Select Committee on Education and Skills Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witness (Questions 20-39)

14 JANUARY 2004

RT HON CHARLES CLARKE MP

  Q20 Mr Chaytor: Secretary of State, do you think that reducing the fee for a physics degree to zero is an effective way of increasing recruitment of physics degrees?

  Mr Clarke: I would not say it is an effective way. It could be a way of doing it and I think some universities will do it. What do I think of the ways of increasing recruitment to physics? First and foremost there has to be an improvement of science education in schools and the approach we have taken in those areas, for example through the science specialist schools and developing better partnerships between the schools system and industry in this case using physics in a positive way, and it is raising the excitement students feel in physics. Secondly, in terms of motivating and incentivising universities, it has to be to encourage through the HEFCE funding regime proper support for undergraduate teaching in physics so that universities which opt to provide physics courses do deal with that in a way that gets properly funded and resourced. Thirdly, we have to establish at a research level the relationship between high quality research and physics, and schools and undergraduate education is very important. I mentioned I had a meeting with PPARC, part of the Physics Research Council, just before Christmas talking about ways in which their fundamental research could tie in with what schools are doing, because I happen to think that the work that is done on space is exciting and motivating for students thinking of coming into those areas, so that whole range of issues is important. But then the issue comes what does a university do when it sees the possibility of having to close the physics course because, despite what I have said, there are not enough applications? It happened in my own university, the University of East Anglia, about four years ago that a physics course was closed which was extremely unfortunate and everybody regretted it but, simply, the number of applications was not coming through. It might well be in those circumstances that the university might feel that to reduce the fee for students going on to those courses might encourage more students on to those courses and enable them to keep going rather than be closed as a result of still getting the HEFCE funding stream that comes through, but I would say the university should be free to do that if it wished to do so in order to deal with it, and that is an argument for variability in my view. Do I think it should be the central strategy? No. I think it should be those other things I talked about, but just to have a fixed fee which did not allow that variability would weaken a university's ability to try and deal with these situations.

  Q21 Mr Chaytor: So are really saying that in terms of the relationship between the level of student support and widening participation and access, the precise financial arrangements for student support are not the main factor?

  Mr Clarke: That is my view; others do not agree. But I go back to my reading last year when I read The Times Guide and the Virgin Guide to British Universities and a good read it was, because you go through for each university a great list of issues, including the quality of the beer and all the rest of it to encourage people to go to particular universities. There is a great deal of information, including likely career destinations, how well you do at getting jobs and so on and so forth, which is in those guides today, and I say to put a bit of extra information in which is about the fee for the course is a consideration—but it is a consideration, not the consideration. Some colleagues argue it is the consideration; I simply do not think that is the case.

  Q22 Mr Chaytor: If you had to choose between the question of the fee for the course as the determinant of access and the school to which a young person was admitted at the age of 11 as a determinant of their chances of going to university, which is the most important?

  Mr Clarke: A school. There is no question about it, I would say, and I would say that is why our whole strategy is about achieving but, as I said earlier in answer to Mr Sheerman, 20% of our university courses are studied through further education and there is a whole string of means of access to university education which are not dependent on the school, and I announced last Thursday our intention to take further and stronger steps if we can achieve it on part-time and mature student entrance to universities precisely to reflect that fact. So I do not think it is just about school but if I was asked to pick one single measure I would have to say it would be the quality of schools which would be important.

  Q23 Mr Chaytor: In respect of variability, have you any concerns at all about a variable fee regime being a deterrent to applicants to university and, if so, is that based on evidence of variable fee regimes elsewhere, either in the United Kingdom or abroad, or is it based on general perception?

  Mr Clarke: No. The evidence from abroad is that the experience of variable fees does not deter and can, in fact, increase access. I met last week because we had a seminar at the BETT conference at Olympia education ministers of other countries, the Canadian Minister of Education, the Federal Minister, and he was very impressed with the package we were putting forward which he thought put it on to a proper basis, but in the areas, for example, in Ontario where they have made progress in these areas, it is the case that the variability is enhanced access rather than reduced. I do have a fear, and I have had it throughout and I said to it the Committee before and I will say it again, that there is a perception of debt in these areas which remains an issue, and I regard it as my responsibility after this  Bill has Royal Assent to have a major communication to potential students to explain what the proposals are, because the greatest single problem we have is that most people in the country do not understood well enough even how the current system operates, let alone how the new system would operate, and it was a major obligation on my department to try and make sure people understand clearly what it is. In short I do not think it is a point of substance about what the system is which is the determinant, but the sub-issue of perception about what it might be.

  Q24 Mr Chaytor: Pursuing the question, what is the difference between a fee regime in which the state legislates to allow vice-chancellors to fix any fee they like between zero and £3,000 for any given course and a regime in which the state fixes a maximum fee and then legislates to allow vice-chancellors to produce variability by simply discounting the fee?

  Mr Clarke: I think this is a words game. To talk about a fixed fee with discounts is very different, certainly in intellectual terms, from talking about a variable fee regime. They are identical. You could argue, I suppose, that you could go below zero in some type of variability and that should pay people to go on certain courses and so on, and that might be an answer to the physics question that you were talking about, but assuming you have a floor of zero in a situation I see no distinction between them.

  Q25 Mr Chaytor: Would it not have been easier for the government to say the maximum fee will be £3,000 and then divert the responsibility and the flak to the vice-chancellors for their discounting policy?

  Mr Clarke: That is precisely what our Bill proposes to do and perhaps some vice-chancellors do not want that responsibility. I think that responsibility should be exercised by universities but some colleagues, for entirely genuine reasons, fear giving universities that right.

  Q26 Chairman: This Select Committee a long time ago, or it seems a long time ago, Secretary of State, said to you that we thought most universities would charge the full £3,000 for most courses. Would it not have given you a much easier life if you had just accepted that and encouraged them to do so?

  Mr Clarke: Well, I suppose you would say, and you have said it in the House before, Mr Sheerman, that my life would be at its easiest if I accepted all Select Committee recommendations, and maybe I should—

  Q27 Chairman: That was not a recommendation!

  Mr Clarke: Thank you. It might have given me an easier life but I do not think it would because I think that the current £1,125 going up by 2006 to £1,200 flat fee which exists at the moment is just about low enough for some of the contradictions of this not to become sharp and acute. If you start talking about a higher fixed fee—some suggested £2,500, some £2,000 or whatever—then the lack of flexibility inherent in such a system, in my opinion, becomes very acute indeed and if you simply said for the sake of argument £2,500 for every course in every style that happened, then the vice-chancellors say to me, "What do we do about the sandwich courses? What do we do about trying to encourage people on the physics course?"—and my example of that is a real discussion with a real Russell Group vice-chancellor—"What do we say about the students spending a year abroad as part of their foreign languages courses? Are we to be required to charge them during that year abroad at that same fee level? What do we say about the foundation degree we are trying to build with some local employer or business or whatever, and they say they can do it if we charge £1,200 but not if we have to charge £2,500 or whatever?", and those difficulties would have made my life very miserable whereas with the Bill that I have published now, when it is agreed with one bound I will be free and the problems will be those elsewhere throughout the system!

  Q28 Mr Chaytor: Secretary of State, you said that the level of public funding per student will continue at the same level after the variable fee regime comes in. Can you reaffirm that now?

  Mr Clarke: Yes, I can. We have said that.

  Q29 Mr Chaytor: But how can you guarantee that beyond the next election?

  Mr Clarke: I have said that is the policy of this government and it is carrying it through but it is certainly true following the questions raised by Mr Jackson that if a Conservative government was elected under the next election I cannot see how that could be fulfilled. I can say for this government that it is our intention to do that and that is what we said in the White Paper.

  Q30 Mr Chaytor: Is that for the next CSR period, or throughout the next Parliament?

  Mr Clarke: We are talking about the next CSR period but this whole process will go into the future, and the commitment of this government to maintain funding and extend it is absolute.

  Q31 Mr Pollard: I have three distinct questions, Secretary of State: what is the ratio of graduate financial input to what the government will be putting in?

  Mr Clarke: It is about 1:14 at the moment. There are interesting issues about what it is legitimate to contain within that estimate and to what extent you consider research and teaching, and it is the case that the cost of different courses varies very substantially, so the relationship of any fee to the cost of providing a particular course will vary very significantly, which was one of the points I was putting in answer to Mr Chaytor about the HEFCE funding systems that move through. There is not an easy answer but the global answer is about 14, and the language I have always used is that the lion's share of university spending will continue to be met, and in my opinion should continue to be met, by the State.

  Q32 Mr Pollard: Following on from that, the government has raised the threshold at which payments start back from £10-15,000 which is very welcome, and many of us argue that it should be even higher than that. Have thoughts ever been given to London weighting? For example, costs across the board, housing and everything else, are much higher in London and your £15,000 will buy much less than in the other parts of the country?

  Mr Clarke: We are ready to look at that through the Committee stages of the Bill and so on, but I would not want to sound too optimistic. I know from St Albans, and I have other colleagues from other seats around London and in London, that it is an attractive option but the fact is that every £1,000 you raise the threshold by is an expensive operation—I do not have the figure to hand—and we made an assessment about whether it would be better to raise the threshold to £15,000 in terms of repayment or raise the student grant at the beginning, and the view we came to was that we got more result in terms of our excess ambitions by raising student grant at the outset than by raising the threshold and therefore slowing the repayment rate at the end. We consider we are making a pretty big difference by raising the threshold from £10-15,000 including for current students, and we thought it was more important to make progress on the grant front with the resources we had available than by increasing the threshold. I would just say that for London, though this would not necessarily help your constituents directly, the biggest impact of our decision to increase the median rate of maintenance loan for students is upon students living in London, because the difference between what it costs to live as a student and the maintenance loan you receive for that is greatest in London according to the statistics we so far have.

  Q33 Mr Pollard: One of the main thrusts of what government has tried to do is increase the number of working class students who get to university, and in Australia there has been a system similar to ours in place for many years. The evidence there is that the working class students have neither increased nor decreased. Now that says that those who worry about it will stop working class students—clearly it flies in the face of that but it does not encourage us to assume that more working class students will go along. Are there any other countries where it is contrary evidence?

  Mr Clarke: That is the fundamental reason, Mr Pollard, why we think the Office of Fair Access is an important development. We have had the system for many years in this country for a different student support without a tangible impact on the class basis of what is happening. We think our proposals with the student grant regime we are establishing, the total £3,000 package, does give us a real chance of making a difference there and, of course, we are committed to doing it, but all the evidence is, though there is not any serious discrimination between applications and admissions by universities, there is a serious differential across those who apply to   different universities from working class backgrounds, and that is why we think the Office of Fair Access is an important vehicle to reinforce that. I was massively encouraged by the decision of Cambridge University which they announced before Christmas to put a bursary of £4,000 which, let us recall, is on top of the £1,500 grant and the £1,200 fee omission we are talking about, so a total of the order of £6,700 for a student going to Cambridge from a very poor family. I think that is a pretty significant financial incentive. Now, of course, not all universities will be able to achieve that, though I do know at least one of the major universities of that group which is intending to announce similar proposals in the next few weeks and months, but I think that kind of development stimulated by this Bill and by OFFA and its approach is the way to attack these problems.

  Q34 Paul Holmes: Is the £3,000 cap on variable fees to last for three or four or five years depending on the next Parliament?

  Mr Clarke: It lasts indefinitely. Would it be helpful if I gave my understanding of where we are on the length of the cap? What I have said is that the £3,000 in real terms would be a cap on all fees at universities. I have said that, as far as the Labour Party is concerned, that will be a position that continues until the end of the next Parliament, come what may. Other parties may have different views on this. I have said as far as the process of change is concerned, and I think this would run across parties, that we will have a review of how the first three years of variable fees has worked, because there are colleagues of mine—and I know there are many Liberal Democrats who share this concern—who are worried that the effect of variability would not be beneficial, and so I have suggested that we have a review which reviews how it has gone and what has happened, so if some of the fears of those who are worried are seen then that can be adjusted. I have said that no change in fee should be agreed other than on the basis of a recommendation from that independent commission to Parliament, so there would be that process and a recommendation would be made to Parliament in those circumstances. Then I have said that the commitment I have given for this   government is that any decision on that recommendation would be taken through secondary legislation as in this Bill but by a full vote of the whole House and not sitting on the committee corridor with every member enabled to take a view on what it should be, so there is a kind of double lock before you get to a position of an increase in the cap, firstly that it would need to come as a result of the recommendation of this independent review and, secondly, that it would have to be voted on by all members of the House. Now, I think that is quite a significant double lock in the situation and I know there are some members who are exercised about the possibility of universities coming along and saying, "Let's go for £15,000 fees or £10,000 fees" or whatever, and people are genuinely worried about that, but I am saying that the process I have set in place offers, in my opinion, guarantees which make it very difficult for that to happen in the way some people fear.

  Q35 Paul Holmes: The thin end of the wedge argument, as you will guess from the question I asked you last Thursday in Parliament, is exactly the point I want to go on to: if the cap is only there indefinitely until 2010, let us say, the end of the next parliamentary term, and then it will be reviewed, once the principle of variable fees in a market has been conceded there is obviously going to be a huge pressure to raise that cap considerably. Universities UK has said £3,000 is too little too late; various vice-chancellors—Oxford, Imperial College, LSE—have told us about £10,000, £15,000, £20,000 at various times, and lots of academics have talked about those sorts of figures, so once the principle of variability in the market place has been conceded what is to stop, after 2010, fees going to those sorts of levels?

  Mr Clarke: Let me make it clear that the principle of variability in the market place has already been conceded. We have variability for part-time student fees, for post-graduate fees and for overseas student fees, so there is variability but not for some classes of course at the moment. I do not think there is a principle position for university education against variability. There is a practical position based on what has been and how things have operated, and I think it is right that we should, if there is to be a change which I think there should be, examine what its meaning is and, Mr Sheerman, there has been speculation and your Committee has heard from various sources about what fees would be charged at what levels, and it is the kind of thing this Committee would want to look at as any system went through, as it rightly should. I do not know what is going to be charged but I think we should make a judgment based on what has happened. I know there is a thin end of the wedge argument. I could argue that today a fee of £150,000 a year could be charged to a post-graduate student going to the University of Derby to do their MBA which could happen. Why will it not happen? Not because the Secretary of State has said it cannot happen but because there is a set of conditions which make it unlikely to happen. I say let us have a discussion in the real world of where it is rather than looking at thin end of the wedge arguments, which are always interesting but not necessarily illuminating.

  Q36 Paul Holmes: We have been urged by yourself and by the Prime Minister, for example, to look at international comparisons and the Prime Minister talked very favourably today at Question Time about the American example. In America there is huge variability in the market between lower quality, cheaper, state universities and the Ivy League and so on. I had a student working as an intern, a graduate, for me last summer from Chicago. She had won a   place to an Ivy League university, and a scholarship—wonderful, but the scholarship paid about 40% of the cost of the fees and what she had left to pay in fees was still something like $36,000 a year. She could not afford to go even though on ability she could go and she had won a fantastic scholarship. She still had a huge sum to pay so she shopped around for the cheapest university, and that, of course, is the standard practice in the USA.

  Mr Clarke: But I am not saying, Mr Holmes, and nor is the Prime Minister, that the American model is the ideal model and one to which we should aspire. In fact, in Questions today he mentioned not only the American example but the Australian, the New Zealand and the Canadian example, taking OECD countries not entirely dissimilar from ourselves as examples to illustrate this point. He could have gone on to other countries in Europe which had variable fees. There is a whole range of countries within the OECD which have a network of variable fees. For me the question is not "variability or not", as I tried to indicate earlier in answering Mr Chaytor's questions. I think it is unrealistic to say there should not be variability. The question is what is the fairness of the system of repayment, how it operates, whether the bursary system operates, and I certainly would not take the American model on any basis for that because it has an entirely different culture and history to that which we are trying to establish. I hope that the kind of system we have with the loan and repayment that we have described could be taken as an example for other countries that are thinking of doing this without the sharpness, as you have described, though it is always possible to say, "There is the American example and we allege"—falsely—"that this government wants to follow the American example". Well, it does not. What the American example tells us is that you can have a system which gives very large amounts of money per head into universities by this route and they have achieved that in the States compared to what we do here, and that you can do it in a way that still allows access to their major Ivy League universities to people from the poorest backgrounds which they have also achieved, but I do not hold up America as a kind of model for what we ought to be doing. I think we need a British system and need to look at the way that the British systems have operated, and I happen to think that the proposals we are putting forward do that well.

  Q37 Paul Holmes: On that aspect, one suggestion is that some universities might have an internal market and that, for example, they charge £3,000 to students who are on a very popular or over-subscribed course like English, say, and very little or nothing to students going on to other courses like physics or chemistry or modern languages, where there is a shortage of people. Now, the students on the popular course who have paid their £9,000 of tuition fees and got that debt to pay back might go into a relatively low paid job or be at the lower end of the graduate market; the student who has had the free tuition subsidised by the English student might go on to a very well paid job and not have to pay that money back. Is that a fair consequence of the system you want to introduce?

  Mr Clarke: I think it is, yes. The fact is that the paying back, whether of the English or the science student as a graduate, will depend entirely on the amount of money that they earn at that time, so if the English student decides to go off and be a playwright and sell his or her plays in the streets of London scrubbing together an income to make it go they will not be paying anything back at all, and as a result of the statement I made last Thursday if they do that for 25 years they will not have to pay it back at all and it will simply be written off. I do not think that is unfair at all. In fact the way we operate will say you make your life choice after you leave university; if you want to conduct an occupation which does not make you very much money then you will not have to pay very much back, and I think that is perfectly reasonable.

  Q38 Paul Holmes: But the whole justification for what you want to do is that graduates earn more so they should contribute—fair enough—but here you would have a graduate, let's say an English teacher, earning on average after seven or eight years in the job £25,000 a year, and they will be paying back their £9,000 fees where a modern language student working in a particular job might earn £60,000 a year and be paying nothing back. Surely if the principle is that the graduate gets access to better paid jobs and should therefore pay, what is wrong with progressive taxation rather than this totally unfair system that you are suggesting?

  Mr Clarke: It is not totally unfair. First, if you take the English teaching example, I cannot speak for my successors but I certainly think we would want to continue the encouragement of people coming into teaching English and other subjects that we have at the moment which means there is extra money coming in for students in those areas which deals with some of these issues, and in other hot supply areas of work. But I believe it is perfectly reasonable to pay back provided the issue of your ability to pay is taken properly into account. The other point, which I think you have acknowledged, is there is a difference between the totality and the particular so in general most students earn more throughout their lives and can therefore afford to pay back. That does not mean there will not be some students who are not in that position, and in my opinion they must not be penalised and that is why we have achieved a system which brings those two things together.

  Paul Holmes: I will not go further down that one!

  Chairman: We will move on to student support.

  Q39 Jonathan Shaw: Secretary of State, the principal concerns of students while they are undertaking their degree is the amount of money they have got in the pockets, the cash in their pockets to be able to pay for things, their day-to-day living, rather than post-qualification paying off fees, et cetera. Now, we have asked you, indeed I have put to you and many other people have put to you since then that the totality, the £2,700, it would be better, rather than having fee remission, actually to take that money and make it into a grant because as our esteemed colleague said, you cannot go to Tesco's and buy much food with the fee remission and the Government is not going to give you credit, is it ?

  Chairman: There is a lot of advertising in this session.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 20 October 2004