Select Committee on Culture, Media and Sport Fifth Report


APPENDIX 1

National Lottery licensing and competition

An independent report prepared for Camelot by Frontier Economics Ltd, London (Executive Summary)

1. In July 2003 the Government announced that it had decided that a radical new approach to licensing the National Lottery is needed, both to increase competition for licences, and also to allow more companies to participate in the Lottery.[175] The Government therefore proposes to replace the current "single licence" model, whereby the National Lottery is run by a single operator, with a "multiple licence" model in which the National Lottery Commission (NLC) may offer one or more operating licences to run different parts of the Lottery.

2. Camelot asked Frontier Economics to carry out an independent economic assessment of the government's proposal to adopt a multiple licence model, focusing in particular on the likely impact of this on the money raised for good causes.

Key assumptions

3. The impact of the multiple licence model on good causes will depend on the specification of the licences that are offered by the NLC, and also on the details of the licence award process. The NLC has not announced a final decision on these issues, but has given some indication of its likely approach. For the purpose of this report we have assumed that:

  • there will be no significant change in the legal definition of a Lottery, and so the scope of activities that may be licensed by the NLC in future will be similar to now;
  • operating licences will be "full capacity" licences as defined above. That is licences will cover specified games or classes of games, and also the means to deliver them;
  • the NLC will continue to regulate the design of individual games (or classes of game) promoted by operating licensees in a similar manner to the current Section 6 licences; and
  • the NLC will award operating licences by competitive tender to the bidder(s) who (subject to meeting probity and player protection conditions) offers the best deal for good causes.

4. Subject to these assumptions, our analysis is not predicated on a particular view of the operating licences that the NLC might offer. Instead, we have focused on examining the key issues and trade-offs that are inherent to the multiple licence model as compared to the single licence model. As a consequence, our main conclusions do not depend on the exact nature of the operating licences offered.

5. In the two previous licence competitions commercial gambling firms have been prevented from bidding by the requirement that the National Lottery be operated by a single purpose company. It is possible that the government could relax this restriction in order to encourage bidding competition in future licence competitions. This would, however, blur the distinction between the National Lottery and harder forms of commercial gambling in the public eye. In addition, Camelot would be placed at a disadvantage relative to commercial gambling firms unless it was allowed to diversify beyond the National Lottery.

Government policy and the effects of competition

6. The Government has made it plain that the promotion of effective competition is one of its key policy goals. Competition is recognised to be a powerful mechanism for delivering consumer benefits, in terms of lower prices, higher quality and innovation.[176]

7. So far as the National Lottery is concerned, the multiple licence model may appear to offer a way of pursuing this policy goal by adding competition "within the market" (between Lottery operators, for customers) to competition "for the market" (between bidders for one or more licences to run the Lottery itself). The NLC could encourage competition "in the market" by using tendering processes that make it difficult for a single firm to win all the licences, or by reserving one or more licences for a new entrant. By making it easier for entrants and/or small bidders, the multiple licence model is seen by some of its advocates as a way of also increasing competition "for the market".

8. There a number of problems with this argument. First, the conventional consumer-based rationale for promoting competition is not directly applicable to the National Lottery. This is because the primary purpose of policy with respect to the Lottery is to raise funds for good causes, rather than to maximise the consumer benefits enjoyed by those who play the Lottery, in terms of lower prices or higher payouts. Competition should therefore be seen as an objective only in so far as it protects or enhances these funds.

9. Second, as explained below, competition "in the market" may actually reduce the money available for good causes, absent any increase in bidding competition.

10. Finally, it is questionable whether the multiple licence model would in fact increase competition "for the market" (e.g. by increasing the number of bidders) by enough to compensate for the negative impact of competition "in the market", or indeed whether it would lead to any significant increase in competition for licences at all.

Key conclusions

11. We have reached five key conclusions as follows.

Multiple licence holders competing "within the market" could reduce funds for good causes.

12. The funds available to good causes depend upon the economic value of the Lottery (defined as the net value of Lottery sales less costs) and its distribution between licensees and good causes. Allowing a number of operators to run different parts of the Lottery could result in lower net Lottery sales revenue, and higher costs, compared with those achieved by a single operator, resulting in a reduction in the economic value of the Lottery. This is because a single operator has both the incentive and the ability to develop the Lottery more efficiently than multiple operators.

13. There are a number of specific ways in which the economic value of the Lottery could be undermined with multiple competing operators:

  • licensees may develop products that cannibalise rivals' sales rather than expand the market;

  • product launches may be undermined by a lack of co-ordination between licensees;

  • free-riding by some operators may result in under-investment, notably in the Lottery brand and infrastructure; and

  • there may be a loss of economies of scale and scope that cannot be effectively remedied by access agreements and the sharing of infrastructure, which would increase total operating costs.

14. The NLC's role would change radically in the multiple licence model in terms of both scale and complexity. In particular, the NLC would be required to intervene in key areas such as product development, marketing and brand management in order to reconcile operators' competing interests and ensure the efficient development of the Lottery. This would be a very challenging regulatory role, and it is doubtful that the NLC currently has the commercial and technical expertise that would be needed to fulfil this role. Moreover, the increased level of regulatory intervention in the multiple licence model would be costly in itself, and could stifle product innovation, particularly if operators seek to use the regulatory process to inhibit product development by rivals.

The multiple licence model would only increase funds for good causes if competition "for the market" were increased significantly.

15. Since the economic value of the Lottery is likely to be lower in the multiple licence model than in the single licence model, the multiple licence model would generate more money for good causes only if the share of the economic value of the Lottery that goes to good increases by enough to offset the fall in the economic value of the Lottery. This would be the case only if the multiple licence model leads to a significant increase in competition "for the market" in the form of stronger bidding for licences.

Moving from a single to a multiple licence model might not increase competition "for the market"

16. To assess the impact of changing to the multiple licence model on bidding competition for licences, it is necessary to assess the degree of competition that is likely under the single licence model. It is far from clear that there will be an absence of competition for the third licence. The changes made to the conditions of the second Lottery licence (such as asset and intellectual property ownership) should significantly reduce or remove any incumbency advantage enjoyed by Camelot. Moreover, it does not appear that Camelot has any significant brand advantage, exclusive contracts or relationships, or any proprietary technological knowledge that would inhibit competition. A further important factor is that the Lottery will be more mature and hence easier to value in 2009 than at previous bidding rounds

17. It is also unclear that the multiple licence model would in fact lead to stronger bidding competition. This is because bidders would face a significantly more complex and uncertain strategic environment when developing their business plans and preparing bids. For example, bidders would have to take into account the potential impact of market competition in the event that there are multiple operators. This will depend on the eventual outcome of the licence award process, and also on whether the NLC decides to issue additional licences sequentially. The increased market and regulatory risk, combined with the likely increase in the cost and complexity of bidding may deter some bidders, thus decreasing rather than increasing bidding competition.

18. It might be argued that the multiple licence model, by allowing for "bite-sized" licences could attract small bidders who would be unwilling to bid for the entire Lottery. This is not necessarily the case. For example, it is possible that a firm bidding for all (or most) of the licences would be able to take advantage of synergies between the licences and outbid small competitors bidding for single licences. In this case, small bidders could be deterred by this "large operator" advantage and may rationally decide not to enter the competition in the first place. The NLC could guard against this by reserving licences for entrants or small bidders, but this would run the risk of imposing an inefficient outcome to the detriment of the development of the Lottery and the good causes.

Competition "for the market" can be increased within the single licence model

19. There are a number of ways in which the bidding process for a single licence could be modified, in order to encourage competition against the incumbent. For example:

  • gambling and gaming firms could be allowed to operate the Lottery through a subsidiary (although as noted earlier this could affect the National Lottery brand, and also place Camelot at a disadvantage unless it is permitted to diversify beyond the National Lottery);

  • the Lottery operator could be permitted to select different suppliers during the course of the licence;

  • bidding costs could be underwritten; and/or

  • the incumbent could be required to submit a final binding bid before others are asked to bid.

A reserve price based on the incumbent's historic performance could also be incorporated to protect against the risk of weak competition.

20. The evaluation of these and many other techniques, familiar in the fields of economic regulation and auction theory, is outside the scope of this study. At this stage it suffices to note that there are a number of possible ways in which the single licence model could be modified to provide a more efficient and less risky way of increasing the money available to good causes than moving to the multiple licence model.

Offering multiple licences would be a complex option with significant risks and no clear benefits to good causes.

21. We therefore conclude that the multiple licence model is complex and risky, and that it could lead to a significantly worse outcome for good causes. As explained above, the multiple licence model could result in competition between operators and a significant increase in regulation, both of which could undermine the development of the Lottery to the detriment of good causes. For this reason, we think that the multiple licence model is only likely to increase the money for good causes if it leads to stronger bidding competition than the single licence model. On the evidence we have seen, we think that there are good reasons to doubt that this would be the case.

Recommendations

22. We recommend that the Government should consider the following issues before the next licence is awarded.

  • First, the government should undertake a rigorous assessment of the risk of weak bidding for a third single licence in 2009. This will require a careful analysis of the size and competitive impact of any incumbency advantage enjoyed by Camelot (along the lines well-established by UK competition authorities), taking into account the conditions in the Second Licence, the range of potential bidders, and the maturity of the Lottery market.

  • Second, if this assessment indicates that there is a risk that competition for a single third licence would be weak, the government should assess the alternative options that could be used to negate any residual incumbency advantage and encourage competition within the single licence model.

  • Third, the government should consider whether the contribution to good causes in the single licence model could be increased by modifying the shape of the retention schedule. This influences the marginal incentives to grow Lottery sales, and it may be better (for good causes) to move from the current declining schedule to a flatter or upward sloping schedule in future.

  • Fourth, if the Government decides to proceed with the multiple licence model it should take steps to mitigate the risk to good causes. For example, the government should:

    • ensure that the bidding process permits a single operator to win all licences. In this way a multiple licensing approach would not rule out the possibility that the Lottery could continue to be operated by a single operator, if this is the most efficient approach; and

    • ensure that licences are designed so that competition between different operators would be limited, and economies of scale and scope are preserved.

  • Fifth, the Government should recognise that moving to the multiple licence model would require the NLC to intervene in complex commercial and strategic aspects of the Lottery, as well as to adjudicate on access pricing and allocating risk and investment between licence holders. This would be a very significant increase in the scale and complexity of the NLC's remit, and it will be important to ensure that NLC is properly resourced to meet this challenge effectively.



175   Foreword to DCMS Decision Document (July 2003). Back

176   See, for example, the OFT guidelines ( February 2002). Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 25 March 2004