so many of the people we spoke to, the whole concept of the liberalisation of trade being beneficial to developing countries was almost always set in a context that said you had to take account of lots of other circumstances, they were not absolutely prescriptive about, in every case, it always works because, and do you feel that that flexibility matches some recognition of flexibility on your own account?
  (Mr Hilary) No. I think that the people who have said that we are not very well acquainted with GATS actually are trying to pull the wool over your eyes. Certainly I have been working on it for five years now, and we tend to have much stronger arguments than the Government and the European Commission officials which we talk to. In particular, in relation to flexibility, we know that the architecture of GATS, the way in which the positive list approach works, is intended to give developing countries more flexibility in which sectors they will commit under their national schedules. But the process of GATS negotiations at the WTO negates that flexibility, because it brings completely unequal partners into bilateral negotiations, in secret; and we have heard from many of the developing country representatives at the WTO that this puts them at a terrifically unfair disadvantage, they cannot withstand the overwhelming pressure which comes at them from those countries which are trying to push them to liberalise. And in the case of the European Union we know that they have the most aggressive interests in opening up developing country markets, which they say, and the UK Government fully admits, are for the benefit of business interests in the UK and in Europe. And what we are saying is, it is not just about pushing forward the business interests of Europeans, actually it is looking at the impact on the poor and the most vulnerable in developing countries, which, of course, from Save the Children's point of view, also includes the children in those poorer communities.

Tony Worthington

  238. I have been trying to read your "water" paper[54], at the same time as listening to you, so I may have got it wrong. You say you are arguing for flexibility and for policy choice, and in "water" you say "We're going to take away that policy choice, we're going to ban any WTO country from choosing to go the GATS way"; that is right, is it not?

  (Mr Hilary) Not at all, no, we do not say we are going to ban anything. I think it would be presumptuous of a single NGO to suggest that we could "ban"; we are recommending that WTO members do not commit their water sectors under GATS, precisely because that would then eradicate their choice, if they wanted to bring back their water sectors into public control, as so many have.

  239. Well I am trying to find it, but it does say that water should be withdrawn; it should not be?
  (Mr Hilary) We agree that water should not be a sector in which countries make commitments, in their national schedules, under GATS—


48   Preparatory process in Geneva and negotiating procedure at the Ministerial conferences. Communication from Cuba, Dominican Republic, Egypt, Honduras, India, Indonesia, Jamaica, Kenya, Malaysia, Mauritius, Pakistan, Sri Lanka, Tanzania, Uganda and Zimbabwe. 24 April 2002. WTO document: WT/GC/W/471. Available at www.wto.org. Back

49   Not printed. Copy placed in the Library. Also available at: www.scfuk.org.uk/development/resources/gen-dev-agenda.pdf Back

50   "Trade and Investment: Some Issues". Paper by the Permanent Mission of India in Geneva. Copy placed in the Library. Back

51   "GATS and Water: The Threat of Services Negotiations at the WTO", Paper by John Hilary, Save the Children UK. See Ev for Executive Summary. Back

52   UNCTAD paper on "Assessment of Trade in Services of Developing Countries: Summary of Findings". Available at: www.un.org/esa/socdev/docs/unctad3e.pdf Back

53   WDM paper on "Whose development agenda? An analysis of the European Unions GATS requests of developing countries", April 2003. Available at: www.wdm.org.uk/cambriefs/Whose%20development%20agenda%20v-4.pdf Back

54   See Ev x for the Executive Summary. Also see: www.scfuk.org.uk/development/global-pub/GATS%20and%20water.pdf. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 9 June 2003