Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 138-159)

WEDNESDAY 19 MARCH 2003

COMMISSIONER PASCAL LAMY

Chairman

  138. Commissioner, thank you very much for giving us your time. As you know, we are a Select Committee of the House of Commons that particularly monitors and scrutinises international development. We are doing an inquiry on trade and development, so we are very interested in the Doha Round and the present trade negotiations. Our Government's Department for International Development have set themselves a target by which they are going to judge the success of the WTO negotiations. They say that this target will be judged to have been met if there is agreement at the "development round" of WTO negotiations by WTO members, taken as a whole, to an average 20% reduction in bound tariffs on industrial goods and a substantial reduction in support for agriculture. The test they have set is a substantial reduction in industrial tariffs and a substantial reduction in support for agriculture. I was wondering whether you thought that those were the appropriate benchmarks of judging whether or not this will be a development round and, if so, are those the sorts of targets that are achievable in your view?

  (Commissioner Lamy) Basically, yes, and we are limiting this to the multilateral negotiation, which is one of the aspects where development policy and trade policy are related. There are many other aspects of trade policy where development and trade are related—bilateral relationships, the preferences we give, the ACP relationship, but I suppose we will talk of this later. On the WTO round, we have named it the development round; it is our policy to make it a development round. I think that the first of these benchmarks, which is a substantial reduction in industrial tariffs, is a good one and is obviously the most important one. Industrial goods are 75% of the exports of the European countries and it is 80% of all trade. The rest is 10% on agriculture and 10% on energy. It is not only very important North-South-wise but also South-South-wise. One of the big gains of trade liberalisation for developing countries lies in developing countries opening their trade to developing countries. So, yes, 20% is a sort of clever number. Of course, you cannot apply that to the European Union. The average tariff in the European Union is in the order of magnitude of 8% to 9%. We may have higher tariffs in textiles or footwear here and there—although they are much lower than the US tariffs—but there is an average tariff of 28% or 30%. However, the idea that this results in a serious tariff reduction, especially for developing countries—notably in textiles and footwear, which is one of the proposals we have made, namely to make a special effort on this one—yes, it is true. Agriculture is also one, obviously, not only in terms of a level of support and whether it is domestic support or export support, or whether it is market access—it is also a big chunk of that, but it is not the only one. This round is about classical market opening but it is also about rules-building, in things like antidumping, competition, investment, public procurement, trade facilitation, which is also very important for developing countries. The gains they can make in streamlining their systems, in trade managing, are enormous. The obstacle to trade which you have in things like red tape in many developing countries, or indeed in some of our countries, sometimes amounts to between 5% and 10% of the cost of what you trade. It is fine having a big fight about 5% tariff reduction—if you are still loaded with 8% to 10% of the cost of your goods because of port formalities and things like that. So I think that the rules part of it is also very important.

Mr Colman

  139. Going on to agricultural policy, I was in Doha and congratulate you on the hand you played in terms of getting commitment to agricultural reform by the EU clearly put on the table. Do you believe that the World Trade Organization negotiations on agriculture can succeed without European Union agreement on CAP reform? Will they fail if there is no CAP reform within the European Union?
  (Commissioner Lamy) No, but they will be at a higher level at the end of the day if we succeed in pushing through the package which we have tabled to the Council of Ministers at the European Parliament. In agriculture, like in other areas, the WTO negotiation—and especially in agriculture—is more about disciplines than tariffs, although it is also about tariffs. What is the purpose of this negotiation? It is to move the ceilings of support which we had agreed in the previous round, which is 1995, lower. That is what we mean when we say reduce domestic support and reduce export support. This is against the benchmark which was set in 1995. Since then, the CAP reform has resulted in a large part of the ceiling not being used. This is why we were able to table, with the CAP as it is today before any reform, a proposal that we would commit ourselves to reduce domestic support by 55%, to reduce export subsidies by roughly 50%, and to increase market access by roughly a third. This we can do today, as a result of the CAP reform that has taken place since 1995. If everybody around the table at WTO—including the Americans, by the way, who in the meantime have been increasing their support and re-linking it to production—agreed to that tomorrow, it would already be a big step forward, because the level of the 1995 agreed disciplines will be lower and we would start the next negotiation at a much lower level. The present CAP reform—the package which is on the table—if adopted, will result in an extra credit of negotiation in terms of domestic support, in terms of export support and, to a lesser extent, in terms of market access. So if you add the sort of credit we have gained since 1995 and this one, we can buy a better result in the whole negotiation. But if the negotiation were to stop today, we would take the commitments which the present CAP allows. It would already be a big step forward.

  140. The decoupling, which I think you are describing—the shift from price support to direct payment to farmers—do you see that as making CAP WTO-compliant and do you see it as making it more development country-friendly?
  (Commissioner Lamy) Of course it is, because it is less trade-distorting. If you start from a position where we have 7 million farmers in the European Union, 6.5 million of them are non-competitive by academic international standards; 70% of these farming operations employ less than one full person a year. So it is all small farming, except for a chunk—

  141. Hobby farmers we would call them in Britain. It is not serious in terms of being their main source of livelihood.
  (Commissioner Lamy) It is not serious, but we want them to remain there, for a variety of reasons. This is the basic European choice. We want them to remain there. We know that they are not competitive and, because they are not competitive, they provide a sort of service. We want this to be paid for, which is why we will keep support to farming; but we do not want this to have the sort of trade-distorting consequences which the original CAP model had—as a big thing to become self-sufficient and then have an export capacity, but with an insulated system. The whole shift from price support to revenue support makes things less trade-distorting. We have in the WTO a sort of waiver for support, called the green box, which is where you put support that is not trade-distorting. If we have special rules on animal welfare and if the European Union citizens' view is that hens are happier with one square metre per hen, it certainly makes the average cost of eggs less competitive than if you had 100 hens per square metre. This has to be offset one way or another. The same for environment, for food security and for food safety. So there is a cost there which we have to compensate for. The whole decoupling makes it less linked to production, so we do not overproduce—which, by the way, has a good environmental impact—and we do not dump it into world markets, then contributing to the decrease which a number of developing countries suffer from—of course, under the condition that others do the same, notably the Americans who support their farming activities as much as we do.

  142. They say half.
  (Commissioner Lamy) No. Look at the numbers. 0.5% of GNP. Of course they say half because, for instance, they do not include food stamps in the support system; but they do not have oil stamps or farmer stamps or footwear stamps. It is all about dumping their surpluses into social aid. If it was not social aid, however, it would just be piling in stocks. They spend 0.5% of their GNP, as we do, on supporting farming, and they of course export a lot more than we do. We are by far the biggest importers in the world—by the way, including from developing countries.

Hugh Bayley

  143. In President Chirac's recent proposals there is a proposal substantially to reduce trade-distorting export subsidies. How much do you achieve that? To put it more strongly, how can you achieve that without reducing excess production in Europe? How might we achieve that goal?
  (Commissioner Lamy) This proposal is within the Union's proposal which we tabled in Geneva, which is that we are ready to eliminate export subsidisation in areas of particular significance for the developing countries. Mr Chirac's view of developing countries is focused on Africa. We talk about developing countries because we have a larger concept than that. The proposal implies price reductions or price decoupling or support decoupling, so that you do not have to put your thing onto the market at reduced prices.

  144. Or quota changes?
  (Commissioner Lamy) No, I would not like it to be this way because then it would mean that you have to stop the import side so that the addition of imports through domestic consumption does not result in added exports. I do not think it should be this way.

  145. Can I move on to Everything But Arms? It is early days, but which countries do you see as benefiting most, which benefiting least, and why? What are the prospects for broadening Everything But Arms to include all developing countries, or at least more developing countries? Again, President Chirac has a proposal to include all of Africa. What about India, for instance?
  (Commissioner Lamy) First, it is two years old and it is quite soon to look at numbers. Basically, however, it has resulted in a DCs' export increase of 10% since then, which is to be compared to average developing countries' export rise of something between 5 and 7% a year—which means, by the way, that you cannot really compare the without-Everything-But-Arms' potential rise because, by definition, these countries are least developed countries. Their supply system, their export system, their harbours and so on, are in a much worse shape—if that is possible. It has worked, notably with sugar where they have started exporting sugar. Of course, it is not big numbers. The sort of increase is in the order of magnitude of

10 million, which is not much for us, but

10 million is a big number for them because, remember, they are the poorest. On Everything But Arms my view is that, at the end of the day, this is the sort of concession which we could consider, for instance with the whole of Africa or the economic partnership agreements which we are negotiating with Africa, because this is what we can table in terms of concessions. Obviously, 100% duty-free, quota-free, for a country like India would not be possible in the present CAP system. In things like sugar or rice, for instance, India has quotas. By the way, sugar will have to be reformed. It is not in the first package of the MTR but it is a very developing country-sensitive thing. So it obviously would not be possible for a country like India in the present situation. I was in India a few days ago. India's agricultural strategy does not very much reach out to external markets. It is feeding its population and increasing the efficiency and productivity of its own agriculture. The sort of "respiration" with the rest of the world which a continent like India has in agriculture will, in my view, always be marginal. It is not Australia or Argentina.

  146. When you say Africa, Commissioner, do you include the Maghreb? North Africa, or are you talking about the sub-Sahara?
  (Commissioner Lamy) We already have a free trade agreement with the Maghreb and we periodically review the agricultural part of this—as, by the way, we review the industrial part, and we will be starting to negotiate services quite soon with them.

  147. The American Africa Growth and Opportunity Act sets targets, I believe, for increasing the volume of exports from African countries. Has that been more successful in generating growth in exports than Everything But Arms?
  (Commissioner Lamy) It is a valuable initiative. They started from very small numbers. Most of the African countries do not trade with the US, or very little. On top of that, it is mixed with terribly strict rules of origin, notably in the textile sector. But I have to acknowledge that the PR value of this is well run on the US side. I sometimes wish that we could sell our own system of preferences or the special relationship we have with ACP as well as they do.

Alistair Burt

  148. It was widely thought that the acceptance of the principle of Special and Differential Treatment by the WTO was a marked success for developing countries. I have two particular questions. First, does the EU see Special and Differential Treatment as meaning countries having a longer period of time to harmonise and liberalise trade policies, or does the EU see Special and Differential Treatment as allowing those countries to have a much greater flexibility in terms of their policy choices for the future? Secondly, what is the EU's view about how countries move on from their position, to make sure that the development box does not become so much of a straitjacket that we classify countries as remaining at almost subsistence level? How does the EU see a ladder of progress to enable countries to be graded and differentiated within those terms?
  (Commissioner Lamy) It is a very complex issue. The concept of Special and Differential Treatment is extremely attractive because it is vague and flexible, and it is a good old GATT principle. A much more difficult question is, for instance, can there be special and differential treatment within Special and Differential Treatment. I think that you again have to distinguish here between multilateral rules and bilateral rules. We already do a lot of special and differential treatment through bilateral rules, notably trade preferences which are unilateral—the extreme of these being Everything But Arms. Within the multilateral rules our concept is not that we should create, with Special and Differential Treatment, a sort of two-class WTO. It is more a first option that developing countries have more flexibility in terms of transitions and they have more de minimis possibilities of using this or that. The vision behind this is that at the end of the day—and it may be very far away on the horizon—the sort of least common denominator which we have in WTO, which we are trying to raise decade after decade, is good for everybody. In terms of climbing the ladder, it has happened that a few countries have moved out from the developing countries' group to the developed countries' group. That was the case with Korea. We do not have any African example of this, unfortunately; we have a few Asian examples of it. However, they will resist a lot—they have always resisted a lot and will go on resisting a lot—differentiation among developing countries, notably under UNCTAD influence and because of the view that, together as a developing country group, they have better pressure and leverage on the whole system than if we start dividing them in terms of groups.

  149. Are you sympathetic to the view which is sometimes advanced by NGOs and development agencies that there is still a question mark over to what extent liberalising trade can actually make a serious difference to the eradication of poverty?
  (Commissioner Lamy) I believe that it is a necessary condition but not a sufficient one. If you look at the distribution of countries and at a number of criteria, over the last 50 years you do not find countries which have seriously developed closed systems. There are a number of countries which have tried to develop closed systems and which have failed—sort of inner-focussed development theories which obviously did not work. If you rank them or distribute them according to governance capacity, you have a much better explanation of where it works and does not work than just by looking at trade. Trade opening is something which is good; it is not only good in goods, but it is good in agriculture and in services. Remember that, on average, 50% of developing countries' economies are with services today. It is one area where they can gain a big comparative advantage. A country like Kenya, for instance, is now terribly good at exporting a number of services. That is my basic thrust. It is important to do it, but of course it has to be matched with rules, with domestic governance—which is of utmost importance—and, as much as we can, with a reorientation of our classical development assistance programme into trade-related development assistance. Maybe we could give to our friends this brochure which we have published on a number of cases. Not theory, not declarations, not visions, but how, in addressing and simply focussing on a few things—trade-related technical assistance—it has resulted in making trade work, whereas it did not work before. It is not about spending billions on roads, railroads, airports or harbours; it is about spending 1, 2 or 5 million on things which have to do with sanitary or phytosanitary requirements, for instance. At the end of last year I asked for a rapid poll amongst ACP countries. We sent this to all delegations and asked them to contact five or 10 authorities in trade in each and every country. The question was, "Where are the obstacles to trade for your country with the European Union?". Eighty per cent of the answers were "non-tariff barriers"; 20% were about tariff barriers, amongst which two-thirds were about sugar and bananas—which is an area where, if trade was totally liberalised, African countries would be totally wiped out. The big issue, therefore, is non-tariff barriers—which are there for reasons which have nothing to do with development. If we have a requirement that there is a zero tolerance for chloramphenicol in seafood, we will not change that because we would like to have a better development policy.

Mr Colman

  150. But they could be protectionist.
  (Commissioner Lamy) They are protections. They are protections for health. I do not know whether it would work in the House of Commons, but I can tell you that it would not work in the European Parliament if the Development Commissioner were to go there and say, "I need legislation that says that the level of chloramphenicol in shrimps should be . . ." or "There has to be a special tolerance for exports of developing countries". It will not work. The only solution is helping them match the increasing requirement in terms of standards in this domain. I can tell you, at least for the European Union, these are not inspired by protection. By the way, we have totally changed our system and there is a Chinese wall between those people who deal with trade and those who deal with health and consumers. Ask David Byrne if he will accept any instructions from my side that he should do this or that—or the other way round. It does not work.

Mr Battle

  151. Could I ask you about capacities of developing countries? To trade and take part in negotiations you have to have something to trade. You also have to have negotiating skills to bring to the table, and I think that it is generally acknowledged that there is a deficit there. What is the EU doing to help developing countries develop an effective voice themselves, so that they are not dependent or led by the nose by NGOs, or indeed donor governments?
  (Commissioner Lamy) We are directing a number of our assistance programmes into training, transfer of knowledge and so on. Bilaterally—for instance, with Africa—we have, in the present systems, either national or regional or pan-African programmes precisely for training negotiators. We have financed the ACP Office in Geneva, which I inaugurated 18 months ago. So we are providing them, through the ACP secretariat here, with monies, training, either directly or through the WTO system—which we do not finance directly but which our Member States do finance directly—or through things like the Integrated Framework, which is a joint venture between the IMF, the World Bank, UNCTAD and the WTO, which we also fund and which we sponsor as a sort of "godfather" for some countries like Mauritania or Cambodia, for instance.

  152. Is that money increasing? There was a meeting on 17 December of the Trade, Debt and Finance Working Group to discuss an Africa Group proposal, but there were no African delegates there because they were at a TRIPS meeting and they did not have enough people to cover both. Is that being tackled now, do you think?
  (Commissioner Lamy) It remains a problem that they have fewer resources—which, by the way, is one of the characteristics of less developed countries—but there is a big improvement. I remember the Uruguay Round, and I can tell you that the level of participation, understanding and knowledge is incomparable to what it was 15 years ago. Of course, they obviously still have a problem.

  153. This is a question on "new issues". In your view, do you think that developing countries actually want the "new issues" to be on the agenda? What would the EU gain from them being on the agenda?
  (Commissioner Lamy) We got them on the agenda because of the view we have that overall it is good for the system and good for them. The fact that a number of developing countries do not have written, transparent, predictable, multilevel rules for foreign direct investment, for instance, is a big handicap. I used to be a banker in my previous life, and I can tell you that it is a big problem. Taking competition, for instance, there is no way that the benefits of trade liberalisation will be spilled over to consumers if you have a big cartel, which sometimes happens in developing countries—for reasons which we all know. For us, all of these issues are systemic issues. We Europeans do not need much of that because we usually have bilateral investment treaties, very good competition law and open public procurement. We believe, therefore, that overall it is one of the things we have to do on the rules side, precisely to translate the benefits of trade opening into development. Of course it is putting a constraint on their governance systems, but I think that we would all agree that part of the development problem is improving the governance system. If this can be done as a sort of trade-off, in the WTO not plugging extremely sophisticated systems but the sort of basic systems which improve the level of economic governance of these countries, then it is a good deal for everybody.

Mr Walter

  154. Commissioner, earlier on you touched a little on the General Agreement on Trade in Services—GATS. To some extent, GATS is misunderstood by a lot of people. It is a voluntary arrangement and it is not for industrialised countries' utilities taking over the utilities of developing countries. On the other hand, you need developing countries to participate and to come into it. The UK Government maintains that GATS is not about promoting privatisation. In the current negotiations it appears, however, that the EU has targeted sectors in other countries where the state is currently the sole supplier of these services. I wonder if you could tell us what are the implications, as you see them, for such state provision of making a GATS commitment?
  (Commissioner Lamy) No problem. A GATS commitment is about opening your market to foreigners. It is not about changing the rules of the game; it is not about privatisation. It is just whether or not you are ready to open your market. It was a nice understatement when you said GATS was not the best understood thing on this planet! It is not about liberalisation of services. It is about liberalisation of trade in services and it does not impact the regulatory environment, nor the way companies are run. Of course, if it is a monopoly, it will probably resist opening to foreigners because it means that you have to renounce your monopoly. However, it does not change the fact that it is a publicly owned company that runs a service operation.

  155. Could I draw you out a little further on that? If we want countries to participate in this process, what evidence is there that making a commitment under GATS will bring greater benefit to that country in liberalising these services than having that agreement outside GATS?
  (Commissioner Lamy) It is a trade-off. They need more market access in services in our countries, in things like tourism and in plenty of areas where they can get more market access. WTO is not, above all, a philanthropic organisation. It is a bargaining system. The philanthropy of the system stems from the fact that trade opening, with rules and the necessary conditions, is a win-win game. If we ask developing countries to liberalise trade in a number of services, it is because we believe that basically is good for their consumers. Take a very hotly debated topic, water distribution, which we have to distinguish clearly from access to the resource itself. In my view, there is no way we can meet the Johannesburg targets in terms of linking people to water if a number of developing countries do not open their market for water distribution. We just will not be able to make it. This idea—and I have debated it with many NGOs, notably European, in recent months—that the rest of the planet, notably developing countries, is covered by excellent-quality public services and that we are trying to damage these is an eerie concept. It does not work that way. When you go to these countries, you realise what the public services are—in transport, water distribution, health and the rest. It is therefore just a means of putting things together.

Alistair Burt

  156. As you said earlier, it is all about bargaining and about a trade-off. There is still the suspicion that, because the terms of trade are so very unequal between the developed world and the less developed world, any form of bargain that is struck will be so weighted in the interests of those who have the greater power—who are able to dangle the carrots towards the less developed nations in order to get what they want—that is what fuels the suspicion outside. We all understand perfectly well the arguments you make about public services and so on, and I cannot believe that those who run NGOs are stupid either. Why is it so difficult to shift opinion on this GATS issue, which leads those who speak for and represent less developed countries to feel that somehow something unfair is being transacted?
  (Commissioner Lamy) It is a very good point. I think that the basic reason behind this is because we have not tried. Nobody knows what GATS is. It pops up suddenly, and a number of NGOs, whose basic problem is to defend the weak against the strong—and I am fine with that, it is part of my own personal political philosophy—have this idea that it is a gain by being strong and, at the end of the day, "What we gain they will lose and what they gain we will lose". That idea is just wrong. That is not what trade is about. Of course we are more powerful, but the WTO table is a table where it is one country, one vote. Two-thirds of the members of WTO are developing country members. If the system is unbalanced, they can re-balance it—notably with the European Union, which has goodwill in this direction. It is true that we have a carrot, but what is the carrot? The carrot is that we have a huge market which is very rich and that their getting a chunk of this very rich, huge market is enormously important for them and for their development. That is the way it works.

Mr Khabra

  157. There is a growing concern in the developing countries about the lack of progress made in the TRIPS negotiations and agreement, and also public health issues. What are the prospects for a development-friendly agreement on TRIPS and public health, and what would you suggest is needed to achieve such an outcome? That is one question. May I ask you another question straightaway? Looking at different economic partnership agreements and regional agreements, what is the relationship between the EU's bilateral and regional trade negotiations—Cotonou—and multilateral trade negotiations, which is the WTO?
  (Commissioner Lamy) On the first one, we missed this agreement which we were looking for around the table at WTO on the remaining problem of the TRIPS-related access to medicine problem. Let us remember that access to medicine is a huge problem which has many components, part of which is price, and part of the price problem is patent-related. It is 10% to 15% of the problem. The quality of distribution systems, the availability of funding—all these are very important components in order to ensure that access to essential medicines is there in a number of developing countries. In Doha we solved part of the problem, which is how do you use compulsory licensing, which should potentially result in reduction of prices for countries which have manufacturing capacities. The problem remained of what do you do with countries which do not have manufacturing capacities. That is, how do you translate the compulsory licensing system into importing and exporting generally? We tried to broker an agreement in Geneva on this with the European Union as the broker, because we have a foot on both sides. We are pushing developing countries into it but we also have a pharmaceutical industry which is very reluctant regarding any concession on the TRIPS agreement. We got there, and the US finally blocked this compromise under the pressure of their pharmaceutical industry—and there we are. In the meantime, we have fixed the problem short term. Any developing countries which do not have a manufacturing capacity and which want to use the compulsory licensing system for HIV, malaria, TBT, can do it under a system of waiver which the US, EU, Japan and Switzerland put in place. So short term, legally speaking, the solution is there. What is not there is the medium and long-term solution, on the basis of a multilaterally agreed rule. We prefer to have a multilaterally agreed rule because it provides for the necessary framework, so that people can engage both in the pharmaceutical industry, in producing the necessary medicines and doing tiered pricing, and also a variety of other actors in the health system—distribution, financing—to step in there. What we need, therefore, is to bring the US on board. In order to bring the US on board, we need to fill the system with a bit of trust. The problem on the US side is that the pharmaceutical industry mistrusts a number of European countries, suspecting that they will use the system to unravel the patent protection or the research-based industry. It is terribly important, of course, for the research-based industry that the patent system remains. Otherwise, there is no investment, and so on. There is also quite a suspicion on the side of a number of developing countries regarding the pharmaceutical industry, given their behaviour in the years between 1995 and 2000—which we saw in South Africa, Brazil, and so on. That is the problem. I had a meeting here yesterday with the European pharmaceutical industry to try to address this. So that is where we are.

  158. Can I ask you a related question? The pharmaceutical industry in India particularly has a great potential to manufacture medicine, but they are finding it very difficult under the present rules and trade barriers.
  (Commissioner Lamy) No. That was true five years ago, but I was there a week ago and they have coped with that. They have understood that TRIPS—intellectual property protection—has its good side. They have a powerful generic system, but it is now working fine. They clearly have problems to address—their own problems—before going to exports. They have a huge problem domestically, notably on HIV/AIDS. So I do not think that it is a big problem now.

  159. Is it possible that different countries of the European Union operate a different policy on that issue?
  (Commissioner Lamy) No. The EU pharmaceutical industry is very much multinational. I do not think so. On economic partnership agreements, EPAs, yes, that is what we are trying to do as a result of Cotonou. We are trying, with the relevant regional groupings in Africa, to negotiate trade agreements which will result in regional liberalisation in Africa, which is absolutely crucial—with their putting together a number of common rules so that they reach the numbers, in terms of size of markets, which are needed in today's world, in the market capitalist system in which we live. A market of 20 million people is not worth anything for an investor today. It has to be much bigger. So that is what we are trying to do with them. It is a construction; it is very difficult, although they have started doing this in many regions of Africa. When you look at NEPAD, for instance, one of its important concepts is regional integration before going to African unity. How does it relate to WTO? It is two parallel negotiations, with a similar "tool box" in terms of trade liberalisation, agriculture, industry, services, or rules on intellectual property, air transport, or whatever—which is not within WTO but within the sort of thing they can do locally. Let us assume that we succeed in concluding a round at the end of 2004 in Geneva. The negotiation of economic partnership agreements should be finished by 2008. We will then have a system where they are within the least common denominator—which is the WTO system—and they will have a preferential trade relationship with us, sort of free trade-like, in the future. Obviously we accept that we have no protection and that they have a protection for a long time, because they probably need it in order to get their act together—where the level of rights and obligations in trade terms is higher between the Union and each of these partnerships than it is in the least common denominator which we have in WTO.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 23 April 2003