Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 1-19)

24 MARCH 2004

MR SIMON BULLOCK, MR ROGER HIGMAN, MS BRYONY WORTHINGTON AND DR HUGH ELLIS

  Q1 Chairman: Welcome. Good afternoon. Thank you for coming in. Did you want to make a few introductory remarks? We have had your press release on the Budget, "Brown Ignores the Environment Again"[1]which may be a summation of your views, but if you have any brief comments to add we would be pleased to hear them.

  Mr Bullock: Yes, we would be very grateful to make some introductory remarks. First of all, I am Simon Bullock and I work on Environmental Taxation Policy; Bryony Worthington is our UK Climate Campaigner; Hugh Ellis is our Planning Adviser and Roger Higman is our Environmental Limits Co-ordinator. So, briefly, to set out what we think three priorities for the Treasury should be: a priority for us—and I think we share this view with Tony Blair, it seems—is to tackle climate change to deliver at least 60% cuts in carbon emissions. This level of target means that all sectors will need to do their part; domestic, transport, aviation and industry. We feel that to do this the Treasury must set a strategic approach to set the right economic framework to deliver that target, for two reasons: first to provide the incentives to change behaviour and redirect investment, and secondly, to signal the Government's intention that it has a strategic commitment to tackle this which will underpin all of its policies across all departments. Our view is that although at the moment there is some reasonable rhetoric we do not have such a strategy, as we can see from the Government's own projections on, for example, transport and aviation emissions. So the first of three priorities, we feel, is that the Treasury should set an economic strategy to deliver 60% carbon cuts. Within that there are two priorities. The first would be to link the Budget more clearly to the spending review, particularly the coming spending review this summer. Taxes and economic instruments need to be introduced as part of well-designed packages, it has been argued for a long time, and a stronger link with spending is needed. Some proportion of revenue is needed to provide appropriate incentives, some spending will be needed to reinforce tax policy and some is also needed to address any adverse impacts that taxes may have. As an example for that we would cite transport. The right incentives are crucial. As we can see, the costs of motoring are continuing to fall and they need to increase, but that is not enough on its own; we need to have that hand-in-hand with spending to create alternatives for people to travel by public transport or make walking or cycling safer. The last priority for us is that this strategy should be very clear and open about the environmental and social objectives of its strategy. Often it has not been spelt out clearly enough that policies should be intended for environmental and social means, and these goals should be linked together as well. Again, transport for us is a good example of that. There is an urgent social need as well as an environmental need for alternatives to the car. Friends of the Earth are very keen on ensuring that policy delivers environmental and social goals together. If you look at transport, 60% of the poorest fifth of households do not have access to a car. Even for the whole population, 30% of the population do not have access to a car, so for those people having decent alternatives, a decent transport network and safe streets to walk on is an absolutely crucial thing and a basic need for most people. I have brought with me today a copy of a report we have done (I will leave a copy for you). It is work we have done with communities in Longsight, an area of Manchester with very low areas of car ownership, and we were asking them what they wanted to see and what their priorities are for transport. Overwhelmingly it is better buses and safer streets. It is an issue that is eroding the quality of life for them and people in the city. So this is an example of where improving public transport and safety would meet environmental and social goals together. To conclude my opening statement, I think the two crucial elements to deliver a carbon strategy for the Treasury—to meet the 60% target—are clear, linked social and environmental goals and to link tax with spending, particularly with the spending review coming up in the next couple of months.

  Q2 Chairman: Thank you very much for that. We will come back to a number of the points you have raised in a minute or two. Can I ask you, first of all, whether you think the Government has, as it seems to claim, an environmental tax strategy?

  Mr Bullock: I think the statement of intent on environmental taxation in 1997 was very good. Two statements, in particular, were very good. The first one was that growth must be stable and environmentally sustainable, that quality of growth matters not just quantity; and the second that the "Government will aim to reform the tax system to increase incentives to reduce environmental damage. That will shift the burden of tax from goods to bads." We think that was a very good initial, starting statement. In Labour's first term we felt they went quite a long way on this agenda: they introduced a climate change levy, they introduced an aggregates tax and they put in some good measures on road taxation. Since then we feel they have stalled, relatively. They have back-tracked on transport taxation; environmental tax as a proportion of GDP is 10% and has been around 10% for ten years—that is not moving up or down particularly much. They say there is a strategy to deliver a low-carbon economy, (coming back, again, to climate change and a 60% target), and for some sectors they are doing quite well; there is a long way to go and there is a lot more to do, but in industry, for example, we are going in the right direction. For the domestic sector things, at least, are not getting any worse. However, two areas which are really crucial are transport and aviation, and the trends are in completely the wrong direction. We see the Government's tax and spending policies having a major effect here in stopping us getting towards those climate targets.

  Q3 Chairman: Coming back to one of the points you made earlier, is not the reason why it is moving the wrong way on transport exactly to do with social attitudes and social issues? We saw it happen with the fuel crisis/protest and the public objections that were raised. Whilst it may be the case that 60% of the poorest fifth do not have a car at all, there are an awful lot of people who are not well-off who do, and who object very strongly when the price of running their cars goes up.

  Mr Bullock: I think this is a clear example of the need to link environmental and social goals and deal with tax and spending at the same time. Of course, it would be politically very difficult to increase the costs of motoring if alternatives to the car are not put in place. I would note, however, that since 1980 the costs of motoring overall have fallen and since 1997 the costs of motoring have fallen as well. We have a tax and spend policy which does not provide for those alternatives. If you look at the spending figures the Social Exclusion Unit put out on transport, buses and walking get very small comparative sums compared with other modes of transport. Bus spending, I think, is around a third of annual spending for rail, or maybe a quarter—I forget the exact figures.[2] Overall, though, they said that spending is very regressive. The poorest fifth of the population get 12% of the transport spending budget and the richest fifth of the population get 38% of it. So it is very important in the Comprehensive Spending Review that the Chancellor puts more money into creating decent alternatives to the car.

  Q4 Chairman: Taking it back to my first question, it seems, in the context of what you have just said, that rather than there being an environmental tax strategy which has stalled, there is no strategy as such at all.

  Mr Bullock: That is one way of putting it, yes.

  Q5 Chairman: There were some initiatives, there were some statements, there was Tax and the Environment: Using Economic Instruments published in 2002. These do not amount to a strategy.

  Mr Bullock: No, I do not think they do. That is why we are calling for an overall carbon strategy which would link the transport, aviation, domestic and industry sectors. As I say, we need to take action in all of these areas to ensure that overall that 60% target is met.

  Q6 Joan Walley: Can I just press you a little bit further on that and ask: if you were advising the Chancellor how that strategy should look, are you saying there should be an action plan to it, or what would you say should be flagged up in that, in a bit more detail?

  Mr Higman: If I can come in on that, I think, firstly, we are looking to see that the Chancellor review all the areas of taxation in respect of carbon emissions to make sure they are moving forward on each of those areas. There are some areas that are not being taxed at all at the moment. Secondly, we have to consider other environmental impacts, and there are areas where we have seen voluntary initiatives, for example on pesticides, where we feel that tax approaches might be more suitable. We are looking for the sorts of initiatives that the Treasury was putting forward in the late-1990s to be reinstated, and that level of commitment moving forward to get the amounts of taxation on environmental bads increased such that we can reduce taxation on things that are considered to be environmental goods, like labour.

  Q7 Chairman: In the light of that, what do you see as the role for fiscal instruments? Do you see them as a way of reflecting the cost to the environment of various activities, or do you see them as a way of managing demand—as a stick to beat bads?

  Mr Bullock: We would say that the role of any fiscal instrument is to achieve the policy objective rather than simply just to internalise the external costs, which is I believe something the Committee has touched on before.

  Q8 Chairman: Do you think internalising the external costs is a worthwhile activity?

  Mr Bullock: I think it is worthwhile in that it certainly would be better than doing nothing. If you look at aviation, for example, the external costs are not being tackled at all at present due to the lack of duty on various sorts of fuel. But we feel we would need to go beyond that. There are a large number of methodological difficulties in internalising external costs. We have got reservations about that almost at a moral level in some senses, in that it assumes that all environmental resources have a price and that there is no such thing as critical natural capital, that environmental goods can always be traded off. We would think that just dealing with internalising the costs, although it would be a useful and necessary first step, if that is the practical way to proceed at the moment, is worth doing, but in the long-term the price mechanism should be used to meet the policy objective rather than just to iron out externalities.

  Ms Worthington: I would only add that there is an obvious trend in government to move to more flexible, market-based economic instruments. Where they are designed well and lead to the achievement of environmental objectives we support the use of those. I think the Government's policy is now far broader than simply a fiscal and spend policy; it now has a third string in its bow, if you like. I do not think they have, perhaps, been as explicit in telling us what their attitude to those instruments is and it might be useful for them to make a statement about their continued use of these trading mechanisms.

  Q9 Chairman: Coming back to something Roger Higman said, we hear a lot about environmental taxation and managing, controlling and punishing bads. Do you think there is enough done within the fiscal environment to encourage good behaviour? Are there a sufficient number of carrots (on the basis of what you said) as well as an insufficient number of sticks?

  Mr Higman: I think in some areas there are. Clearly, we have got incentives for alternative fuels and we support those. We may want to argue about the details of those but we generally support the framework. In other areas it may not be enough to give fiscal incentives, we may actually want to give direct support, financial support, through spending. Again, an example we have already mentioned, public transport, is a very good one. You can reduce the taxation of public transport quite substantially but that may not be the most effective way of providing the alternative people need. So, in that sense, we do not see it as simply a question of taxation.

  Mr Bullock: To add a little bit to that as well, if the Government was to increase road fuel duty just to keep the overall motoring costs constant, so no extra burden to motorists, that would raise between £16 and £30 billion pounds over the period to 2010, depending on the global price of oil. We feel that a large amount of that revenue could be used to create those incentives for alternative behaviour. For example, if you were to put a Safe Route to School into every school in the country that would cost a mere billion pounds compared to the £16 to £30 billion figure. If you wanted to put 20 mile-an-hour zones into every residential street in the country that would be around £500 million. If you wanted to put a comprehensive network of bus lanes into the total built-up area that would cost £1 billion as well. So there is a major opportunity in the spending review coming up and the review of the transport 10-year plan to use some of the spending which should be raised from increasing motoring costs into providing safer streets, improving safety and improving public transport.

  Q10 Joan Walley: Have you actually got all of those details set out in some separate report that you have done?

  Mr Bullock: Ourselves and Transport 2000 will be publishing it on Monday, so I can get it to you.

  Joan Walley: That would be very helpful.

  Q11 Chairman: Yes, it would. Thank you very much. Can I just finally ask, we used to hear from you about Green GDP. I know that Roger Higman, for one, has been with Friends of the Earth for quite a long time. What has happened to Green GDP as a concept? Has it departed?

  Mr Bullock: No, I think not. In fact, the new Economics Foundation published a report very recently with an update called Measure of Domestic Progress, which is in fact very similar to the Index on Sustainable Economic Welfare. I think this agenda is still very relevant, mainly because it highlights that not all types of growth are good. It shows that much growth comes from running down environmental resources, treating capital like income (as no business would do); it shows that a lot of growth has large costs attached, like climate change and air pollution. So where we see the advantage of Green GDP is that it focuses on the fact that growth is for a purpose, it is not an end in itself; it is there to improve the quality of life, and from that you can show that some growth is just not worth having. It is very important that this debate continues. I think there is a danger that it simply focuses on how best to adjust Gross Domestic Product; it is not just about fiddling with the indicators or going down some statistical black hole, what is important is the idea behind Green GDP, which is that we need to focus on quality growth. We think this is a really major issue because, in principle, in the statements of intent and subsequently, Tony Blair and Gordon Brown have both said that quality growth is crucial, but we do not feel the Government acts on this in any strategic way. If the Treasury was to take quality growth seriously it would use economic instruments not just to promote any old growth but to promote growth that meets its environmental and social goals. I think this is part of the sustainable development idea; that you should link economic, social and environmental goals together. What we see, unfortunately, from Government on quite a number of occasions is that it still trades-off these goals—the language is very much about balance, about trading off. A good example was the Aviation White Paper where the environmental damage was considered to be the price to pay for economic growth. Our view is that the Government should use economic instruments to promote growth sectors in the economy that do not damage the environment or people's health. That is why it is so important that the Green GDP debate continues.

  Q12 Mr Challen: I was very struck by the headline of your overall press release, issued on 17 March, "Brown Ignores the Environment Again", and I was particularly struck by the "Again" word at the end. Obviously you do share some of the frustrations that this Committee has. To what would you ascribe this caution? Is it lack of commitment or is it confusion or is it, perhaps, a fear that if we go too far too fast the electorate is going to boot us out?

  Mr Bullock: I think, partly, it may be to do with a perception that some environmental issues are too politically difficult to deal with. I do not think that is actually the case. Transport is a good example of that. If you just increase road fuel duties then that is going to get people's backs up, but if you link it very explicitly to tackling problems and creating alternatives for people then I think it is much more politically palatable. I do not know, Roger, if you want to add anything.

  Mr Higman: I think there are a number of things I would say about that. Firstly, the Government made a lot of progress, as you said, up until 2000, and I do not think we would underestimate the importance of things like the fuel protest in terms of dissuading the Government from the strategy it was pursuing. What we are looking for, though, is for the Government to recognise that although the pursuit may have got difficult, the path may have got difficult, the eventual aim was the right one, and what they were committed to in the late-1990s was the right approach. Therefore, if you like, we need to get smarter about how we do it. That is the message we would have put, and that is where we have been a bit disappointed. We feel there might be things that the Government could do that would not be so controversial but would actually enable them to further the environmental tax agenda in a way that they otherwise have not been doing. An example might be the pesticide side.

  Q13 Mr Challen: This was described as a "Steady as she goes" kind of Budget, a consolidating Budget—and we have our differences, probably, about that. Should we not also try and consolidate the things that we have done in terms of the environment—climate change levy and things of that sort—which in their own areas are hugely controversial and which some people might want to get rid of still? Should we not allow things to work and to see how they work rather than saying that every year we are going to have more and more new measures?

  The Committee suspended from 4.15 pm to 4.35 pm for a division in the House   Mr Higman: Essentially the question was why do we have to do more every year, I believe. The answer, obviously, from our perspective is that we are facing big environmental problems right across the range. We think that climate change is the most prominent of those but we have also got continuing air quality problems, we have got problems to do with over-consumption of resources, problems to do with water pollution and problems to do with abuse of fertilisers and pesticides. All of these environmental problems need to be tackled, in our view, and therefore we have been calling on the Treasury to have a progressive movement so that eventually all of those are tackled. That is why we feel that we need to do a little bit more every year.

  Q14 Mr Challen: Looking at a couple of graphs in the Budget document (I forget what it is called: the Red Book or something), if we turn to page 161 (I do not know if you have access to it) it does show that there are fairly consistent trends downwards in, for example, CO2 emissions from new cars. I am just looking at the graph, which shows a steady downward trend. Chart 7.4 on page 162, UK particulate emissions from the transport sector show a dramatic decline. Some of it, of course, is fairly predictive but, even so, there is an actual decline in the last ten years, then a further decline down to 2015, and then a very slight increase at that point. I am pursuing this issue about how much can we get away with if we want to increase these rates of improvement before people say "That's enough; we are not going to go with it any further". That is the cut-off point for any government. Is it not?

  Mr Higman: There are a number of things to say about that. Firstly, not all of those indicators are going down. There are—

  Q15 Mr Challen: So you dispute the—

  Mr Higman: There are other indicators where, if you look, for example, at the 15 government headline indicators we had the report on last week, my recollection is that in three of them the emissions are actually going in the wrong direction and three of them are steady. So while we can draw attention to those where we seem to be making progress, there are others where we need to make more progress.

  Q16 Mr Challen: Let us be clear on this: you are saying that the Chancellor is using the information selectively to bolster the case and is ignoring other relevant information?

  Ms Worthington: Yes, absolutely. The indicators that were used in the Budget—they used a greenhouse gas statistic without comparing it to the year before. If you look at what is happening in carbon dioxide emissions in totality, they are increasing and have been increasing since 1999. That is not a good record for a Government that is supposedly using economic instruments to tackle climate change. So it is absolutely true that they are using indicators selectively; if they were to look at the totality of energy and fuel consumption they would see big rises, and yet that is buried in amongst the statistics that you really have to look out for in order to see that that is happening.

  Q17 Chairman: It is a fair point that Mr Challen draws attention to, which is that the graph that he refers to is detailing efficiency gains. It is reasonable that efficiency gains are there and real, and where, as a result, individual engines have been more efficient then there is a downward trend. The problem, I take it, is that total volume of traffic continues to rise and, therefore, the total problem continues to get worse.

  Ms Worthington: Yes, absolutely. The environ-mental goal for us is not efficient cars but to maintain the integrity of the environment. I am afraid that indicator is not very helpful in telling whether it is a green taxation policy or not.

  Mr Bullock: Efficiency is just one element of the solution.

  Q18 Mr Challen: You have argued for reinstating the fuel duty escalator and larger differentials in the VED.[3] Would you put some figures on that? I have not seen any myself so I am wondering how far you would go down that route.

  Mr Bullock: We commissioned some research from the IEEP a couple of years ago which is still up-to-date but shows that if you were to increase the road duty to keep overall motoring costs constant that would raise £16-30 billion. It depends on the global price of oil, but it would range between 16 and 30 billion. On VED, currently the Government has lower rates for more fuel-efficient cars but we believe that there should be an incentive against gas-guzzling, very fuel-inefficient cars, so we are proposing a series of bands, £200, £250, £300, £350 and £500 according to carbon emissions. The Department for Transport's research shows, I believe, that if you had a £100 differential between bands then that would persuade 47% of people to buy a more fuel-efficient car. So we think it would make sense for the Government to extend the VED range at the higher end as well as creating incentives at the lower end.

  Ms Worthington: There are other economic instruments that we know the Treasury and DfT are considering which would, in fact, increase the cost of transport, whilst delivering a valid gain. The one that they are looking at at the moment is to create an obligation for renewable fuels, so that it becomes obligatory to sell a proportion of bio-fuels within your fuel mix. That would have the effect of a very precise instrument. It would be spread across all industry so it would lead to an increase in the cost of transport but it would also deliver environmental gain.

  Q19 Mr Challen: If the money (£16 billion) that you estimate might be raised in these two particular ways was hypothecated to public transport, do you have any evidence to show that that would have greater public acceptance? Have you done any polling on that subject, for example?

  Mr Higman: I think there has been polling looking at motorists' attitudes in general to these things. We do not necessarily carry out extensive polls on every single item of policy—we have not got that sort of level of resources. The opinion polls I have seen have suggested that although there is hostility to some aspects of increased taxation, that is mollified quite dramatically when the money is used to promote an alternative. We can see that, also, in press reactions to government policies where large sections of the media have been crying out for more resources to go into alternatives.

  Ms Worthington: The best example of that is congestion charging, where you saw a new facility that was directly linked to visible improvements—the number of buses, frequency of buses and the cleanliness and newness of buses. So where it is obvious, it is common sense; people can see that the payment is going directly to something that they can perceive to be changing. That has made that a more popular instrument.


1   Press release, 17.3.04. Please see www.foe.co.uk Back

2   Mr Bullock later added that for passengers it is between a third and a quarter. The Social Exclusion Unit says of the Transport 10 year plan: "of the plan's £20 billion allocation, 11% relates directly to buses, compared with 40% for passenger rail". Back

3   Vehicle Excise Duty. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2004
Prepared 11 August 2004