Select Committee on International Development Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by the Commonwealth Business Council

DELIVERING BASIC SERVICES TO THE POOR NEW APPROACHES TO OLD PROBLEMS

I.  SUMMARY

  1.  This paper sets out six areas of reforms designed to increase the levels of private sector involvement in improving the delivery of public services to poor people.

  2.  The international community is committed to challenging targets for improving basic infrastructure services to the poor through the Millennium Development Goals (MDGs). The investment required to meet these targets is, however, much greater than is currently being spent by public and private sectors combined. Moreover, recent public sector lending to infrastructure is down sharply from close to $8 billion per annum in 1993 to only $2 billion per annum in 2002. [39]Private sector investment into emerging markets is also in retreat, falling from a peak of approximately $130 billion per annum in 1997 to half this level by 2001.

  3.  While the large scale transfer of market risk involved in full divestiture, concessioning, build-own-operate or transfer can be workable where there is a robust off-take arrangement or a clearly observable commercial upside, it remains extremely problematic in infrastructure sectors where basic commercial viability is difficult to demonstrate, such as with water, sanitation or road development.

  4.  In order to attract more private capital—especially in the current risk averse environment—a wider range of approaches is needed.

  5.  The main challenge lies in how to create sustainable infrastructure business models that are responsive to the real needs of local communities, that can deliver services cost-effectively and that are capable of mobilising the large amounts of long-term capital to finance the heavy front-end expenditure involved. This paper points to the following areas of reform which, if addressed collectively, would facilitate a much greater role for the private sector in meeting the MDG objectives:

  6.  Universal access not universal standards. All customers need to be actively involved in decisions about the trade-offs between standards, cost and affordability. This points to a "tripartite" approach to project design, development and management involving civil society (notably national NGOs), government and business as a means of establishing better co-operation between groups not always comfortable with each other's objectives and motives. There needs to be a shift in focus away from attempting to achieve universal service standards to improving universal access. Appropriate standards of service are more likely to have an acceptable level of "full-cost recovery" fees—making charges affordable and yet maintaining the commercial sustainability of service delivery.

  7.  New models for delivery and ownership of infrastructure. Especially in the more challenging infrastructure sectors such as water, new models are needed that allow inclusive stakeholder involvement, whilst retaining business-like management of the implementation by private sector professionals. In this process there needs to be greater emphasis in delivery through partnerships with NGOs and the role, and a building up of the capabilities of domestic private sector infrastructure managers. New arrangements, based on the concept of corporate entities where surpluses are reinvested in network expansion rather than distributed, operated privately on a fully commercially sustainable basis, but owned and governed by national stakeholders may be worth investigating as potential solutions.

  8.  Attracting commercial operators. This model is likely to secure much greater commitment from commercial operators because it involves undertaking controllable cost and performance risks, but not the regulatory or, at times, revenue risks which are, for them, non-controllable risks. At the same time, commercial operators would be fully incentivised to deliver on performance and be rewarded for the professional skills and management expertise committed. In other cases, bringing in private sector management prior to concessioning or sale can sometimes presage a successful change of ownership. These approaches should therefore be combined with an emphasis on output based contracting, which is consistent with output based aid (OBA) approaches being led by the World Bank. [40]

  9.  Paying for the service. Whilst it is essential that user charges pay for the cost of running the infrastructure service, in many cases such levels of charges would be unaffordable to large proportions of the poor. Carefully structured subsidies, utilising OBA approaches, targeted at either specific groups or else at particular impediments to service uptake (such as up-front connection costs), will be needed to make delivery of services viable for private sector investment.

  10.  Mobilising finance. In an ideal world much of the required debt capital would be raised from domestic financial markets. Although this goal should remain within the policies of international development partners, progress however is likely to be slow. In the meantime, International Financial Institution (IFI) credit enhancement mechanisms will be increasingly needed to address specific country risks impeding the flow of capital from international credit and capital markets as well as potential equity, risk sharing, based interventions.

  11.  Improving the capacity to deliver. The need for wider and more intelligent stakeholder participation in designing infrastructure projects, the need for better allocation of the various risks to those who can most efficiently bear them and the complexity and long term nature of contract management, have very significant implications for the capacity of the public and private sectors to transact and manage infrastructure projects. This is especially relevant in the poorer nations where good management is often the scarcest commodity of all. While facilities exist to improve policy formulation, these must be complemented by tools to ensure that governments and local business have the capacity to transact and subsequently manage the structures. A number of Commonwealth countries such as the UK, and more recently South Africa, have developed centres of excellence in private sector participation (PSP) techniques which should be made available to other Commonwealth members. At the same time, and equally vital, there must be an overarching sense of pragmatism to ensure that new implementation structures are not so complex that they cannot stand the test of practical and cost effective implementation.

  1. INTRODUCTION

  12.  The poor of the world lack access to adequate basic services—safe water, adequate sanitation and modern energy services, not to mention telephony and modern modes of transport. It is estimated that about 1 billion people currently do not have access to safe water, about 2.2 billion do not have access to any form of improved sanitation service and in excess of 2 billion do not have access to modern energy services (electricity and petroleum products). [41]The consequent cost in both human and economic terms in incalculable.

  13.  In September 2000, heads of all UN member states gathered in New York where they adopted a series of resolutions that set out clearly the priorities and commitments for the international community to deal with the problem. The resolutions included commitments "To halve, by the year 2015, the proportion of the world's people whose income is less than one dollar a day and the proportion of people who suffer from hunger; and also, by the same date, to halve the proportion of people who are unable to reach, or to afford, safe drinking water. [42]These, together with other targets adopted at the summit, have become known as the Millennium Development Goals (MDG).

  14.  Two years later, this time at the World Summit on Sustainable Development in Johannesburg, world leaders reaffirmed these resolutions. They also added targets to halve the proportion of people without access to basic sanitation services by 2015 as well as a number of commitments on improving access to modern energy services. Box 1 outlines key commitments as summarised in the UN "Key Outcomes of the Summit" document.

Box 1: Key commitments from the World Summit on Sustainable Development
WaterHalve, by the year 2015, the proportion of people without access to safe drinking water (reaffirmation of Millennium Development Goal).
SanitationHalve, by the year 2015, the proportion of people who do not have access to basic sanitation.
Access to energyImprove access to reliable, affordable, economically viable socially acceptable and environmentally sound energy services and resources, sufficient to achieve the Development Goals, including the goal of halving the proportion of people in poverty by 2015.
Renewable energyDiversify energy supply and substantially increase the global share of renewable energy sources in order to increase its contribution to total energy supply.
Energy marketsRemove market distortions including the restructuring of taxes and the phasing out of harmful subsidies.


  15.  This paper argues that whilst both the private and public sectors have worked hard to develop partnerships in infrastructure development, significant challenges still remain due to the complexity of the issues. Reverting to public sector only solutions, which have consistently failed in increasing access to basic utility services, is not an option. At the same time, the means by which the private sector is involved, particularly in highly sensitive sectors, arguably also needs to be revisited to take account of current realities and the lessons that have been learnt. The private sector still has a major role to play, not least if the major financing requirements are to be met. Greater innovation is therefore called for, which combines a number of different models, if a balanced approach is to be achieved and if the benefits of private sector participation (PSP) are to be maximised.

  16.  While we take for granted that an appropriate legal and regulatory environment is a major prerequisite for private sector involvement, this paper focuses on:

    —  some of the key challenges to be addressed in meeting the MDGs, not least the scale of the funding requirement;

    —  key principles to be applied in developing new and innovative public-private approaches that can address traditionally thorny problems;

    —  the means by which infrastructure services can be paid for; and

    —  how the necessary long term debt and equity funding might be raised.

III.  CHALLENGES

  17.  It is one thing to set targets as ambitious as the MDGs and quite another to achieve them. The challenges facing developing countries and the donor community seeking to redress the situation are systemic and chronic.

(a)  The funding gap—why private capital is so important

  18.  It is very difficult to even estimate a figure for the resources required to achieve the MDGs and those targets added in Johannesburg. In water management alone, the Global Water Partnership, in their report to the World Water Commission, states that the current expenditure of $70 billion per annum will need to be increased to $170 billion per annum. Other analyses suggest that this figure is still likely to be an underestimate. The situation in the sanitation and modern energy sectors is similar. With rapid population growth and the deterioration of existing assets the funding requirements are only set to grow.

  19.  Current levels of public and private investment are insufficient, by a long way, to satisfy these growing requirements. Firstly, the developing countries' fiscal positions have never been sufficient to tackle the infrastructure problems properly, and if anything, have become more strained over the last decade due to economic crises, population growth, AIDS, climatic calamities etc. Secondly, international development partners, which have been supplementing these fiscal deficits for years, are not able to keep up with the demand. Estimates of the average annual amount of official aid over the last three years, in the water and sanitation sectors, suggest that it amounts to only around $9 billion per annum. [43]There is little, if any, prospect of this figure increasing significantly in the foreseeable future. Moreover, figures for IBRD—public sector lending to infrastructure more widely, shows a deep downward trajectory from close to $8 billion per annum in 1993 to only $2 billion per annum in 2002. [44]

20.  The private sector, which in the 1990s invested significant amounts into emerging markets' infrastructure, is also in retreat. The flows of 1990s were driven by investments into the power and telecommunications sectors of East Asia and Latin America, which have gone into reverse as both regions hit crises during the later part of the decade. From a peak of approximately $130 billion per annum in 1997—the year of the onset of the Asian crisis—annual flows had more than halved by 2001. The picture is slightly more optimistic for those low income countries, who never really benefited from the desire for emerging market exposure in the 1990s, as they have actually seen a slight increase in flows. The amounts of capital in question, however, still fall far short of what is required.

  21.  The outlook across all the countries may even be more unfavourable than the historical outturn as the availability of new capital is becoming increasingly rationed, driven by falling global stock markets and retrenchments by many utility and telecommunications companies following the corporate excesses of the last decade.

  22.  With annual global savings at around $7 trillion per annum (World Bank SIMA database), private sector capital is plentiful, which is why it is so relevant. However, in an era of risk averse capital, the additional risks associated with emerging markets have done little to improve the appetite for continued investment in these markets. This conundrum is a challenge for both policy makers and investors alike and requires a careful reassessment of what is required to reinvigorate investment flows to developing and transitional countries.

(b)  Unsuccessful delivery models

  23.  There have been problems with both public and private sector infrastructure service delivery models. The public sector monopolies of the second part of the twentieth century have often been grossly inefficient. They have been unable to maintain existing assets, improve service to existing customers and importantly, have not been able to meet the ever-growing demand in developing countries—especially from the poor. Decisions by poorly trained and unmotivated public sector work force tend to be driven by political pressures and not commercial sustainability and/or technical necessity. These weaknesses are well known by those active in this sector in developing countries. [45]

  24.  On the other hand, private sector solutions have repeatedly been presented as a panacea for all problems, often with little understanding of the role that the private sector is able to take in a given situation. Large scale transfer of market—pricing and volume—risk involved in full divestiture, concession/build-own-operate (BOO) and build-operate-transfer (BOT) can, for example, be workable where there is a robust off-take arrangement (independent power production) or a clearly observable commercial upside—(for example, airports in buoyant economies, electricity transmission etc), but extremely problematic in infrastructure sectors where basic commercial viability is difficult to demonstrate. The building of toll roads and water and sanitation often fall well within this latter grouping.

  25.  To these basic commercial impediments must be added the full range of financial (interest rate and currency devaluation) and particularly political (such as currency transfer) and wider country risks. Regulatory risk arising from an independent regulator making arbitrary changes to prices—often in the face of popular hostility to a PSP arrangement—represents a continuing impediment to private sector investment.

  26.  A number of development partners have been extremely keen to pursue the most radical forms of PSP largely in the belief that it is the best way to raise private capital. The highly publicised recent failures of this approach—for instance in Bolivia—has done little for the cause. Pushing unacceptable risks on to the private sector will either result in failure of the approach—as witnessed by a number of recently abandoned transactions such as the Manila water concession (Mayniland) in the Philippines, or transactions taking place on terms which are undesirable for all stakeholders, often leading to subsequent renegotiation of badly performing contracts. In designing PSP approaches it is therefore imperative to be realistic about what risks the private sector is willing to take so that the ensuing arrangements both represent value for money and are more sustainable.

  27.  In addition to concessions, it is important to consider other approaches, particularly in the more challenging sectors, such as lease arrangements (water) and revenue bonds for municipal financings. As will be discussed, it is perfectly acceptable and in many cases necessary, to allow for subsidies in the design of projects, as long as they are targeted on the underlying problem (such as the high costs of grid connection to households who can otherwise afford the ongoing service) and leverage in private finance rather than crowd it out (as in the case of bilateral concessional loans which can displace private money).

  28.  In summary, whilst we are still on the learning curve as regards developing appropriate forms of PSP solution, the approach remains valid in the fact of continuing public sector failure and the need for private sector financing. The issue should therefore be seen as not so much one of whether or not the private sector should be involved, but rather the precise manner in which its role maximises the benefit to all.

(c)  The need for tariff reform

  29.  A basic tenet of commercial viability is that revenues are higher than all-in costs, whether this be through the tariff rate or through other income flows such as subsidies. But the pricing of many infrastructure services—not least water—is often highly politicised.

  30.  Many feel that water and sanitation services are a public good that should be provided free at the point of use. This belief has made setting cost recovery tariff levels and having effective collection procedures very problematic. Financing services out of (local or national) taxes is undermined by low levels of economic activity and widespread tax evasion. The difficulty lies in reconciling this reality with the simple fact that, at the end of the day, someone must pay for these services.

31.  Further aggravating the problem is that, in country after country, the limited financial resources that are available are misallocated. The better-off tend to enjoy deeply subsidised prices for their infrastructure service while the poor receive no service at all—in fact they often pay much higher prices for significantly lower quality service (eg questionable quality water from unlicensed street vendors). Despite repeated urging by donors to abolish these subsidies and divert the funds towards financing basic service access by the poor, the political realities remain hard to shift. The better-off tend to be more politically empowered and therefore have greater leverage on national and in particular local level politicians to pursue their self-interest.

  32.  What needs to be recognised by all—including those (often foreign) pressure groups who are against private sector involvement—is that infrastructure services need to be cost recovering—irrespective of ownership. In a context of finite resources, where subsidies are employed (whether for the benefit of the rich or poor), the opportunity cost of providing them must be evaluated against other key social services forgone—such as health and education.

IV.  NEW APPROACHES

Harris, 2003 The Beginning of the End or the End of the Beginning? A review of Private Participation in Infrastructure in Developing Countries, The World Bank.

  33.  The challenge, therefore, is to create sustainable PSP models that recognise the challenges faced by the private sector, even once various forms of official risk mitigation (such as political risk insurance) are taken into account, but which are responsive to the real needs of businesses and local communities (including the poor) in developing countries. Such approaches need to be able to deliver services to existing and new customers cost-effectively whilst minimising the barriers to the flow of long-term finance from domestic and international financial markets.

  34.  Achieving this combination will not be easy; however, adopting the following principles and structures, which recognise the central though, differing role of the private sector, may assist in making this more achievable.

 (a)   Appropriate service standards and means of delivery

  35.  A starting point is the nature of the service provided. Networked water, sanitation and modern energy solutions generally provide a significantly higher standard of service to connected customers than non-networked solutions. However, the cost of providing networked services to the entire population of a country (in particular with regards to water and sanitation) is prohibitive. There therefore needs to be a shift in focus away from attempting to achieve universal service standards to improving universal access. In essence, this means accepting the fact that it will be impossible, at least in the short term, to provide every household with the same level of utility service, irrespective of the costs of doing so. Policy-makers need to be realistic in recognising that one size does not fit all, in terms of both the nature of the service and who delivers it, with the result that some people may receive a higher level of service than others, although everyone should be better off. In the longer term, however, these anomalies can be corrected for many customers, not least because there will be a greater ability to fund the costs of higher levels of service—such as connecting more geographically isolated customers to the grid—from a much larger customer base.

  36.  A related point is that of being more prepared to accept the role, and to build on the capabilities of existing domestic private suppliers. Whilst it is recognised that sometimes these suppliers operate high cost monopolies, the response should neither be one of closing them down nor ignoring them, especially where they are the sole providers of a much needed service. As there is unlikely to be a major element of natural monopoly in the market structure, as elsewhere, the introduction of competitors will be likely to reduce prices and increase quality of service. [46]

  37.  In short, local entrepreneurial, customer focused behaviour should be encouraged as the domestic private sector will often be in a better position to assess business risk than foreign suppliers. A further advantage of local, especially smaller scale, approaches is that they are often more financeable—either through formal or informal channels, than large scale networked solutions which require long term, difficult to raise, local and international financing. More usually, however, there are attempts to frustrate smaller scale suppliers—such as auto-producers of electricity who sell their surplus to neighbouring households and villages—through regressive legislation/regulation or through imposing unrealistic technical standards. (The issue of improving regulatory impact assessment is an area that CBC and others are seeking to tackle).

  38.  In the final analysis, the objective should be about delivering a service that is appropriate to the ability and willingness to pay of different groups, rather than the form of the delivery. As such, the appropriate solution may differ both between infrastructure sectors and between different areas.

(i)   Urban areas

  39.  Urban areas present the greatest opportunities for more traditional forms of single utility and have traditionally been more able to attract larger, especially foreign, private sector operators. It is most likely that higher levels of income, a greater potential for some cross subsidy between commercial and industrial customers and households, and the lower average costs of connection arising from greater population density, will make concession of divestiture models more viable. Even here, however, rather than assuming that a consortium from an OECD country will seek the opportunity, investors and financiers from other developing countries may be best suited to such opportunities, bringing highly relevant experience from their own countries.

(ii)   Peri-urban areas

  40.  In small towns and peri-urban areas of larger towns, lower cost and lower specification solutions are likely to be needed if widespread access to basic services is to be achieved. For water services the appropriate technology for such areas may therefore be largely standpipe/kiosk based, supplemented by provision of service points for tanker services and water vendors to ensure that the service can keep up with the rapidly changing patterns of settlement. Government acceptance of these alternatives and therefore better (water quality) regulation will protect public health whilst the competition from numerous alternative points of supply will keep the prices down.

  41.  Appropriate technical solutions in sanitation, that are economically feasible in poor peri-urban districts (often with unclear land tenure), are likely to be limited to simple private on-site solutions such as dry pit latrines or, where local culture and strong incentives and institutional arrangements for maintenance permit, shared public latrine blocks.

(iii)   Rural

  42.  Networked solutions for the basic infrastructure services will, in most cases, be even less appropriate for rural areas. A fully reticulated water supply system, for example, will not be economically feasible, except in the very long-term. For the smallest village communities, the appropriate technical/economic solution for water supply, in the short-term, may be limited to local manual abstraction at or near the source—for example a protected well or borehole with a hand-pump. In larger communities it may be appropriate to pump the water from source to an intermediate storage tank or reservoir, allowing the water to be distributed to standpipe/tap house facilities and offering the scope to move progressively from shared communal facilities to a networked solution with individual household connections.

  43.  Whilst the costs of connecting peri-urban areas to a national electricity grid can be within reach of many developing countries' budgets, they become prohibitively expensive in rural areas. Isolated networks with local generation capacity (diesel or preferably renewable sources—solar or hydro power) are likely to be the more appropriate solutions. Often, in very remote areas, house specific (possibly solar) generating power capacity may be the most efficient and effective way of providing energy to the household.

 (b)   Empowering the customer

  44.  As with any service, however, it should not be for national (and even for local) governments alone or for development partners to take decisions about the trade-offs between service standards, costs and charges—local communities, as consumers of services, must be centrally involved in these decisions. This point was emphasised at the recent commonwealth Local Government Forum in South Africa. It is only through this invaluable "voice of the customer" feedback, that services can be adequately structured. Indeed, unlike most public sector providers, the private sector typically needs to be responsive to customer requirements if it is to prosper, or in many cases, survive.

  45.  Recent efforts to adopt a "tripartite" approach to project design, development and management involving civil society (notably national NGOs), government and business have shown promise as a means of establishing better co-operation between groups that are not always comfortable with each other's objectives and motives. A starting point is to be clear about the objectives, roles and responsibilities of all stakeholders. Although slower to get started, such decentralised and demand led approaches are much more likely to be sustainable. With more affordable solutions and community buy-in there will also be a greater willingness of beneficiaries to pay user charges and/or additional local taxes. The challenge remains to develop institutions and processes that provide for informed local involvement in decision making while retaining a disciplined commercial environment conducive to mobilising the required finance.

 (c)   New forms of partnership

  46.  As discussed, full concession and divestiture business models have in many cases proven to be inappropriate (examples include water concessions in the Philippines, Bolivia, Argentina etc). This approach has proven to be unacceptable to national stakeholders and to private sector water companies (given their limited appetite for non-controllable risk). Having said this, the commercial discipline needed for operational cost-efficiency, raising of finance on international and potentially domestic financial markets, as well as a high degree of responsiveness to customer needs, is most likely to be achieved through some form of a private sector approach. Going back to publicly managed monopolies will not, generally, be the appropriate solution. It is therefore time to consider more innovative approaches, particularly in the more problematic infrastructure sectors.

 (d)   A not-for profit distribution vehicle in the water sector?

  47.  To address this point in sectors such as water, while maximising the benefits of PSP, it is perhaps time to consider new models which combine inclusive stakeholder involvement, while retaining business-like management of the implementation of agreed investment programmes by "sector professionals". While sector expertise might initially come from abroad, there must be a partnership with local managers wherever possible and with the aim of building local expertise for the long term. Such a model would be likely to retain a limited liability corporate vehicle; however, it might operate on a not-for-profit-distribution basis, with all profits being reinvested in continued network expansion.

  48.  As the private sector operator may not always be in a position to commit to a significant financial stake in such an arrangement, it is imperative that an appropriate incentive regime is established to encourage the commitment of human resources. In other words, the provider needs to be contracted to deliver specified outputs and rewarded for results, if as an equity investor it is not able to take on the full range of business and country risks. The "client" and contracting counterparty with the service providers would be the licensed corporate vehicle set up to develop and operate the infrastructure services within a defined area. With output-based contracts the contractor finances the implementation of the agreed investment programme and is paid on agreed bases as and when it delivers the contracted outputs.

  49.  Involving the foreign private sector in this way has several important advantages:

    (i)  the model is likely to secure much greater commitment from foreign operators because it involves them taking controllable cost and performance risks with appropriate rewards, but not the regulatory and revenue risks which are, for them, non-controllable risks;

    (ii)  in many countries it should be more acceptable to governments and local communities than the concession model, because surpluses are not paid out in profits, but rather reinvested in the service and/or used to reduce user charges. This could unlock opportunities for the benefit of users and private sector service providers alike;

    (iii)  the use of the corporate structure is likely to make it easier to reach agreement on charging arrangements that will cover full cost of service (whatever level of service that may be);

    (iv)  the transfer of controllable cost and performance risks to the private sector service providers will help ensure cost effective service delivery; and

    (v)  it will assist in the mobilisation of long-term debt to finance the investments as an appropriately incentivised private sector operator will be more credible with private banks.

(e)  Involvement of the local private sector

  50.  Involving the national private sector, sometimes as partners with the foreign private sector, is also very important. This is probably the best way that a strong national capability in delivery of basic infrastructure services can be built up over time. This will also reduce the tendency for entrenchment into "Us" and "Them" positions often seen in concession models operated by the large international private sector companies.

  51.  National and foreign non-governmental organisations (NGOs) also have an important role to play working with local communities to strengthen their capacity to engage effectively in the process of decision making about what to do, as partners often with good local knowledge and contributing to the delivery of basic services for the poor.

V.  PAYING FOR INFRASTRUCTURE SERVICES

  52.  We now return to one of the major impediments discussed above—payment for infrastructure services. As set out, the fact that services must be paid for—and not by the private sector—must be accepted. Investment in infrastructure services requires heavy front-ended expenditure on capital assets that deliver a flow of benefits to users over many decades. The front-end expenditures must be financed—by public or private sector borrowing and/or equity finance. Over the life of the project, revenues generated must be sufficient to recoup the full cost of providing the services including the cost of capital (interest on debt and/or return on equity). Those revenues can be derived from just four possible sources:

    —  user charges levied on the beneficiaries of the services once they are available;

    —  increased user charges levied on existing connected customers;

    —  new national or local taxes; and

    —  donor grants and subsidies.

  53.  Ideally, the user charges would be set to "full-cost recovery" levels, which would mean that the expected revenues generated over the life of the asset would be sufficient to recover the capital and operating costs (including the costs of capital). However, the problem arises when large segments of the population are not able to afford the "full-cost recovery" levels, as is the case in many developing countries.

(a)  Subsidies

  54.  In cases where the affordable level of service by households is deemed to be below a socially and politically acceptable level, carefully targeted subsidies will be needed to supplement the shortfall.

  55.  Traditionally multilateral and bilateral international financial institutions (IFIs) have supported infrastructure services development by making commercial and/or concessional loans to parastatal utilities. This approach is widely recognised as having provided very weak incentives on borrowers/operators. The quality of investment has often been poor, cost over-runs considerable and there have been very limited benefits for the poor in most developing countries.

  56.  A new approach—output based aid—builds on the concept of output-based contracting referred to earlier. The development partner or IFI contracts—as part of a wider financial plan—to make payments to the contractor as and when it delivers a pre-agreed output specification (quantity and quality). For example, a service provider to a medium-size town may agree that, in addition to providing services from which the future revenues can be expected to cover the costs, it will also provide certain "non-commercial" services (ie services that are not able to recoup the costs from its users) in peri-urban areas. The IFI agrees to make future payments contingent on the contractors' performance sufficient to meet the difference between the expected costs and the revenues received from (subsidised) users. The contractor is able to raise the required working capital from its bankers to mobilise and implement the contract on the basis that it will receive contract revenues from donors subject only to delivery of the contracted outputs.

  57.  The advantages of OBA are similar to those of output-based contracting:

    —  payments are linked to performance regimes which maintain strong incentives to deliver defined outputs at least cost (because cost and performance risks remain with the contractor);

    —  payments are targeted on pro-poor outcomes (contributing to affordability for target groups) and only made when outputs are delivered;

    —  costs are minimised when payment schedules are set by competition; and

    —  the schemes can be designed in a way that customers have a significant say in their design.

  58.  Output-based aid programmes will require a different approach by development partners to supporting pro-poor basic infrastructure services. Commitments are made to a non-sovereign, non-public sector borrower (the regulated corporate vehicle) and to a (private sector) service provider to make future payments contingent on contractor performance. The commitments will typically involve disbursing funds many years in the future. This is an unfamiliar approach (particularly for bilateral donors). To date most OBA schemes have been used principally for rural electrification schemes in middle income developing countries, but more and more examples, in different sectors, are being tested. [47]

  59.  Considering that funding from development partners and the IFIs is finite, it is still of paramount importance when designing the infrastructure solutions that the service standards are appropriate to the customers' affordability levels and costs of service. Customer involvement in these trade-offs will be crucial. In addition, governments will need to pursue more vigorously the removal of subsidies from better-off customers, redirecting them to supplement any OBA donor funding.

VI.  MOBILISING LONG-TERM FINANCE

  60.  As mentioned earlier, large amounts of long-term finance are required to finance the basic infrastructure investment programmes—at least for major "production" or "trunk" projects which have lumpy, up-front financing requirements. This provides major challenges for both debt and equity finance.

(a)  Debt

  61.  Long-term debt, either from credit or capital (bond) markets, is usually desirable for infrastructure projects as it is cheaper than equity and acts so as to keep the cost of capital (and therefore user charges) as low as possible (unlike dividends, interest is also normally tax deductible). The debt will be secured on the future revenues to be derived from user charges, from additional taxes (if any) agreed with local or national government and from payments by the development partners (eg under output-based aid contracts).

  62.  There are, of course, limits to the amount of debt that can be raised for a project—the more risky the project, the greater the proportion of equity required so as to be able to service the debt. The greater the project risk is reduced, through, for instance, appropriate risk allocation, the more debt can be raised within a given financing structure.

(b)  Local currency debt

  63.  In an ideal world much of this debt would be raised from the domestic financial market and in the local currency. Such a scenario would improve domestic saving and investment opportunities, strengthen the domestic financial markets and eliminate the foreign currency exposures faced by so many of the private sector operators in developing countries. Indeed, recent research quoted in an Economist magazine survey, shows empirically that a mix of foreign equity and local debt is optimal for economic development.

  64.  In most cases, however, this is not possible. A major problem in many developing countries is that the savings rate is not high enough to generate a sufficiently large pool of funding, a fact compounded by the lack of development of local credit and capital markets, which have extremely limited, if any, long term liquidity required for major infrastructure financing. Funding of smaller scale infrastructure services is, however, much more possible.

  65.  Recognising these problems and the considerable benefits that can arise at both the project (better matching of revenue and cost flows) and macroeconomic level (reduced strain on scarce foreign exchange resources) many donors have been seeking to develop support mechanisms for local currency funding. In particular, the Swedish and UK governments have taken a lead in developing GuarantCo which will help infrastructure companies tap into local institutional markets through appropriately structured credit enhancements (see below). Such approaches remain, however, very much in their infancy.

(c)  International debt and the need for credit enhancement

  66.  The availability of such local finance will, however, be constrained by a number of factors including the overall pool of national savings as well as the low inflation environment required to keep local interest rates competitive. A considerable amount of finance for infrastructure will therefore inevitably be foreign currency debt, raised from multi-lateral and bilateral institutions and from the international debt markets. The quantum of finance required to meet the MDGs/Johannesburg targets, for example, far exceeds what is likely currently to be available from official lenders or domestic capital markets, so recourse to the international private sector debt market will be necessary. However, perceptions of country risk, in particular, prevent many developing countries from accessing (the relatively plentiful) long term debt to finance infrastructure investments. Even where opportunities offer a clear prospect of generating future revenues sufficient to repay the debt, finance will not flow in the absence of official financial interventions or so-called credit enhancements. This problem is set to be aggravated following the latest Basel round, in which country risk exposures are more likely to be heavily penalised than they are at the moment, further discouraging lending.

  67.  Credit enhancement is a mechanism for selectively transferring specified risks from borrowers to the provider of credit enhancement (for a fee). It increases the availability, and reduces the cost, of debt to the borrower. If credit enhancement fees are modest then the all-in cost of debt is reduced—allowing a reduction in average charges on users over the project life.

  68.  Box 2 sets out a range of credit enhancement instruments that have been used by private sector project sponsors to mitigate project risks to facilitate financing at a reasonable cost.

BOX 2: FORMS OF CREDIT ENHANCEMENT
Risks covered% of exposure guaranteed Nature of credit enhancement
All risks100%"Full faith" guarantee
All risks<100%Partial credit guarantee
Political risk onlyUp to 100% Political risk guarantee
Specific risks (government breach of contract, regulatory risk) Up to 100%Partial risk guarantee
Demand-side risk onlyUp to 100% Minimum revenue (take or pay)
undertaking
Supply-side completion risksUp to 100% Completion guarantee
Performance risksUp to 100% Minimum performance
undertaking

  69.  Why should the IFIs provide credit enhancement? Why not, instead just increase lending? In the short term there are many IFIs with available capital to support basic infrastructure investment programmes when they are structured as viable business opportunities generating sufficient revenue to repay the debt. In the short-term therefore the constraint is not lack of funds—at least IFI funding—it is lack of opportunities. [48]But, in the medium-term, if the financial flows required to meet the MDGs/Johannesburg targets are to be mobilised, new sources of capital from the private sector financial markets will be needed.

  70.  Why credit enhancement rather than more loans? They are four key reasons. First, to maximise leverage—by this we mean the ability to mobilise more than $1 of debt finance by "using" $1 of IFI funds. Provision of partial risk guarantees offers the prospect over time of diversifying the risk portfolio, thereby enabling IFIs to mobilise from the debt markets amounts of credit that are a multiple of the value of the IFI support. Second, partial risk credit enhancement is cost-effective because it leaves controllable risks with the party best able to control and manage them (eg supply-side commercial risk with service providers). Third, leaving commercial risk exposure with commercial risk with service providers). Third, leaving commercial risk exposure with commercial lenders provides a strong incentive for them to re-assure themselves that the commercial opportunity is well structured and economically viable. Finally, providing partial credit guarantees to domestic lenders and bond investors supports the longer-term objective of developing deep, domestic financial markets.

(d)  Equity

  71.  Whilst keenly priced debt is highly attractive, it is, however, extremely difficult to remove the need for some form of equity cushion all together. In reality, at least with the array of risk mitigation devices currently available, it is difficult to fully cover off all risks—especially in developing markets. Ultimately, the customer will need to pick up the tab for unfavourable market developments, but lenders will normally look for some equity protection, especially where there is considerable market risk. Whilst the not for profit distribution corporate model has been applied in the UK within the water sector, this benefits from a relatively stable regulatory environment, with the market being largely mature and the consequent risks being possible to mitigate through retained profits acting as quasi-equity. The developing world will be different. Most importantly, whilst equity was not seen as a major constraint during the late 1990s, the reality on the ground is that such risk capital is fairly scarce.

  72.  As equity inevitably bears all risks, many development partners have normally shied away from providing it, sticking instead to the provision of political risk mitigation. In today's market, however, development partners and/or governments are often the only group in a position to take, or at least substantially shoulder, certain risks. The objective of any such financial intervention—for instance—through development partners taking a share of the equity or first loss risk and the private sector taking a mix of first loss (equity) and second loss (eg mezzanine) risks, would be to leverage private capital. This should not be undertaken in a way that the providers of such capital take all of the downside but none of the upside, but rather in a genuine risk sharing manner, ideally with the discipline of the private sector "bidding" to take risk at the least cost. Such approaches to financial structuring—which need to be combined with appropriately structured performance contracting—should be more actively considered now than they have been hitherto if the current shortage of risk capital is to be addressed.

VII.  CAPACITY

  73.  There is a temptation to lose sight of the practical implications when new approaches to transactions are considered. The need for wider and more intelligent stakeholder participation in designing infrastructure projects, the need for better allocation of the various risks to those who can most efficiently bear them and the complexity and long term nature of contract management, all have significant implications for the capacity of the public and private sectors to transact and manage infrastructure projects. This is especially relevant in the poorer nations where good management is often the scarcest commodity of all. While facilities such as the World Bank's PPIAF exist to improve policy formulation, these facilities must urgently be complemented by tools to ensure that governments and local business have the capacity to transact and subsequently manage the structures. At the same time, and equally vital, there must be an overarching sense of pragmatism to ensure that any new structures are not so complex that they cannot stand the test of practical and cost effective implementation.

October 2003


39   Harris, 2003 The beginning of the End or the End of the Beginning? A Review of Private Participation in Infrastructure in Developing Countries, The World Bank. Back

40   The Global Partnership for Output Based Aid (GPOBA) has recently been established by the World Bank and the UK Department for International Development. Back

41   Global Water and Sanitation Assessment 2000 Report-WHO/UNICEF Joint Monitoring Programme. Back

42   UN Millennium Declaration-September 2000. Back

43   DfID "Addressing the Water Crisis" March 2001. Back

44   Harris, 2003 The Beginning of the End or the End of the Beginning? A review of Private Participation in Infrastructure in Developing Countries, The World Bank.

 Back

45   "Making connections"-a DfID consultation document 2002. Back

46   Back

47   See, for example, Brook, PJ and Smith, SM (Eds) 2001, Contracting for Public Services. Output-based aid and its applications, World Bank. Back

48   As shown in market analysis carried out by the Emerging Africa Infrastructure Fund. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2003
Prepared 2 December 2003