Select Committee on Culture, Media and Sport Written Evidence


23.  Supplementary Memorandum submitted by the National Lottery Commission

NOTE ON THE RISKS AND BENEFITS ASSOCIATED WITH A POWER TO GRANT MULTIPLE LICENCES TO OPERATE THE NATIONAL LOTTERY

PURPOSE OF THIS NOTE

  1.  Recent evidence given to the Culture, Media and Sport Select Committee (the CMS Committee) by Camelot emphasised the risks associated with the Government's proposal to empower the National Lottery Commission (NLC) to grant more than one licence to operate the National Lottery. The NLC first saw the submissions when they were copied to the NLC by the Committee on 14 January 2004. This note sets out the NLC's views on the arguments put forward against the Government's proposal.

THE NATURE OF THE PROPOSAL

  2.  The NLC's starting point is that an effective competition for a third licence to operate the National Lottery is likely to be very difficult to generate under the present arrangements. This view is based on both experience and views expressed by potential bidders (see paragraphs 9-11 below).

  3.  The Department of Culture, Media and Sport (DCMS) consulted on four options for change in June 2002. The Government proposes to give the NLC the power to grant more than one licence to operate the National Lottery if it considers this appropriate. The present arrangement for an operator's licence and separate licences to promote games would be replaced by "full capacity" licences. This would remove the limitation under present legislation that only one operating licence can be granted. It would also do away with the requirement for individual game licences, although it is likely that approvals would have to be given before new games could be launched.

  4.  The key features of these proposals, from the NLC's perspective, are that:

    —  it has greater flexibility to structure the next competition in a way that it judges likely to make that competition as effective as possible. This does not preclude the NLC offering a single licence if it considers this to be the best option, based on conditions at the time. Nor does it prevent applicants bidding for all licences if more than one licence is offered;

    —  a more flexible structure offers the opportunity to generate greater competition for licences, so ensuring that the good causes receive a high proportion of the value of each ticket sold. It also offers the opportunity to encourage greater innovation and specialisation than may be offered under a single operator model, bringing the potential for greater growth to the portfolio;

    —  it will be able to consult widely and carry out research in order to assess what licence structure is most likely to generate effective competition for the relevant licence(s) and encourage innovation, whilst minimising harmful competition between licensees during the course of those licences; and

    —  the introduction of "full-capacity" licences will allow the NLC to specify a clearly defined role for each licensee within the National Lottery as a whole. This will give each licensee greater freedom to manage their part of the overall portfolio and should help limit the degree of competition between operators.

FLEXIBILITY AND TIMING OF DETAILED RESEARCH

  5.  The Government's proposals have been criticised on the basis that detailed research has not yet been undertaken to demonstrate how they will operate. To the extent that critics ascribe a pre-determined view of the structure of the next competition to the NLC, this is misguided. The NLC has made clear that it has not taken such a view.

  6.  Early legislation giving greater flexibility is essential if that flexibility is to be utilised in the next competition. The NLC cannot dedicate resources to research and consultation on powers which have not been given to it by Parliament. It therefore cannot carry out the detailed design work critics say is essential before Parliament grants it wider powers.

  7.  More fundamentally, the NLC believes that now is not the right time to reach firm conclusions on the structure of the next licence competition. The extent of the response to the DCMS consultation, and the NLC's own informal contacts, suggest that potential bidders have yet to turn their minds to the next competition. They will look, as must the NLC, at the state of the market and technology closer to the time of the competition. It is then that the NLC will be able to engage with potential bidders and to assess the likelihood of competition and the licence structure most likely to encourage it. To take a final view now, two years into the current licence, risks adoption of a scheme which may prove inappropriate at the time of the next competition.

  8.  If a mandatory scheme in primary legislation, based on prior research and consultation undertaken at the present time, were to be adopted, there is a risk that it would not obtain Royal Assent in time for it to be used effectively for the next competition. The legislation might also prescribe a scheme which would be appropriate for the next competition but inappropriate for following competitions. The implication that Parliament should legislate on the scheme for competition before each competition takes place removes much of the benefit of an independent and experienced regulator. Rather, the regulator should be given the flexibility to make a considered judgement at the appropriate time.

LIKELIHOOD OF COMPETITION IF NO CHANGE IS MADE

  9.  The NLC believes that the present legislative requirements greatly reduce the likelihood of competition for the third licence. This view has not been reached without seeking the views of others.

  10.  During the preparation of the competition for the last licence, the Commission made contact with as many potential bidders as it could. It actively sought views from bidders involved in the first competition. Whilst some pointed to issues of intellectual property and access to retailer data (which have been addressed in the second licence), concerns were far more wide ranging. These included:

    —  nature of the undertaking: running the National Lottery is a large and specialist undertaking. Some potential bidders identified that it did not sit well with their core business; others that it was so large that, although their core business was in a similar field, it would unbalance their business and distract management attention;

    —  likely returns: these were not considered particularly attractive when the costs of bidding, risks of handover and pressures of public scrutiny were taken into account;

    —  opportunity costs of bidding: some potential bidders emphasised the effort required and diversion of focus from other opportunities and from their core business as reasons for not bidding. Others had the skills to cope with bidding complexity (which was seen as similar to PFI deals) but were discouraged by the lack of opportunity to make use of their investment if unsuccessful. A PFI team can generally bid for a number of PFI deals. The Lottery is only competed for every seven years.

    —  reputational risks: potential bidders were concerned about the risks associated with handover from the existing operator and the significant impact that an unsuccessful handover might have on their reputations. Part of their concern related to information flows. But they were also concerned about the incumbent's preparedness and ability to manage the handover, especially if, for example, key staff left before the licence ended;

    —  limited number of gaming system suppliers: this was seen as a significant constraint.

  11.  It is very difficult to identify and engage with potential bidders so far from the next competition. But the limited contact the NLC has so far had has not reassured it that the changes made in the second licence are sufficient to deliver a strong competition for the third licence without legislative change. Indeed, the NLC notes that the CMS Committee, the National Audit Office (NAO) and the Public Accounts Committee have all expressed similar views, and that the People's Lottery made clear in its evidence to the CMS Committee that it did not expect the present arrangements to generate competition for a third licence.

FUTURE DEVELOPMENTS IN THE LOTTERY MARKET

  12.  Much of the criticism of the Government's proposals is based on the likelihood of competition between multiple operators to launch new games, the damaging effects this will have and the need for the NLC to take on the operator's role in managing such launches. This is based on three assumptions, each of which is uncertain.

A continued proliferation of games

  13.  The present operator is focused on a strategy of diversification, whereby new games are introduced to offset the decline of existing games. The NLC does not believe that this strategy is viable indefinitely. Player demand for an ever widening portfolio of games has not been established. It seems more likely that the National Lottery will, in time, reach the point where returns from new games will no longer justify the cost and effort required to introduce them. Whilst some new, innovative opportunities will be identified, these will be comparatively rare. Operator(s) will focus much more on refreshment of existing games, and replacement of underperforming games with redesigned versions, which would fall within their "full capacity" licences. The present operator has already indicated that its plans for the year following the introduction of EuroMillions are to focus on new distribution channels rather than new launches, in part in order to allow the existing portfolio to "settle".

  14.  The timing at which this point might be reached is unclear, but may well occur in the second licence period given the present operator's longer term commitment to an aggressive schedule of game introductions. The NLC would expect to assess the position closer to the next competition and to design the next competition in a manner which best reflects the state of the market.

Competition between games

  15.  Critics also appear to assume that all games compete for similar players and that this will encourage competition between operators. The NLC accepts that some games cannibalise others significantly (and that this may reduce the incentive for licensees to take into account cannibalisation where it impacts upon other licensees), but notes that the degree of cannibalisation is not necessarily uniform or high across the portfolio. For example, work carried out for both the NLC and the operator by third-party consultants has concluded that there is very little cannibalisation between scratchcards and draw-based games. Again, further work will be required closer to the next competition, but the NLC has already indicated that it will seek to minimise the risks in this area by letting at most a small number of licences, packaged to keep games which substitute for one another (especially jackpot games) within the control of a single licensee.

Technological limitations

  16.  Criticism is also based around technological constraints. The assumption is that technology (especially Lottery software) can only be updated on a very limited number of occasions a year. This will cause competition between licensees for their updates to be given priority. It is also assumed that economic and security considerations point to the need for a single gaming system.

  17.  The NLC doubts that these constraints will be significant by the time of the next competition. The present operator runs its main games on a software platform which was current at the time of the first licence (1994). The NLC's own experience from discussion with lottery software suppliers suggests that current systems are written to open standards and are modular in format. This greatly eases development, reduces constraints on introduction of updates and allows different systems to interface much more straightforwardly. Modern terminal design also allows much greater flexibility. The NLC anticipates that the next licence will see the introduction of such systems regardless of the basis of competition, but would expect to assess fully technological developments and take these into account in the design of the third competition, to the benefit of the good causes.

THE FRONTIER ECONOMICS REPORT

  18.  The NLC believes that the report would have been better informed if it was based on a wider range of views. It appears to be based predominantly on information provided by the present operator. No approach was made to the NLC or, it appears, to DCMS or to other potential participants in the next competition. Nonetheless, it provides a starting point for further consideration of the issues.

  19.  The NLC has the following comments to make on the recommendations reached by Frontier Economics.

Undertake a rigorous assessment of risk of weak bidding for the third licence

  20.  The NLC agrees that this needs doing. It has emphasised the need for extensive consultation before the competition for the third licence term is designed and would welcome views from potential bidders at as early a stage as possible. However, the NLC believes that it would be premature to undertake a final assessment now. Market conditions and technological developments change and, without an understanding of these, potential bidders may not be able to take a clear view whether they would wish to bid. In addition, potential bidders are likely to see the next competition as a distant event and so will have given it little thought. Whilst early conversations would be helpful, taking a firm view based on consultation at the present time is likely to give undue emphasis to the views of the current operator and its suppliers.

  21.  The NLC would expect to undertake the necessary economic analysis as soon as it has the power to do so (that is, once the Bill has received Royal Assent or, possibly, its second reading in the House of Commons) and to commence consultation soon afterwards.

Consider alternative options to multiple licences to simulate bids

  22.  The NLC agrees this work should be done, but would emphasise that it has already explored a range of options within the present legislative framework. These inevitably focussed on how the process is structured rather than the content of the licence offered. The NAO considered these in its review of the award of the second licence and concluded that, even with these in place, there remained a significant risk that there would be no competition for the third licence. On the evidence presently available, the NLC is of a similar view. We also note that the consultation undertaken by DCMS offered interested parties the opportunity to make suggestions, and that these were taken account of by the Government in its development of the proposed reforms.

  23.  The NLC has also sought to explore possible arrangements for the handover of assets, in particular key contracts for a limited period, from the incumbent to a future operator. This would help address concerns about handover arrangements. Implementation of such changes is dependent on the agreement of Camelot and its key suppliers. The NLC asked Camelot to open discussions on how this might be achieved in July 2003. Camelot is presently considering this request.

  24.  Camelot and Frontier Economics hint at other alternatives. It is difficult to assess these when so little detail is provided, but the NLC would comment as follows:

    —  oblige the operator to make best use of competitive tendering and procurement arrangements / permit the operator to select different suppliers during the course of the licence: the last competition expressly asked bidders how they would make use of such arrangements. The present operator is free to use competitive tendering and has done so, for example in selection of its advertising consultants. But under the present licence structure, benefits flow to the operator alone unless the savings trigger a secondary contribution (where profits exceed those forecast in its bid). The NLC considered whether to put different arrangements in place, but considered that these could lead to an over-complicated structure where it became involved in specifying tenders and selecting the preferred supplier, as the NLDF would have a financial interest in the outcome;

    —  allow gambling and gaming firms to compete: both competition processes to date have permitted this, so long as involvement was through a single purpose vehicle. Organisations such as Rank and Littlewoods have either bid or considered bidding;

    —  underwrite bidding costs: this is under consideration and was discussed in the NAO report, but is not considered sufficient to offset other disincentives to bid (see paragraph 10) and carries its own risks;

    —  require the incumbent to submit a final binding bid before others are asked to bid: it is hard to see how this would work, or what benefits it would bring, without further detail.

Modify retention arrangement

  25.  The present retention arrangements are those contained in the present operator's bid. It is not clear to the NLC why the change which Frontier Economics suggests would affect the level of returns to good causes favourably. It is arguable that the greater incentives should be contained earlier in the licence period, both to allow the licensee to recover its capital costs and also to secure the benefits of game introduction early in the licence period, so that returns flow throughout the licence rather than only for the later years.

Mitigate the risks of multiple licences

  26.  The NLC agrees that the design of the next competition should seek to mitigate risks, but emphasises that these include the risks of no competition associated with a single licence model. It has made clear it intends to achieve this through careful design of the next competition, following thorough research and wide consultation prior to finalising the design of the competition (see paragraph 7).

Ensure the NLC is properly resourced to address risks if a multiple licence model is adopted

  27.  The risks depend on the degree of complexity introduced, including the number of licences, the degree to which they can be structured to minimise competition between licensees and the availability of co-operation provisions within licences which are enforceable.

  28.  The NLC believes the Government has the ability, through the proposed changes to its constitution (permanent chairman, flexibility of numbers, executive commissioners), to bring new expertise to the Commission and, through oversight of its budget, to ensure that it is properly resourced.

  29.  The NLC is also clear that its role would change significantly if the present single licence model were retained and did not generate any significant competition for the third licence. In such a case, it would probably need to move towards the models adopted by utilities regulators when overseeing monopoly providers in order to control the operator's profits and so maximise returns to good causes.

CAMELOT'S SUBMISSION

  30.  Camelot identifies a number of specific risks which it believes will lead to an over-complex solution which will inevitably lead to a reduction in returns to good causes. The NLC offers the following comments on Camelot's arguments.

Game plan

  31.  Camelot assumes that portfolio growth will be the key element of the game strategy in the third licence, and that all games represent substitutes for each other. The weaknesses in these assumptions are highlighted in paragraphs 13-14. Also implicit in the argument is that the skills and expertise needed to develop all elements of the lottery portfolio are similar. This is not necessarily the case. The expertise required to manage a draw-based portfolio is not the same as that required for the management and distribution of a physical product like scratchcards.

Marketing and brand management

  32.  This argument repeats that put forward on game plans; that licensees will compete between themselves through marketing arrangements for each others' players. The same weaknesses in these assumptions apply. As the NLC has indicated, it would maintain the existing overarching brand (which it owns) with game brands beneath it. This is consistent with Camelot's submission, which suggests that it presently sees different games as different brands within an overarching framework.

Jackpots

  33.  The NLC has consistently recognised the need to maintain the natural monopoly that jackpot games require and indicated its intention to design licences accordingly. However, it would note that even under a single operator, more than one jackpot game may be operated (eg twice weekly Lotto draws, Lotto Extra and EuroMillions are all designed to be jackpot games), and the need to refresh these products effectively is important.

Interactive strategy

  34.  If Camelot is correct that interactive channels simply represent a different medium by which existing games may be offered, then the NLC agrees that it is unlikely to make sense to group these within a separate licence. However, interactive channels are still in their infancy and their future is difficult to predict. Both bidders, at the time of the last licence competition, saw these new media as a means to offer innovative new products and other lotteries are exploring such options. If it became clear that such new products could be generated successfully, then a separate licence for such products might be an option worth considering.

Retailers

  35.  The NLC accepts that retailers have significant concerns about the impact of multiple licensees, but it does not see any reason why these could not be met. It anticipates that it will be possible for licensees to share, at the least, use of a common terminal and local connection. This will address concerns about multiple terminals. More modern terminals and supporting systems may also provide gains to retailers, amongst others. The NLC would expect to consult widely with retailers before making any final decisions on the third licence structure.

IT

  36.  The NLC sees no reason to suppose that lottery IT systems must be placed in their entirety under the control of a single operator. The banking sector provides an example of how different operators may provide secure interfaces between their systems to allow customers access to services through a variety of operators. The utilities sector provides clear examples of successful "common carrier" models. As explained at paragraph 17, technological moves to modular systems architecture written to open standards should allow each licensee to manage their own gaming systems, using the modules relevant to their business, with secure interfaces between operators where necessary.

Support services

  37.  The NLC believes that a model based on co-operation is possible, and that it is quite feasible to generate economic and licence incentives to operators to participate in such arrangements. In this way, the supervision required by the regulator in this respect may not be substantially greater than that required under the present single licence arrangement.

Role of the regulator

  38.  Given the points made above, the NLC does not accept the argument that it is inevitable that the regulator will become the de facto operator. The NLC rejected the option of a state operated lottery in its original submission to DCMS and has taken the view that, whilst the regulator's role will change, it should aim to minimise the degree to which the regulator controls licensees' commercial decision making.

CONCLUSION

  39.  The NLC believes it is essential to take a balanced view of the risks and benefits associated both with the Government's proposals and with making no change to the present licensing framework. It is not clear that all the risks identified by Camelot will materialise, or that they are all of similar consequence. The ability to mitigate those risks is not assessed. More fundamentally, the risks of change are not balanced against the likelihood of, and risks associated with, the potential lack of effective competition under the existing arrangements. The NLC believes that the flexibility in the Government's proposals will allow it to take that balanced view, at the appropriate time and based on research and consultation, when designing the next competition.

28 January 2004





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 25 March 2004