Select Committee on International Development Written Evidence


22. Memorandum submitted by the Caribbean Banana Exporters Association (CBEA)

THE WTO DISPUTE ON BANANAS

  1.  The CBEA has, since 1993, been involved in the dispute in the WTO over the EU's banana import regime and Caribbean banana growers, whose interests the CBEA represents, have been seriously affected by the successive changes to that regime which the dispute entailed. The WTO rulings have significant implications for developing countries and particularly for those which are small states with vulnerable economies.

  2.  The historical background to this dispute is set out in an Annex to this Memorandum. The central issue was the preferential terms of access granted to the ACP states. These fulfilled the Community's Treaty commitment under Lome and were essential to the survival of the ACP banana industries.

  3.  The new banana regime introduced in 1993 was challenged first in the GATT and then in the WTO, which succeeded it. In a series of cases the WTO ruled that all provisions entailing any degree of discrimination between contracting parties, whether by way of tariff preference or any other condition of access, infringed WTO rules. Any form of preference was therefore possible only if the WTO members grant a specific waiver, which is rare and difficult to obtain, requiring a two-thirds majority.

  4.  Following the WTO rulings, a settlement was finally agreed between the EU and the USA in 2001 after two more years of negotiations. This laid down terms for retaining a regulated market until the end of 2005, together with the existing preferential tariff for the ACP (subject to securing the necessary waivers). The terms included a larger market share for US companies and greater imports of dollar bananas. Above all, it required the removal of all protection for the ACP after 2005, except for a tariff preference yet to be negotiated.

EFFECT OF BANANA RULING

  5.  The WTO ruling adversely affected all ACP countries benefiting from the banana regime, because it brought a significant increase in the supply of dollar bananas, which has inevitably led to lower prices. More threatening was the commitment to remove all restraints on the volume of imports after 2005 (apart from the tariff still to be negotiated). This will inevitably lead to even higher volumes and still lower prices and threaten the survival of the ACP industries and particularly the Caribbean trade, which (for reasons explained later) is the least competitive.

PROBLEMS RAISED BY THE BANANA CASE

 (i)   Increasing Poverty

  6.  The banana case upheld and reinforced two key principles that drive the WTO. One is to promote liberalisation of trade; the other, of over-riding priority, is absolute equality of terms of access for all members to all markets and within those markets. Discrimination between members is the one cardinal sin.

  7.  The problem is that the playing field is far from level at the other end of the pitch: the circumstances in which production takes place, including the remuneration and treatment of workers and respect for the environment. The conditions of competition differ greatly depending on what rules govern these and other factors in producing countries. That is why some argue that the WTO should lay down common rules to ensure both fair competition and proper treatment of workers and environment. However, there are clearly major political and practical obstacles to such a course.

  8.  The consequence of untrammelled free trade in a commodity like bananas, which is in permanent surplus, is that the lowest cost supplier will ultimately drive out others that are less competitive. There is thus risk of a double down-side from the WTO rulings on bananas. All but the most competitive producing countries risk being driven out of the market, including those like the Windward Islands that are heavily dependent on banana exports; while banana workers in other supplying countries, who are already poorly paid, risk receiving still lower wages as banana companies compete to increase market share. Consumers may gain in the form of lower prices—at least in the short term. But they will have less choice—Caribbean bananas, for example differ from Latin American, in size and taste—and even the low price advantage may diminish once trading competitors have been driven from the market.

  9.  The pressure for lower prices is driven by supermarkets, which in the UK account for over 80% of the fruit and vegetable market, and the intense competition between them for market share. The fact that there are always surplus bananas available increases the pressure on suppliers to lower prices. This threat was increased by the decision of ASDA, now owned by the US Company Walmart, to switch to a single supplier for bananas. This fiercely contested prize went to a US Company, Del Monte, at a heavily discounted price. It set an ominous precedent which others may feel tempted or obliged to follow.

  10.  The EU regime had provided a relatively remunerative return for exporters from all origins, by limiting volumes on the market. Since the 2001 settlement, with increased imports, and the fiercer supermarket pricing that this facilitated, the situation has deteriorated. Prices are no longer remunerative even for many Latin American suppliers, let alone the ACP. The unit value of banana exports from the Windward Islands in terms of local currency is now nearly 40% lower than in 1991. For Jamaica the comparable figure is over 50%[31] The outlook is inevitably much worse for 2006 if the tariff quota is ended then, as currently proposed.

  11.  But even before then the problem could get worse. Next year, in 2004, the EU is enlarged by the addition of 10 states from Eastern Europe and the Mediterranean. Additional quota provision will need to be made to cater for these new member states. But Eastern Europe has traditionally been the market of last resort, offering the lowest prices of all. Adoption of the common external tariff and the quota regime will inevitably raise prices to consumers there and consequently reduce consumption. A quota increase based purely on past patterns of consumption would, therefore, result in increasing the oversupply in the Community as a whole and finally push prices below the level at which traditional suppliers can have any chance of surviving.

  12.  These are not problems that can be resolved in the Doha Round negotiations, but it is important to recognise that a problem does exist. Removal of barriers to trade should go hand in hand with consideration of the impact on producers in developing countries; and in particular the implications for the smallest and most vulnerable states.

 (ii)   Special & Differential Treatment

  13.  The Windward Island banana exporting states, Dominica, St Lucia and St Vincent and Grenada, are undeniably small, with populations averaging only around 100,000 people on each island. They manifestly have vulnerable economies because of their heavy dependence on that one threatened product and their lack of natural resources and limited scope for diversification.

  14.  Banana production on these islands is totally different to that in the more competitive Latin American states. In the Windward Islands in particular it is based on very small family farms, averaging just a few acres, often on difficult terrain. Largely for this reason production is ecologically friendly because it is more labour intensive and relies less on chemical inputs than more industrialised systems. It is also socially just because much of the labour is self-employed and labour laws ensure fair wages for workers that are hired. But Caribbean producers cannot begin to compete on price with Latin American production, based on vast plantations of thousands of hectares of flat land near to ports. Much of that production is controlled by the large multinational trading companies, which benefit from a highly integrated operation and major economies of scale.

  15.  Much has been done in the Caribbean, with help from the EU, to improve their position. Efficiency of production has been improved, and quality and consistency raised. The Windward Islands are also developing niche markets in Fair Trade and Organic bananas. But under the 2001 settlement, with even the current diluted regime due to end by 2006, the Windward Island industry is unlikely to survive, except to the very limited extent that these small niche markets may be preserved.

  16.  The free market philosophy that drives the WTO maintains that these islands would in any event be better off concentrating on other economic activities in which they have a comparative advantage. But there are no other areas of comparative advantage, existing or potential, except for tourism, which is already well developed—and which cannot be increased beyond a certain point without destroying the very features that make this destination so attractive. Tourism is, however, suffering in the Caribbean, as elsewhere, from the consequences of the terrorist threat after 9/11.

  17.  There are no other agricultural products that would not be subject to the same handicaps that affect the competitiveness of bananas. There is no other agricultural product that provides a year round crops like bananas. Nor could any alternative yield the same revenues as bananas have done in the past or maintain the same level of employment. Moreover, the tiny population of each island state (or even all collectively) means that there is no effective domestic market to back up any new industrial or commercial enterprise.

  18.  This trade, which brought such substantial economic benefits to these islands, represents only a very small proportion of the global market. In 2000, the last year of the previous regime, the Windward Islands accounted for 3.5% of the EU market and only 1% of global banana exports. It would seem reasonable to find some way to exempt such small amounts from WTO rules, when it would make such a huge difference to the economy of these small countries—the difference between well-being on the one hand or economic distress, unemployment, emigration and possibly drug trafficking on the other.

  19.  In such cases, where a small state is highly dependent on a single product in which it is nevertheless not competitive, importing countries might be permitted to discriminate in its favour, within prescribed de minimis limits. This discrimination might take the form of a special tariff preference, including possibly a negative tariff—a concept once mooted for bananas by the USA but rejected by the EU—or other preferential conditions of access. Similarly, where such small states are forced to diversify out of their primary export product, they should be permitted tariff and non-tariff barriers to enable new enterprises to get off the ground, just as many developed countries protected their own nascent industries before embracing the doctrine of free trade.

  20.  Unfortunately special and differential treatment has proved a difficult and contentious area in the WTO, with countries excluded by any formula fearing that their interests would be undermined[32] It should nevertheless continue to be pursued, perhaps concentrating initially on the most evident and extreme cases in terms of size of GDP and of population, remoteness from markets and degree of dependence on a particular product.

CBEA

May 2003

Annex

BACKGROUND NOTE

  1.  The EU regime which was challenged in the WTO provided preferential terms of access for African and Caribbean countries. These arose from traditional links between individual EU and ACP states; in the case of the UK, the links were with Jamaica, Belize and the four Windward Island states of Dominica, St Lucia, St Vincent and the Grenadines and Grenada.

  2.  After the Second World War, the banana export trade in these Commonwealth Caribbean states flourished only because the UK operated a restrictive import regime designed to ensure them a remunerative return. Competing imports from the dollar suppliers were limited by quota. Initially, this was necessary for currency reasons, but the restrictions were maintained after that need had gone, in order to safeguard the trade from Jamaica and the Windward Islands and subsequently Belize and Surinam.

  3.  Without this protection this trade could not have survived, because the Caribbean industry could not compete on price with production from the industrial scale operations on the vast plantations of Latin America. But the trade had become crucial to the economies of specific regions in Jamaica and Belize and, above all, to the entire economies of the Windward Islands. It accounted on average for over half all export income and over a third of employment in the three main exporting states, Dominica, St Lucia and St Vincent. There was hardly a family on these islands that did not depend to some extent, directly or indirectly, on the banana trade. That trade had been developed after the War to replace the depressed sugar industry. It transformed the economies of these formerly impoverished islands[33]but it depended entirely on a protected market in the UK.

  4.  Following UK accession to the EEC, the continuation of this degree of protection was guaranteed to these countries by the Lome Convention between the EU and a number of African, Caribbean and Pacific (ACP) states. This Convention covered a wide range of trade and aid issues, but on bananas the EU guaranteed to preserve both the market access and existing benefits of traditional ACP suppliers. In 1993, the individual national market regimes that ensured this had to be replaced by a single market regime applying to imports into all member states. It was this regime that was the subject of continuing disputes in the GATT and its successor the WTO.


31   Banana Imports from the Caribbean, a study by National Economic Research Associates, April 2003. Back

32   To by-pass the "conceptually difficult and politically fraught" task of defining small vulnerable states, a study for the Commonwealth Secretariat suggested a more generalised approach based on minimal shares of global trade: "A Study of Alternative Special and Differential Arrangements for Small Economies" by Michael Davenport. Back

33   See, for example, the description of the state of the islands in the Report of the War India Royal Commission 1938-39, which was laid before Parliament in June 1945 (Cmnd 6607). Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 14 July 2003