Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 380-399)

Thursday 8 May 2003

MR CHARLES GORE AND MR RICHARD KOZUL-WRIGHT

  Q380  Mr Khabra: As you know, agriculture and food aid are the most important issues in the developing countries in particular. Could you tell us what impact subsidies, dumping, export credits and food aid have on food security and livelihoods in the developing countries?

  Mr Gore: They have a negative impact. There are concrete examples of this. In our last report, we looked at the tomato processing industry in west Africa, and perhaps I can just refer to that. We found there is a close connection between the collapse of tomato processing in some west African countries and the combination—and it is a combination, this is quite important—of trade liberalisation which allows the imports in and the subsidised exports coming from these countries. The other good example is cotton. I have some numbers here, for example, from the International Cotton Advisory Committee. It puts the cost of producing a pound of cotton in Burkina Faso at 21 US cents compared with 73 US cents in the USA, but the United States' subsidies guarantee a minimum price for US farmers, currently about 52 cents per pound. This means that the Burkina Faso producers find it very difficult to compete on world markets. The World Bank has estimated that during 2000-01 downward pressure on world cotton prices has caused a loss of export receipts of over 3% of GDP in Mali and Benin, and 1 to 2% of GDP in Burkina Faso and Chad. So the impact of subsidies and dumping is working through food imports; it is also working through loss of export markets in things like cotton. There are however other commodities where it is not working. Coffee, for example, is an important export for the least developed countries; there are other kinds of problems for that commodity. But overall there are definitely negative effects. We have found in our report that the countries which have undertaken most, and most rapid, trade liberalisation had in fact the greatest increases in poverty in the 1990s. At the same time, the countries which have undertaken least trade liberalisation have also had increasing poverty in the 1990s. So there is a complex pattern. What is going on here? Why is it that the countries which have undertaken the fastest and most radical trade liberalisation have rising poverty? I think that it is related to this issue which you are raising, but the linkages are quite complex. I do not think they have all been worked out. That is an association which I am just saying we have observed.

  Q381  Mr Khabra: If that be the case, what is being done to remedy the situation?

  Mr Gore: I went to an IFAD meeting, the 25th Governing Council meeting, and the remedy—put on the table by a Belgian Government representative for debate in the form of a question— was, should countries be allowed to protect their agricultural sectors if no progress is made in terms of agricultural subsidies and this dumping of below-cost products on the markets. There was a range of views put forward. My view was that that, of itself, was not going to do the trick. You needed measures to increase the agricultural productivity in these countries, and so it comes into the way in which aid is used. For example, aid to agriculture in the least developed countries has halved since the 1980s. There is definite evidence of harm. If progress is not made in this agricultural subsidies/dumping issue, then people are saying, "In this case, what do we do?" —because you are going to get very high rates of rural-urban migration, and an exacerbation of the poverty problem. So people are putting forward the idea, "We need to protect".

  Q382  Mr Khabra: Could you tell us what impact tariff peaks, tariff escalation and preferences have on food security and livelihoods?

  Mr Gore: The thing which I would emphasise from the least developed countries' position is the issue of tariff escalation. Two-thirds of these least developed countries are commodity-based economies, and it is very difficult to develop through commodities. What everyone suggests, however, is that you should be upgrading your commodity production, increasing your value added; but what you find in the least developed countries is that, in terms of processing, there has been a collapse of processing of commodities before export. This is related to the problem of tariff escalation. It is not only tariff escalation which is the problem, but tariff escalation is definitely a difficulty. In terms of the way it works, I am not sure if it is working on the food security issue. It is the other points which you raised earlier that affect that. The way it works is through, "How does a commodity-dependent country develop?". It has to upgrade its commodity production in some sense; it has to add value. These tariff peaks have acted as a constraint on the processing of commodities for exporting, and this is blocking the broader development process.

  Q383  Mr Khabra: You are aware of duty and quota-free access, for agricultural products particularly, for the least developed countries. What are the prospects of that happening?

  Mr Gore: What are the prospects of it? I am not sure, but I think that the past experience with preferences shows problems of the utilisation of preferences. Again, if I could quote a figure, before the Everything-but-Arms initiative, 99% of the products of non-ACP least developed countries were covered by a generalised system of preferences—so they were offered preferences—but only 34% of the imports which were offered preferences actually came in with those preferences. They came in at higher duty rates. The question is, why is this? They are offered the preferences; they are eligible for preferences, but the preferences are not utilised. There are various reasons for it. It is a question of how big is the preference. Is it worthwhile to go through all the paperwork? But a key issue is the rules of origin. You are theoretically given the preferences, but you cannot realise it because you have to satisfy certain rules of origin in order to get that. With your issue of duty-free access the question is, will it be hedged around with various rules of origin, and will this enable it to be actually realised? In terms of prospects, I am not sure how that will play out. It is a question of the utilisation of these things. I think that the northern countries have been quite generous in terms of what they are offering, on paper, for least developed countries in terms of market access, but the problem is, are these utilised? Can these be utilised? Is anybody looking at ways of increasing the kind of utilisation?

  Q384  Mr Khabra: Is it due to lack of information? What are the reasons?

  Mr Gore: That is a possible reason, but what people are particularly putting their finger on are rules of origin. What is surprising—and this is recent, ongoing research in UNCTAD—is that you would think that these rules of origin are just applied for manufactured goods, where there is a kind of assembly process chain; but in fact this is also affecting agricultural processed goods where, in the processing, there are certain imported inputs which are required. What people are putting their finger on, therefore, are the rules of origin. Another issue is the security of preferences; another is information; another is the margin of preference and whether that is sufficient to go through all the paperwork.

  Q385  John Barrett: Perhaps I could continue on the matter of tariffs. You mentioned tariff escalation and then you touched on market access. What sort of formula for tariff reduction do you favour? You touched on tariff escalation but, bearing in mind the problems that exist for maintaining comparative advantages if there is asymmetrical tariff reduction, is it linked to one of the problems you also mentioned earlier in relation to coffee—the problems when there are different tariffs on the ground coffees as against the coffee beans? The price of coffee in the shops has not plummeted, but the world market price of coffee has taken a plunge. How do you see tariff reduction progressing while maintaining advantages for certain countries, and how can you move forward there?

  Mr Gore: I do not think that I can answer that question.

  Mr Kozul-Wright: There is a bit of confusion, really. We do not work on the specifics of the WTO-driven trading system. Our focus is on the links between trade and development more generally conceived. It is fashionable, of course, to focus on something like Doha, because it is in the press, because of the activities of NGOs, and it homes in very quickly onto this very specific set of issues that come from this very specific institution. But the trade in question is a much bigger question than this. There is a recent study from the CEPR in London, by Andrew Rose, that tried to estimate the impact of multilateral trading rules on the shape and dynamics of trade, and found that there was very little impact from the trading rules, once you factor all the other forces that drive trade and growth in the world economy. Ironically, he found that preferences were one of the factors that had a significant impact on developing country prospects in the trading system. We are interested in trade perceived more generally, in the context of development agendas. In that context, we cannot link it to Doha because in many respects the agenda for trade is not driven from the WTO and it has, over the last two decades, been much more intensely driven by Washington. In that sense—it is globalisation in some generic sense, whatever that means—it is the impact of trade liberalisation and this drive for trade liberalisation which has been the overwhelming characteristic, if you like, of the policy agenda on trade for the last two decades, and what are the consequences of a rapid and what we believe to be a fairly asymmetric and biased pattern of trade liberalisation on developing countries in general. As Charles has said—and his focus is on the poorer countries—we have paid a lot more attention to looking at middle-income, industrialising, developing countries. Although I understand the concerns with agriculture, if you look at the share of developing country exports, the allocation between different types of products over the last two decades, it has moved from essentially 20% of exports being in manufactures in 1980, the rest being in primary exports and agricultural products, to something like over 60% of the composition of exports in developing countries now being in manufactured goods. Within that is a tremendous asymmetry, between who is doing well in terms of manufacturing and manufacturing exports, and who is not. So, when you break down the figures, the big success stories are essentially confined to a small group of economies in east Asia—the Hong Kongs, Taiwans and South Koreas, joined recently by China, quite spectacularly. They have been driving the successful entry of developing countries into a different pattern of growth, based on industrialisation and manufactured exports. There are wrinkles round this story. For example, a big feature that has emerged over the course of the last decade is the way in which international production networks, driven by large multinational corporations, have reshaped the pattern of integration of many developing countries into the trading system. Indeed, in some of the most dynamic parts of the trading system—areas like automobiles, electronic goods—these are essentially driven by these networks. A number of countries have entered the trading system through this vehicle: countries like Mexico and Malaysia, a large number of countries in Central America. There are benefits to that, clearly; but when you look at the way in which they are integrated, there are a couple of big problems. One is that they tend to get stuck in producing essentially the assembly part of what are sophisticated goods, and they find it very difficult to move up the ladder into more value-added components of that process. Another is the real danger that we have flagged in a number of our reports, of enclave economies being built around this particular pattern of integration into the trading system. So you get funny results. You get countries that are exporting a lot more, but their value added is stagnant or, indeed, in some cases is actually declining. We made a point in last year's report that a lot of developing countries—middle-income developing countries—are trading more and earning less, from the way in which this more open, international, business-driven, global economy is working currently. We have attributed a lot of that to the way in which liberalisation has been rushed in many developing countries, exposing domestic firms to an environment that essentially they cannot handle. The classic cases in this respect are in Latin America, where you had a pattern of integration through this import substitution industrialisation—which had tremendous weaknesses in it and, at least in terms of growth performance, was better than the current period, but certainly had problems—coming to an end in the debt crisis. Countries open up, and they get squeezed, sadly, from both ends. They do not have the technological sophistication that allows them to move in to compete with northern industrial producers in high-technology, high value-added products, so their industries get squeezed on international markets from that end; and, from the lower end, they cannot compete with low-cost producers in Asia, in China or India, in areas like clothing or footwear. They are being squeezed from both ends. As Charles said, the natural response to that is to resort back to your natural comparative advantage in exporting resource-intensive goods, which then puts you in competition with poorer countries, which increases the extent of competition on these primary commodity-driven parts of the trading system, and is probably not the basis for sustainable growth. The issues for us are not so much driven by the details that interest you, in terms of the specifics of tariffs and trade-related areas of negotiation, but this wider system of a fixation with liberalisation—trade and financial liberalisation—which, as far as we are concerned, has not delivered what it promised, which was faster and more stable growth across the developing world. It has not. It has delivered slower and more unstable growth in most of the developing world, with the interesting exception of a handful of countries in east Asia. That worries us tremendously, because ultimately the big losers from that kind of system are the countries at the bottom of the ladder, who get stuck with problems of poverty and underdevelopment which they simply cannot get out of.

Andrew Rose, 2002, "Do we really know that the WTO increases trade?". CEPR Discussion Paper 3538. See www.cepr.org

  Q386  Mr Battle: It is very helpful to see that big picture. UNCTAD has been around for nearly 40 years now, and it has been that question of how to shift up that ladder, to add value, to move away from commodities to processing. We seem to have made no real progress, do we? You are suggesting that rushed liberalisation has slowed it down and made it worse. Do you see the Cancún event offering anything for commodity-dependent LDCs? Do you see any hope there that there could be any change, or that the system will shift?

  Mr Gore: I am not sure whether the Cancún event will do that, but I think that there is increasing attention to the issue of an international commodity policy. In our last least developed countries report we identified a very close association between the rate of extreme poverty—this is the $1-a-day poverty—and commodity dependence, which is obvious in itself, but in fact this was not an issue in the poverty debate. There is a very close relationship. We were getting figures like 68% of the population living on less than $1 a day in commodity-dependent least developed countries whereas, for those which had diversified into manufactures, the rates of $1-a-day poverty were declining and much lower—around 25%. This is very extreme poverty. It is a very extreme standard and I do not want to suggest that there is not poverty in other countries and the more advanced developing countries; but, at this extreme level, there is this close relationship between commodity-dependence and poverty. The striking thing about the international approach to poverty reduction was that the international commodity policy issue was absent—total silence. We therefore said, "This is a major gap". The problem then is to think about what constitutes a new international commodity policy because, in some sense, we cannot go back to the old approach of these international commodity agreements, which did not really work; and there is not much political will to go back there. The question is, how does one rethink an international commodity policy? I think that the commodity issue is not simply a WTO—what an international commodity policy might look like. For example, you might think of linking debt service payment schedules to commodity prices. I would see that as an aspect of an international commodity policy. You might think of ways in which aid can be used to upgrade commodity production. The British Government, for example, might think about how aid can be more successfully used to build up productive capacity. I would see that as part of an international commodity policy. However, there are WTO aspects to this international commodity policy. Let me give you another figure on coffee. I mentioned the cotton figures, but this is a number which relates to this commodity issue. The International Coffee Organization reported that, in the early 1990s, export earnings by coffee-producing countries were about $10 to $12 billion; the value of retail sales, largely in developed countries, was about $30 billion. In 2000-01, the producing countries received $5.8 billion and the value of the retail sales was US$ 60 billion. What one has to think of is what does one do about this? In countries in which 75% of their export earnings are from coffee and you have 60% of the people living on less than $1 a day, how are we going to square the circle? How is Cancún going to fit into this? I do not have an answer and I am not so sure that it will happen in Cancún, but I think that the international commodity policy issue is going up the agenda. People want a market-based solution to this, but they find it very difficult to think of it. However, I think that you should carry around in your head these numbers that I have just quoted on coffee.

  Q387  Mr Battle: Just for reference, are they in your recent report on the least developed countries? Is that where those numbers are to be found?

  Mr Gore: They were not. They are in an International Coffee Organization report. We had an executive session to discuss The Least Developed Countries Report, which was held in the Trade and Development Board, where the numbers were referred to.

  Q388  John Barrett: Would you be good enough to repeat those, so that we can make sure we have them down?

  Mr Gore: The International Coffee Organization reported that in the early 1990s export earnings by coffee-producing countries were about $10 to $12 billion, and the value of retail sales of coffee, largely in developed countries, was about US$ 30 billion. However, in coffee year 2000-01, producing countries received only US$ 5.8 billion of the value of retail sales of more than US$ 60 billion. That is the situation.

  Q389  Mr Battle: A widening gap.

  Mr Gore: Yes, and that is to do partly with market structures; it is partly to do with quality of output. Amongst the least developed countries, you have countries, like Ethiopia, and Uganda, which are very highly dependant on coffee exports and you have very high rates of poverty. Cancún is part of the solution, but it is —

  Q390  Mr Battle: As part of the picture, Richard mentioned a paper by Andrew Rose. Is it worth our also looking at that to get a good overview?

  Mr Kozul-Wright: He is rather sceptical about the effectiveness of the trading rules. What is important is that it forces you to think about something bigger than the WTO when thinking about trade issues. As Charles pointed out in the case of commodities, it is not possible to restrict one's attention just to what is happening there. You have to link it in this case to issues of debt. Most commodity producers are also highly indebted countries, and solutions cannot be found by just focussing on one part of the problem. You do need a much more holistic approach. I think that Rose antagonised a lot of my colleagues across the road, and there are disputes about his numbers, but his bigger point is a very important one. It is time to get away from thinking about trade and development issues as defined simply in terms of multilateral rules, and think about how trade feeds into a development strategy that can get back to delivering developing countries 5, 6, 7% growth per year on a sustained basis—which is what they do not have now. More trade for its own sake is not interesting; it is fundamentally not interesting. What is interesting is how trade can feed into this dynamic, virtuous growth path of higher investment, higher productivity, stronger domestic enterprise sectors that are capable of competing against enterprises from other parts of the world. Without those questions, the nitty-gritty of the trading system is a big yawn for me, I am sorry to say.

  Q391  Tony Worthington: Can I switch to the liberalisation of trade in services, how important you think that is to the developing countries, how it got on the agenda and what the drive is there? It was very interesting yesterday that one of the ambassadors we met said that the most important thing to him was Mode 4—the ability of people to travel to other countries and then send back remittances—and that that gives a great boost to economies.

  Mr Gore: Like the tariff question, I find it difficult to say much on that. My response would be exactly the one which the ambassador gave: that the issue of this migration of persons is an important one. It is a mechanism for poverty reduction. It is very important for a number of poor countries and least developed countries, but I do not think that I can add that much.

  Mr Kozul-Wright: The sad thing on migration is that no one has done any serious work on it. I am not aware of any serious work, and that includes from developing countries. This response from developing countries that, "As long as we have labour migration, things will improve", is not obvious to me—at least from an economic point of view. Moving goods is just another way of moving factors around the world. Goods are a way of embodying capital and labour, crudely speaking, and shifting them around the world. If it is not working with goods, it is not obvious to me that it will work with labour. It may do. I have my doubts, particularly as to the way it is likely to unfold. Ten years ago, FDI was going to solve developing countries' problems. That was the way of solving your problems. It would bring in capital; it would bring in entrepreneurship; it would be more export-oriented. The record does not show that to be the case. I suspect that it will be similar with migration. There will be a big push for it; it will not happen, I do not think—so it essentially becomes a bargaining chip, which I understand is useful for developing countries. I would like to see some serious work done on that particular subject in terms of the economics of it, but I have not seen any, unfortunately.

  Q392  Tony Worthington: In terms of the wider issue of trade in services, in the evidence that we have been considering so far there is a conflict between our Department of Trade and Industry, which is saying, "This is a completely voluntary thing. If the developing country feels that it is in its interests to offer to go into the GATS arrangement, then it can do", as against NGOs who are saying that they are being forced into it—forced into it partly by the EU, it is asserted—that, even if they are not being forced into it by the GATS arrangement, then the World Bank is making it a condition of their poverty reduction strategies. Have you any view on what is happening there?

  Mr Gore: I do on the poverty reduction strategies and on the way that that process works. From what I have seen, the government officials in the very poor indebted countries are afraid to take the risk that a heterodox approach would be penalised.

  Q393  Tony Worthington: What do you mean by that?

  Mr Gore: I mean an approach which does not conform to the Washington institutions' view of what should be done to reduce poverty. In fact, they are given a lot of freedom, if you like, to formulate their own poverty reduction strategies. This freedom can potentially release a lot of creativity, in terms of fitting the poverty reduction to particular national contexts. What you see coming out, however, are poverty reduction strategies which look the same and look very similar to the old structural adjustment programmes. My own view on why this is taking place is that the poverty reduction strategies have to be deemed satisfactory by Boards of the Bank and the Fund, and the government officials do not want to take risks in producing a strategy which may be rejected. So they have a lot of freedom to do what they want but if they make the wrong move, they will potentially lose aid, or it will be delayed for six or nine months, or they will potentially lose debt relief. This will increase poverty rates in their countries. If you get it wrong, your poverty rates will increase. So they do not all want to take the risk. This is quite an important point in terms of how the whole process works. They are in a situation where—and I am talking of the poorest countries now—they are aid-dependent and debt relief-dependent. The positions which they can adopt reflect their judgment in terms of ensuring the continuity of aid and debt relief. They are being told that they can do anything but, if you put yourself in their shoes, there is a risk. The risks of making the wrong decision are too high, I think.

  Q394  Tony Worthington: Do you think that they realise the implications of liberalising services? Do you think that enough has been done to increase capacity? When you hear about GATS, it is very difficult to get your head round it, even from our perspective, as to what the implication is of liberalising trade in services, when those services do not even seem to exist in some countries.

  Mr Gore: I think that there is always a case for increasing knowledge of the whole process. I would say that, for the whole process, just increasing information about what things mean, and increasing capacity to understand what it means, is an important thing to do. This is perhaps something which needs to be supported, but it needs to be done in a way which is pragmatic rather than ideological. The problem is that it has to be done in a pragmatic way. Richard has said various things about our views on liberalisation, but I think that what it comes down to, in the end, is that you need to take a pragmatic view of how these things work in practice and not go in on faith, if you like, so that you assume that trade liberalisation will promote growth in an economy where the average GDP per capita is 72 US cents per day. This is the current situation in least developed countries. The resources available in these least developed countries for physical capital accumulation, expenditure on health and education, law and order, is 15 cents per person per day. Are you expecting a similar response to trade liberalisation in this context as you would in Switzerland? Our overall approach, I think, is one of pragmatism rather than to have a kind of blind faith. That pragmatism has to be evidence-based on an understanding of how the whole system and the relationship between trade and development is working.

  Q395  Mr Walter: We have made various assumptions about trade and growth. What is your reading of the historical relationship between trade and trade policy to liberalisation and poverty reduction? Linked with that, what assessment have you or others made of the development impact of the Uruguay Round and what assessment are you likely to make of the post-Doha situation?

  Mr Gore: That is a very big question.

  Q396  Mr Walter: I apologise for throwing it in at the end. It challenges our assumptions really.

  Mr Gore: There is a professor at Sussex called Alan Winters who is preparing papers for the World Bank in particular, and he is essentially pro-trade liberalisation. He produced something for the WTO a few years ago, on trade liberalisation and poverty. There was a quote in there, and I will see if I can find it. Much of what he was writing about was concerned with the short-term effects of trade liberalisation—an issue where people have tried to look at the channels through which reducing a tariff barrier affects poverty. It works through such things as what does trade liberalisation do to government revenue? What does it do to consumer prices? What does it do to competition with producers, et cetera? They worked that out. However, it is a different issue between the short-term effects and the long-term effects. What he says on the long-term effects is, "Overall the fairest assessment of the evidence is that, despite the clear plausibility of such a link, open trade alone has not yet been unambiguously and universally linked to subsequent economic growth". This is a person who is basically pro-trade liberalisation and he is saying," . . . open trade alone has not yet been unambiguously and universally linked to subsequent economic growth". Our reading would also be that it has not been established. Although people are saying that there have been 250 studies which show this link, if you look at it very closely—and Dani Rodrick is the person who has looked at this in particular—you do not find a very clear link. As I said earlier, we have found in our last report that poverty was increasing most in those least developed countries which had undertaken trade liberalisation most rapidly.

  Mr Kozul-Wright: The links between trade liberalisation and financial liberalisation, for example, in the recent period are very close. Countries that have been forced to liberalise on the trade front have often, in the face of imbalances, asymmetries and the inability to compete internationally, been forced to liberalise on the financial front in an effort to maintain a respectable growth rate, close the balance of payments constraint. That sets off another set of asymmetries because, in the world of finance, developing countries are even worse off than they are in the world of trade. The asymmetries are even greater, but the two are not separate—they are very closely linked. There is a lot of history here. It is an area I have worked on. Trade liberalisation was a British invention, when the Brits had essentially established themselves as top dog industrially. Until 1840, Britain was itself a relatively closed economy. Fortunately for the rest of the world, it was not a dogma that was followed elsewhere in Europe. Most of Europe, in the period when it was developing, was closed or relatively closed. There were exceptions. For example, Switzerland was a fairly open economy; Belgium was a fairly open economy. The big economies, however—and the biggest economy of all, the United States—used tariff protection as a way of nurturing their own industrial capacities. You do not go to a market unless you have a product to sell. You cannot get a product to sell unless you have the capacity to produce it. The ways in which you do that are partly through nurturing your own domestic capacities, and trade protection is one way of doing it. It certainly worked for the countries that are now telling the poorer countries not to use it. We know that for sure. Whether it is the most efficient way, of course, is an important question. What other ways might be used more effectively than simple protectionist measures? But there are no short cuts in development. The sad thing about the current debate is that there was a belief that somehow there was a short cut to development: that you would find the silver bullet which would move you—whether it was FDI, whether it is labour migration, whether it is opening up in services. High rates of investment, strong productivity growth, building up technological capacities—these are ultimately what gets you from a $1,000 per capita income to a $20,000 per capita income, and you will not do it overnight. It is slow, long and difficult. All one can say is that a certain degree of humility on the part of advanced countries, a certain respect for their own history, and a certain recognition that flexibility in the multilateral system is the defining quality of a development component of multilateralism, as it works for developing countries, are essential. If you remove all of those elements, I do not think that developing countries have very much chance of progressing up the ladder in the way that we progressed up the ladder 100 years ago. I think that is the sad thing, in the end.

  Q397  Chairman: This is a fascinating discussion which we could pursue for some time, but we have other meetings. Thank you very much for sharing your time with us. I think that you are very kindly going to share with us the summary and the full report?

UNCTAD, 2002, Least Developed Countries Report. See www.unctad.org

  Mr Gore: Yes, I have summaries of the least developed countries report. I also have a statement which I made at the WTO Integrated Framework, which specifies briefly this relationship between trade liberalisation and poverty in the least developed countries.

Charles Gore, 2002, "Mainstreaming trade in national development strategies: Some new evidence on the relationship between trade and poverty in the LDCs".

  Chairman: Thank you very much.

  Witness: MRS LAKSHMI PURI, Director, Division on International Trade in Goods and Services, and Commodities, UNCTAD, examined.

  Chairman: As you probably know, we are a committee of the House of Commons, looking at international development. We are interested in the Doha Round in terms of its development implications. Clearly, here in the Trade Division, you are looking at capacity-building and the ability of LDCs to participate effectively in WTO negotiations. We would like to ask some questions, therefore, about the mechanics of the WTO.

  Q398  Tony Worthington: When you look at the mechanics of the WTO, it is the most democratic of the multilateral institutions, in theory. The poorer countries of the world outnumber the rich countries of the world. It sounds like this is a chance to get a fair deal. How do you see the negotiating process working in practice and how would you strengthen it?

  Mrs Puri: I am very happy to have this opportunity of talking to you and sharing with you what—I would like to qualify—are my personal views. There is no institutional stamp on what I am saying. I think that we should be very clear on that. We have had some experiences in the past where what was said by one of the officials was attributed to the institution. I am the Director of the International Trade in Goods and Services, and Commodities Division, but it would enable me to speak more freely if I were to detach myself from my official capacity and so I begin with that caveat. Indeed, you have put your finger on a very important issue; that is, of process being as important as the substance. You are quite right that, in theory, decisions are to be either voted upon or taken by consensus. There are two problems, however. One is of process overload. The developing countries, first of all, do not have the capacity. Some of them are not represented here. Some of them have very small missions which are covering the entire UN system here, all of the specialised agencies, and also covering the WTO. So sometimes you may have the ambassador and one other person trying to cover everything in the WTO, against—and I do not have the numbers—the 30 or 50 people that the European Commission, or the US, or any other country have. That is one issue—of capacity in terms of sheer presence. There is capacity in terms of trying to understand what the issues are; in terms of the multiplicity of proposals and issues; and also in terms of the profound implications that these issues have for their economies, but which they do not have a hold on. They have neither the capacity to do that, nor perhaps the time. We keep talking about meeting time deadlines, but that is another problem for the developing countries. Yet another issue is how decisions are taken. In fact, the Chairman of the General Council will tell you the stories of the Doha Round, and how decisions were still taken in small groups. As somebody said, the WTO is still evolving out of the "clubby" atmosphere and culture to which it was accustomed, and there is not yet in the WTO that chaos of democracy that the UN system is known for. There is no voting as such. Delegates have told us of how key decisions are sometimes taken on the basis of a group of people getting together, coming to a particular decision, and then bringing it in front of the rest. Then there is an element of political pressure and hard bargaining, unrelated to the WTO sometimes. It means that, in the end, the developing countries are having to accept packages that are not of their making, or perhaps not in their interests. That is the feeling that developing countries have, of a certain hopelessness and inadequacy to deal with the challenge of WTO. Even in terms of implementation—implementing what has already been agreed—because it is an extensive package. If you will permit me a little later, I will address this whole issue of what is the development dimension of the Doha Round. However, there is this problem that, first, they have to deal with the challenge of implementing what has already been agreed in the Uruguay Round, and then the Doha Round came about. Most of the developing countries had not yet assimilated and had problems, and that is why you had the 90-odd proposals on implementation issues—which they felt needed to be looked at because they needed, first of all, to correct some of the imbalances in the Uruguay Round agreements. They were unable to implement some of these and therefore they needed some specific help, and there were other proposals for reform. This is the context in which the present process has to be looked at. Now, in the present process, apart from the traditional issues of market access—you have non-agricultural market access, the agricultural negotiations, and services—in addition, there is the challenge of how to deal with the Singapore issues. There are also two working groups which are looking at trade and transfer of technology, and trade finance and debt. It is a huge process, therefore.

  Q399  Tony Worthington: I do not know if you were in the room when we were discussing this with our previous guests, but when a developing country is going into the room, in theory as a free agent, are they bringing with them elements of fear—if they do not agree?

  Mrs Puri: I would not be able to say. I think that it is more appropriate to address some of this to the negotiators themselves. Nobody is sitting there with a gun to their heads—it is not fear in that sense. The issue is very clearly a sense of hopelessness. I have come across LDC delegations and I have come across Africans who feel that, whatever they put forward, they are somehow set aside and they may not be able to sustain their proposals—that they are not listened to, and sophisticated arguments are put forward. Partly, of course, it may be an issue of capacity, but I have explained what the capacity problem is. There is also a feeling that, in the actual workings of the WTO, there is not the common good approach, or the development approach in the real sense, and that, ultimately, it is a question of bargains. The mercantilist approach on the one hand and, on the other hand, the economic power play. This is the problem.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 18 June 2003